Full Insurance, Bayesian Updated Premiums, and Adverse Selection

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Full Insurance, Bayesian Updated Premiums, and Adverse Selection"

Transcription

1 The Geneva Papers on Risk and Insurance Theory, 22: (1997) c 1997 The Geneva Association Full Insurance, Bayesian Updated Premiums, and Adverse Selection RICHARD WATT richard.watt@uam.es Departamento de Análisis Económico, Universidad Autónoma de Madrid, Madrid, Spain FRANCISCO J. VAZQUEZ franciscojose.vazquez@uam.es Department of Economic Analysis, University Autónoma of Madrid, Madrid, Spain, and C.U. Francisco de Vitoria, Ctra. Pozuelo-Majadahonda Km. 1,800, Pozuelo de Alarcón, Madrid, Spain Abstract In the classic Rothschild-Stiglitz model of adverse selection in a competitive environment, we analyse a no-claims bonus type contract (bonus-malus). We show that, under full insurance coverage, if the insurance company applies Bayes s rule to learn about client probability types over time and uses this information in premium calculations for contract renewals, then there exist conditions under which all client types strictly prefer the Bayesian updating contract to the classic Rothschild-Stiglitz separating equilibrium. Key words: insurance, adverse-selection, Bayesian learning 1. Introduction One of the most interesting conclusions to come out of the adverse-selection literature is that where separating contracts are possible, they are more efficient than any possible pooling equilibria 1. In general, by ensuring that the incentive compatibility constraints are satisfied, the principal can be sure that each agent type will be interested in accepting only that contract designed for precisely his type. That this type of equilibrium, if available, is optimal depends critically on the one-shot aspect of much of principal-agent theory. When recontracting is possible, there may exist other contracts, involving possible initial pooling of agent types, that Pareto dominate the separating contract. Casual observation of real-world insurance contracts reveals that the optimal adverseselection contract menu is not always offered or at least it is not the only contract choice offered. Instead, it is rather common to see insurance companies that recontract with their clients on terms that depend on the client s past history of accidents. This seems to be particularly common in automobile insurance. The no-claims bonus (or bonus-malus contract) is the most common of this type of contract, in which the client is offered a reduction in premium if the monetary amount of his claims does not surpass some prespecified quantity. There are many possible ways in which a no-claims bonus can be modeled. The most obvious is to consider that the company is searching for efficiency, it is often the case that JEL Classification: D8

2 136 RICHARD WATT AND FRANCISCO J. VAZQUEZ small losses are more easily born by the client, and so the potential revenue loss from offering the premium discount should offset the additional costs of the small claims that would otherwise have been presented. In this way, a no-claims bonus is very similar to a voluntary deductible. The difference is that instead of the client paying the first part of all claims, the claims are divided into two groups, large and small, and the insurance company pays for the large claims (entirely) while the client pays for the small ones 2. Second, a no-claims bonus can be interpreted as the company offering a solution to moral hazard; the client is given the chance to alter his type (thus suffering accidents less frequently and presenting fewer claims) in exchange for a saving in his premium. Third, a no-claims bonus can be thought of as the company updating its beliefs as to the client s type according to his accident history. This article concentrates exclusively on the third interpretation. The idea can be introduced using the typical undergraduate insurance setting, in which there exist two types of client, differentiated only by their probability of suffering the insurable accident. When this probability is unobservable by the insurer, and unalterable by the client, an adverse-selection problem occurs. As was first noted in the famous article by Rothschild and Stiglitz [1976], a separating equilibrium may exist in which the lowrisk individuals signal their type accepting a partial insurance contract. In an economy in which the insurer is risk neutral and acts in a competitive environment (thus earning zero expected profits), it is easy to show that, if a separating equilibrium exists, then at this equilibrium the participation constraints of both high- and low-risk individuals will not be saturated (both types of individual strictly prefer to participate), while the only incentive compatibility constraint that saturates is that of the high-risk type (the low-risk type strictly prefers the contract designed for him, but the high-risk type will be indifferent between the two contracts on the market.) This equilibrium will exist only if the expected utility that the low-risk individual would obtain under a pooling equilibrium with full insurance and a premium that is calculated using the market average (the expected) accident probability is strictly less than the expected utility that he obtains under the separating equilibrium 3. In a multiperiod setting, it is not obvious that simple repetition of the separating equilibrium is optimal. In this article, we take the benchmark contract that would be offered as an alternative to any Bayesian information gathering type of contract as being periodic repetitions of the Rothschild-Stiglitz single-period equilibrium contract menu. In a two-period model, Hosios and Peters [1989] show that this is not necessarily optimal for a monopolist, mainly since the high-risk client may play strategically in the first period by not reporting an accident, in an attempt to influence the second-period probability that the principal attaches to him being low risk. In our setting, such strategic play will be ruled out by assumption (all accidents are public information), but anyway, since (as Hosios and Peters show) in the last period the principal will definitely offer the Rothschild-Stiglitz single-period equilibrium, and since under perfect competition this does not depend on the probability of being low risk (except in its very existence), no strategic first-period play in a perfect-competition model is optimal anyway. Second, under the assumption that commitment is only for one period, the greatest second-period penalty that the insurer can impose on the client is zero coverage (and hence reservation utility) in a monopoly, but when other companies are in existence, this is not so (any company can just offer the Rothschild-Stiglitz equilibrium in any period),

3 FULL INSURANCE 137 and therefore the only feasible equilibrium that is not directly related to Bayesian information gathering is periodic repetition of the single-period Rothschild-Stiglitz separating equilibrium. The most relevant articles on multiperiod insurance contracts and adverse selection generally consider models with precommitment to the contract over time and initial revelation of type, and so this type of repeated insurance can be thought of as a single transaction in which the incentive compatibility constraints are modified in a dynamic sense, in order to incite truthful type revelation (separation of types) at the outset of the contract (see Dionne [1983]). These models tend to concentrate on situations in which the insurer is a monopolist and thus is interested in profit maximization. In this article we are concerned with Pareto dominance in a perfectly competitive insurance market in which commitment is not an issue, mainly since commitment to a contract over time does not seem to be a feature often included in real-life insurance contracts 4. It may be possible that contract formats other than the Rothschild-Stiglitz equilibrium menu exist, some involving a learning process but no commitment and still offering zero expected profits to the insurer but greater expected utility to both client types. Consider the following multiperiod contract format: All insurance contracts have full coverage of the insurable loss. All insurance contracts begin with a premium corresponding to the market average loss probability. All insurance contract renewals reflect the client s accident history in a rational manner. Any client is free to not renew his contract, but his accident history is assumed to be public knowledge and will be used in any new contracts drawn up between him and any other insurers. Graphically, this multiperiod contract with learning corresponds to all contracts starting out at the intersection of the market fair-odds line and the certainty line (the 45 degree line). Then the slope of the fair odds line is recalculated, for each individual client, after each contract period using the client s current accident history, and the contract renewal is where the updated fair-odds line intersects the certainty line. Given an adequate learning procedure, all clients who accept this contract format can expect that their contract will, over time, converge to their full information contract. Of course, we do not argue that this is the only possible multiperiod updating contract that could be considered or in fact that it is in any sense optimal. In fact, there are two important variables in an insurance contract the premium and the coverage, both of which could be subjected to updating. Specifically, an insurer could offer the contract that is optimal for the low-risk client at the market average premium (which would imply partial coverage) and then go updating both the coverage and the premium according to observed accidents. Doing so would, of course, introduce a much greater degree of complication into any theoretical analysis. Besides, the analysis contemplated in the current article would appear to be more closely related to most empirically observed bonus-malus contracts, which usually imply full insurance always but with a premium that may vary over time. If we show that our proposed updating contract Pareto dominates the nonupdating alternative, then surely the optimal updating contract will also.

4 138 RICHARD WATT AND FRANCISCO J. VAZQUEZ Note the following characteristics of this contract format. First, the insurer must be earning zero expected profits in all periods, since each client is charged a fair premium corresponding to his expected type, given his accident history. Second, any high-risk clients must receive greater expected utility under this contract format than under the separating equilibrium, since under both contract formats they get full coverage, but the learning format offers a gradual convergence (from above) to the full information contract, which is the same contract that they would receive under the separating contract (we prove this formally in Theorem 2). The high-risk individuals will suffer excess claims penalties during the life of their updating contract. Hence, our assumption that any client s accident history is public knowledge (in the same way as an individual s credit history is public knowledge when applying for a bank loan or a credit card) is vital, or else the high-risk individuals could simply move from one company to another once their current insurer begins to learn the true type. It is interesting to note that this type of information sharing among insurance companies is a normal feature of contracts in France. This assumption also means that claim underreporting is not an issue 5. Third, this contract is equally valid under conditions of total ignorance that is, when even the clients are unaware of their type. Hence, while we are considering an adverse-selection environment, this is by no means the only environment that this contract could be considered under, and that seems to be realistically reasonable. It may be argued that the first-period pooling situation is vulnerable to competition from rebel contracts that are below the corresponding indifference curve of high-risk clients and above that of the low-risk clients. However, the proposed contract is certainly defendable under the reactive equilibrium concept of Riley [1979]. If the company that offers the Bayesian contract infers that some (or all) of the low-risk clients are going to defect to some rebel contract, then that company will just revise the initial probability that it attaches to the market average loss probability accordingly, to take into account the average loss probability expected from the pool of clients accepting the Bayesian contract. In the limit, the Bayesian contract will collapse onto the full-coverage, high-premium contract of the Rothschild-Stiglitz menu, and hence the only credible rebel contract must collapse onto the partial-coverage, low-premium contract of the Rothschild-Stiglitz menu. The only individuals that we must look closely at are the low-risk clients. Assuming existence of a separating equilibrium contract, the updating contract will necessarily start out offering them less expected utility than the separating equilibrium, but on the other hand it can be expected to improve over time as the full-information contract is approached. In particular, since the full-information contract must necessarily offer greater expected utility than the separating-equilibrium contract, the updating contract can be thought of as an initial investment in signals that should pay off in cheaper contract renewals as time goes on (no-claims bonuses). This article proposes to explore the comparisons between the two possible solution formats; the optimal-contract menu versus an information-updating model based on full coverage and premiums that vary according to accident histories. The second model will, logically, be Bayesian in nature, in that the insurer uses Bayes s rule to rationally update beliefs on the probability that any particular client is of one type or another. In particular, our intention is to consider the necessary and sufficient conditions for the Pareto dominance of the Bayesian contract format.

5 FULL INSURANCE 139 The existing literature on Bayesian learning and adverse selection in insurance contracts seems to be rather scarce. The most relevant reference manual as far as insurance and Bayesian statistics is concerned would appear to be Klugman [1992], but he does not treat the adverse-selection aspect of insurance at all. Cyert and DeGroot [1987] analyze many aspects of economic decisions under uncertainty and learning, but they do not treat insurance at all. In two separate articles, Holt and Shore [1980] analyze an abundance of related topics, using techniques that are similar to those to be applied here, but they do not touch on insurance problems either. The repeated contract self-selection models do not always specifically use Bayesian learning as the basis for premium updates (see, for example, Dionne [1983], Dionne and Lasserre [1985], Cooper and Hayes [1987], and Dionne and Lasserre [1987]). More specifically to this article, Gal and Landsberger [1988] use binomial statistics to show that the expected profits of the insurer increase if repeated contracts are based on longer experience histories (which is related to our Theorem 3), but Bayesian updating is not explicit in their model. Lastly, Hosios and Peters [1989] do use Bayesian learning and binomial statistics to consider contract renegotiation and underreporting of claims (underreporting is also the theme of Hey [1985] but is of no relevance here as we are considering pure adverse selection, when all accidents are public information). In what follows, the classic Rothschild-Stiglitz separating equilibrium will be referred to as RS contract menu, while the suggested Bayesian updating contract will be referred to as BUC. 2. A general two-client type model We shall maintain the basic assumptions of the Rothschild and Stiglitz setting; there will only be two agent types (a and b), differentiated only by their probability of accident (state 2), p a > p b. Wealth in state 1, x 1 is strictly greater than wealth in state 2, x 2. Hence the insured loss is just L = x 1 x 2. The insurance company is assumed to be risk neutral and to operate in a competitive market (and hence is restricted to zero expected profits), and the agents have the same utility function for money, U(x), which is assumed to be continuous, differentiable at least twice, increasing, and concave. Assume that each contract period implies one new observation is added to the client s accident history and that a new contract is signed after each contract period, taking into account the entire accident history to date. Let λ denote the insurance company s initial estimation of the probability that any particular client is of type b, and so the initial prior as to the probability of an accident for any particular individual is p (1 λ)p a + λp b. We assume that 0 <λ<1 since an extreme value (0 or 1) for this probability indicates that there is no adverse-selection problem. The initial pooling contract will be just that contract found at the intersection of the certainty line and the iso-expected value contour passing through the initial wealth distribution, x, with slope (1 p)/ p. This contract corresponds to full coverage at a premium cost of pl. Note that this contract will offer

6 140 RICHARD WATT AND FRANCISCO J. VAZQUEZ zero expected profits to the insurance company given the initial beliefs. Note also that since the high-risk individual will be fully insured under both the contract menu and the initial Bayesian contract, but that the second is necessarily cheaper, he must enjoy greater expected utility at the initial pooling contract than under the contract menu solution. Since we are assuming that a separating equilibrium exists, the low-risk client must receive less expected utility from the initial pooling contract than from the separating contract menu 6. After the first contract period, the prior, λ, can be updated according to whether or not an accident occurred. The posterior for λ after the first contract period will be λp b λ(1, 1) = (1 λ)p a + λp b if an accident occurred and λ(0, 1) = λ(1 p b ) (1 λ)(1 p a ) + λ(1 p b ) if not. It is easy to see that λ(1, 1) <λ<λ(0,1)if and only if p a > p b, as has been assumed. Hence, if there has been an accident, the client s contract becomes a little bit more expensive, while if there has not been an accident, the contract becomes a little bit cheaper (there is a no claims bonus). After n contract periods have gone by with, say s accidents, the posterior for λ will be λ(s, n) = λpb s(1 p b) n s (1 λ)pa s (1 p a) n s + λpb s(1 p. (1) n s b) To see this, let S stand for the event; from n attempts, s are observed to be accidents. From binomial statistics, the probability of event S given an agent of type i = a, b, p(s i) is p(s a) = C n s ps a (1 p a) n s p(s b) = C n s ps b (1 p b) n s, where ( ) Cs n n = n! = s s!(n s)!. Given that the prior probability for the agent being type b is λ, Bayes s rule tells us that λ(s, n) p(b S) = λp(s b) (1 λ)p(s a) + λp(s b). Substituting for p(s i) and cancelling common terms leaves us with the equation given for λ(s, n). The following theorem will be fundamental for the results of the analysis:

7 FULL INSURANCE 141 Theorem 1: Let E[λ(s, n), p i ] be the expected value of λ(s, n) for a type i client: E[λ(s, n), p i ] E[λ, n, p i ] = n n! s!(n s)! ps i (1 p i) n s λ(s, n); then E[λ(s, n), p a ] 0 and E[λ(s, n), p b ] 1 as n. i = a, b Proof. See the Appendix. Theorem 1 is an entirely expected, but nevertheless reassuring result: if the insurer uses Bayes s rule to update over client types, then expected type converges to true type over time. Given Eq. (1) we can calculate the probability of an accident given history (s, n): p(s, n) = (1 λ(s, n))p a + λ(s, n)p b. (2) Note that from Theorem 1, Eq. (2) implies that the expected value of the probability of an accident approaches its true value as n increases. Using Eq. (1), it is easy to show that p(s, n) can be written as (1 λ)ps+1 a (1 p a ) n s + λp s+1 b (1 p b ) n s p(s, n) = (1 λ)pa s (1 p a) n s + λpb s(1 p. b) n s Note that p(0, 0) = p, so that the assumed probability of accident without a history is just the initial prior. The expected utility of the BUC, up to z contract renewals for a type i agent, is EUi BUC = (z, W, L,γ) z n γ n n=0 n! s!(n s)! ps i (1 p i) n s U[W p(s,n)l]; i =a,b, (3) where z is the number of permitted contract renewals, γ is the psychological discount factor per period (0 <γ <1), W is the initial periodic wealth, and L is the amount of the possible loss. This can then be compared with the expected utility, over z periods, of the optimal RS contract menu for a type i agent: EU RS i = (z, W, L,γ) z γ n {p i U[W L(1 α i (1 p i ))] + (1 p i )U[W α i p i L]}; i = a, b, n=0 where α i is the proportion of the loss that is insured that is, α a = 1,α b <1. 7 For given values of initial wealth (W ) and possible loss amount (L), define H i (z,γ)= EUi BUC (z,γ) EUi RS (z,γ); i =a,b. (5) If H i (, ) >0, then a type i individual will prefer the BUC to the RS contract menu. (4)

8 142 RICHARD WATT AND FRANCISCO J. VAZQUEZ Theorem 2: For any values of the parameters, a type a individual will always prefer the BUC that is, H a (z,γ)>0 z IN; 0 <γ <1. Proof. See the Appendix. Given Theorem 2, in order to consider the Pareto dominance of the BUC, it is sufficient to analyze only the low-risk agent s preferences. Theorem 3: Given U[ ] strictly concave, if γ = 1, then there exists a value z 0 IN such that H b (z,γ =1)>0 z IN, z z 0. Proof. See the Appendix. Theorem 3 considers a special case that in which the low-risk agent is perfectly patient. In words, the result is, if the agent is perfectly patient, then he will always prefer the BUC so long as the insurer offers sufficient contract renewals. The intuition behind the result is clear; since (from Theorem 1) the low-risk agent s expected premium approaches the full-information level over time, so his expected utility increases over time under the BUC. While his expected utility starts out lower than that corresponding to the contract menu, it must converge to something greater, and so long as the sum of the positive expected utility gains outweighs the sum of the negative part, the agent is better off. This can be guaranteed under perfect patience, so long as there are sufficient contract renewals. Corollary 1: a. For each z IN; z z 0, there exists a γ 0 (z) <1such that H b (z,γ)>0 γ IR,γ 0 (z)<γ <1. b. γ 0 (z) is a strictly decreasing function for z z 0. Proof. See the Appendix. This result can be observed in figure 1, in which the graph of a typical H b (z, ) function is shown 8. Note that as z is reduced, the critical value γ 0 (z) gets closer to 1 that is, if fewer contract renewals are offered, then only the more patient consumers benefit from the BUC; hence, there is a kind of tradeoff between the number of renewals and the discount factor. As an example of how the above calculations could work, consider the following parameter values; p a = 1/2, p b = 1/6,γ =0.98, U[x] = x,λ=0.9,w =20,000, and L = 10,000. The optimal RS adverse-selection contract menu corresponds to α b = , and it gives the low-risk agent expected utility of in each contract period. Hence, the (ex ante) expected utility of z repetitions (note that, from Eqs. (3) and (4), the initial period is called z = 0; hence, the number of repetitions is the number of periods, after the initial one, that the contract is renewed) of the optimal adverse-selection contract for this agent (Eq. (3)) is just ( 1 γ z+1 ) = ( z+1 ). 1 γ

9 FULL INSURANCE 143 Figure 1. The graph of H b (z, ) for different values of z. For selected values of z, this expected utility (EU RS ) is shown in Table 1, together with the corresponding values of the expected utility of the BUC (EU BUC ) calculated from Eq. (4). As can be seen, the RS contract menu, as expected, is better for shorter-length contracts, but the BUC does better for longer-term contracts (more renewals), since it gives the client enough time for his premium to settle down close to the optimal full-information level. The BUC overtakes the RS contract menu after nineteen renewals are possible. At eighteen renewals, the RS contract menu gives as against from the BUC, but at nineteen renewals (not in the table) the BUC gives as against Table 1. Expected utilities of the RS and BUC contracts according to contract length. EU RS EU BUC EU RS EU BUC z = z = z = z = z = z = z = z = z = z = z = z = z = z = z = z = z = z =

10 144 RICHARD WATT AND FRANCISCO J. VAZQUEZ from the RS contract menu. After the BUC overtakes the RS contract menu, it never falls behind again (see the Appendix, proof of corollary). There is an important point to note about the dynamics of the BUC. As we have pointed out, conditional on the only contracts on the market being the RS contract menu and the BUC, all high-risk individuals will purchase the BUC, and there exist conditions under which the low-risk ones will also purchase the BUC. Recalling that our initial assumption was that all individuals are symmetric in all but the probability of accident, thus requiring that they all have the same discount factor, the Pareto dominance theorem is true for a population of individuals with a given discount factor. In reality, there may well exist a range of discount factors in the population, which can be modeled by simply decreasing the discount factor for some clients 9. If this were so, then we would have a model in which, for a given number of contract renewals, all high-risk types (independent of discount rate) would purchase the BUC, and all low-risk types with a discount rate greater than or equal to some critical number (determined by the number of contract renewals) would also purchase the BUC, while the other low-risk types, for whom the BUC does not payoff, will purchase the RS partial coverage contract. This implies the following dynamic situation 10, since not all low-risk individuals are going to purchase the BUC, the initial market odds line is below that corresponding to the entire population of individuals. Hence, the number of contract renewals required increases, and so the most impatient of current BUC buyers will drop out, preferring the RS partial coverage contract, which leads to a further lowering of the average loss probability, and so a further increase in the contract renewal horizon, and so a further defection of impatient BUC buyers to the RS contract. The question that this obviously raises is if the process converges to a stable equilibrium in which the market is divided among impatient low-risk clients at the RS partial coverage contract, and the rest of the clients (all high-risk ones plus patient low-risk clients) at the BUC. The answer is almost always. In fact, the insurance company would be simply reinterpreting the initial prior to be not the proportion of high-risk types in the entire population but rather the proportion of the final mix of clients desired at the BUC contract. In effect, the above model does not depend on the initial prior, λ, being in fact the population proportion, it could just as well be any other number. Hence, the insurance company could just decide, ex ante, on the client mix that it wanted to purchase the BUC (that is, it does not necessarily want that the entire population participate in the BUC, as we have done above), calculate the implied initial prior, and then offer the corresponding number of contract renewals that will attract exactly the anticipated client mix, given the critical cutoff discount rate. Note that this does not require the insurance company to be able to observe discount factors, but it does require that the distribution of discount factors, at least over low-risk types, be known. Vazquez and Watt [1997] have formally analyzed the nonhomogeneous discount factor case. The above argument makes the following prediction: if the BUC bonus-malus contract is offered along with the RS contract menu, then the full-coverage, high-premium contract in the RS menu will not sell. Hence, presumably, it will not be offered. Furthermore, we should see only impatient clients purchasing the RS partial coverage contract older people, people with a high propensity to emigrate to another country, and so on. Both of these predictions would be easily testable empirically.

11 FULL INSURANCE Conclusions In this article we considered the comparison between two different contract settings for insurance when the insurer acts in a competitive environment. On the one hand, we considered the standard separating equilibrium contract menu, and on the other, a format under which all contracts have full coverage, and the premium is endogenously determined according to the client s accident history. It is claimed that this second format corresponds to usual real-world insurance practice, and it was noted that in order for such a contract format to be viable, all accident histories must be made public information among insurers. We have shown that, all high-risk types will prefer the BUC format to the RS contract menu, and, so long as there are sufficient contract renewals, and insurance consumers are sufficiently patient, so will all low-risk types. Since both contract formats offer expected profits of 0 to the insurer, we have shown that there exist conditions under which the BUC with endogenous premiums Pareto dominates repetition of the RS contract menu. Furthermore, if we assume that discount rates are not homogeneous over consumers, then the above model would appear to predict that insurance companies can design their bonumalus contracts such that there is a separation of types over the RS partial insurance contract, and the BUC. Specifically, all high-risk types, independent of their discount factors, and the most patient low-risk types can be attracted to a BUC, while impatient low-risk types will opt for the RS partial-coverage contract. The analysis presented here suggests plenty of further studies. Since the critical values of either z 0 or γ 0 (z) depend on all the other parameters, it would be interesting to consider the comparative statics exercise of changes in initial wealth (W ), loss amount (L), the probabilities of loss (p a and p b ), the (ex ante) probability of any particular client being type b(λ), and perhaps most important, the shape of the utility function U[ ] that is to say, the characteristics of risk aversion 11. Lastly, the analysis here is valid for any increasing concave utility function. Given this, the results achieved could certainly be recast in a setting based solely on second-order stochastic dominance. Doing so may well be rewarding empirically, since it would not require estimations of utility functions in order to calculate the exact terms of the BUC. Appendix Proof of Theorem 1 We make use of the well-known mathematical fact n Cs n x s y n s = (x + y) n. Part 1: lim n E[λ, n, p a ] = 0. Note that we can write (A.1) p s a (1 p a) n s λ(s, n) = λpa s (1 p a) n s pb s(1 p b) n s (1 λ)pa s (1 p a) n s + λpb s(1 p = A B, n s b)

12 146 RICHARD WATT AND FRANCISCO J. VAZQUEZ where λ p s A = a (1 pa ) n s pb s (1 pb ) n s 2 1 λ B = 2 λ 1 λ pa s (1 pa ) n s pb s (1 pb ) n s (1 λ)pa s (1 p a) n s + λpb s(1 p 1. b) n s Hence E[λ, n, p a ] n λ Cs n 2 1 λ ( pa pb ) s ( 1 pa 1 pb ) n s. (A.2) Together, (A.1) and (A.2) imply λ E[λ, n, p a ] 2 ( pa pb + ) n, 1 p a 1 pb (A.3) 1 λ which approaches 0 as n, since pa pb + 1 p a 1 pb < 1. Hence, from (A.3) it is obtained that lim n E[λ, n, p a ] = 0. Part 2: lim n E[λ, n, p b ] = 1. Note that it is always true that (1 λ)e[λ, n, p a ] + λe[λ, n, p b ] = Hence it is also always true that n λcs n ps b (1 p b) n s = λ. { } { } (1 λ) lim E[λ, n, p a] + λ lim E[λ, n, p b] = λ. n n Since lim n E[λ, n, p a ] = 0, it must be true that lim n E[λ, n, p b ] = 1. Proof of Theorem 2 Since, for the high-risk individual, in the contract menu α a = 1, we can write EU RS n a (z, W, L,γ)= γ n U[W p a L]. (A.4)

13 FULL INSURANCE 147 Second, note that, using the equation for p(s, n) in the text (1 λ)ps+1 a (1 p a ) n s + λp s+1 b (1 p b ) n s p(s, n) = (1 λ)pa s (1 p a) n s + λpb s(1 p < p b) n s a. (A.5) Hence, it is satisfied that U[W p(s, n)l] > U[W p a L] for any values of s and n(0 s n), since U[ ] is a strictly increasing function. Thus, (A.1), (A.4), and (A.5) imply that, for any values of z IN, W, L IR, and 0 <γ <1, EUa BUC > (z, W, L,γ) z n γ n Cs n ps a (1 p a) n s U[W p a L]= EU RS (z, W, L,γ). n=0 a Proof of Theorem 3 First note that we can write where H b (z,γ)= h(n) = z γ n h(n), n=0 n Cs n ps b (1 p b) n s U[W p(s, n)l] K, with K p b U[W L(1 α b (1 p b ))] + (1 p b )U[W α b p b L], which is just the single-period utility that corresponds to the RS. Given U[ ] strictly concave, it is easy to see that K < U[W p b L]. Since p(s, n) >p b, it is true that n h(n) < Cs n ps b (1 p b) n s U[W p b L] K =U[W p b L] K. (A.6) On the other hand, U[W p(s, n)l] = U[(1 λ(s, n))(w p a L) + λ(s, n)(w p b L)], and since U[ ] is strictly concave and 0 λ(s, n) 1, then U[W p(s, n)l] >(1 λ(s, n))u[w p a L] + λ(s, n)u[w p b L].

14 148 RICHARD WATT AND FRANCISCO J. VAZQUEZ Hence, we obtain h(n) >(1 E(λ, n, p b ))U[W p a L] + E(λ, n, p b )U[W p b L] K. (A.7) Thus, (A.6) and (A.7) imply that (1 E(λ, n, p b ))U[W p a L] + E(λ, n, p b )U[W p b L] K < h(n) < U[W p b L] K and Theorem 1 yields r lim h(n) = U[W p bl] K > 0. n Moreover, h(n) is a bounded monotone increasing sequence for n sufficiently large. Therefore, it is satisfied that 1. If γ = 1, n=0 γ n h(n) = n=0 h(n) =+ since r > If 0 <γ <1, since n=0 γ n < + and h(n) is a bounded monotone increasing sequence for n sufficiently large, the series convergence criterion of Abel yields n=0 γ n h(n) < +. Hence, H b (z =,γ = 1) =+ and H b (z =,γ < 1)<+. In consequence, there exists a value z 0 IN such that H b (z,γ =1)>0 z IN, z z 0. Proof of Corollary 1 a. Given Theorem 3, standard continuity arguments are sufficient for this part of the corollary to be true. b. First note that n+1 h(n + 1) (1 p b )h(n) = Cs n+1 pb s (1 p b) n s+1 U[W p(s, n + 1)L] since C n+1 s > n Cs n ps b (1 p b) n s+1 U[W p(s, n)l] + p b K n Cs n ps b (1 p b) n s+1 {U[W p(s, n + 1)L] U[W p(s, n)l]}, Cs n. Hence, using that p(s, n) is strictly decreasing in n, it is true that h(n + 1) (1 p b )h(n) >0, and therefore h(n + 1) >0 whenever h(n) 0.

15 FULL INSURANCE 149 Secondly, note that if H b (z,γ) 0 then h(z) >0 and H b (z + 1,γ) H b (z,γ)=γ z+1 h(z+1)>0, which implies that H b (,γ)is increasing for z z 0 and γ γ 0 (z 0 ). In particular, for any given discount factor, once we have found a z such that H b (z,γ) 0, then further increases in z can never cause H b (,γ)to go negative again. As a direct consequence it is obtained that γ 0 (z) is a strictly decreasing function for z z 0. Acknowledgments We wish to thank the participants of the Twenty-third Seminar of the European Group of Risk and Insurance Economists, and the seminar participants of Carlos III University in Madrid. In particular, we thank Harris Schlesinger for valuable comments. Any remaining errors are the responsibility of the authors. Notes 1. Unless, off course, the optimal separating contract happens to coincide with a pooling contract. In the standard 2 agent-type model, this would require that the principal attaches zero prior probability to the any particular agent being of the most risky type, which is inconsistent with the existence of an adverse-selection problem. 2. When this type of coverage is explicitly contracted, it is usually known as a disappearing deductible. 3. Strictly speaking, this is only the necessary condition. The sufficient condition is that no part of the indifference curve of the low-risk individual at the separating equilibrium lie geometrically below the market fair odds line (see Rothschild and Stiglitz [1976]). 4. In Spain, the law regulating damage insurance contracts (as opposed to life insurance), allows a maximum contract duration of ten years. However, there is a commitment problem since the law stipulates that the contract will become null and void twenty days after any agreed premium payment date should the premium not be paid. Second, with respect to repetition of the Rothschild-Stiglitz contract menu, according to the Spanish Actuarial Association, it is normal practice for both life and nonlife insurance (for example, homeowner s insurance) to be of annual (but renewable) duration, and after correcting for changes in risk and inflation, the premium is, in many cases constant over periods. 5. Claim underreporting is a moral-hazard problem, and we are only interested in adverse selection. For a good treatment of claim underreporting, see Hey [1985]. 6. Note that if the Rothschild-Stiglitz equilibrium did not exist because of there being too many low-risk types, then the Pareto dominance of the suggested BUC over RS becomes even more probable. 7. It is a well-known result (see, for the original exposition, Rothschild and Stiglitz [1976]) that α b < 1 and α a = 1 that is to say, low-risk clients must signal their type by accepting partial coverage, and high-risk individuals purchase full insurance (the insurer has no informational difficulties in offering a fair premium to these individuals in the separating contract.) 8. Although for the purposes of the exposition, the actual shape of the function is irrelevant, it can be mathematically shown (by analyzing the first- and second-order derivatives) that it corresponds to the representation presented as Figure For example, some people may be more likely to emigrate. It may also be useful to model older people as being more impatient (having lower discount factors), but on this point we must be careful as we have modeled the discount factor as a constant for the z periods of the BUC. It would undoubtedly be interesting (all-be-it complicated) to allow the discount factor to diminish as the client ages. However, so long as the contract

16 150 RICHARD WATT AND FRANCISCO J. VAZQUEZ length is rather insignificant in relation to the entire life of a client, our assumption of constant discount factor seems acceptable. We thank an anonymous referee for pointing this out. 10. We thank Art Snow for pointing this out. 11. This is bound to be a complicated but most intriguing question. Since updating yields, ex ante, greater variance of possible outcomes, one may be led to believe that more risk-averse individuals might prefer the more stable contract menu, but then on the other hand, in the longer term the Bayesian contract settles down (converges) to the full-information contract and thus offers less variance together with greater periodic utility. References COOPER, R., and HAYES, B. [1987]: Multi-Period Insurance Contracts, International Journal of Industrial Organisation, 5, CYERT, R., and DEGROOT, M. [1987]: Bayesian Analysis and Uncertainty in Economic Theory. London: Chapman and Hall, Ltd. DIONNE, G. [1983]: Adverse Selection and Repeated Insurance Contracts, Geneva Papers on Risk and Insurance, 8, DIONNE, G., and LASSERRE, P. [1985]: Adverse Selection, Repeated Insurance Contracts and Announcement Strategy, Review of Economic Studies, 52, DIONNE, G., and LASSERRE, P. [1987]: Adverse Selection and Finite-Horizon Insurance Contracts, European Economic Review, 31, GAL, S., and LANDSBERGER, M. [1988]: On Small Sample Properties of Experience Rating Insurance Contracts, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 103, HEY, J. [1985]: No Claims Bonus? Geneva Papers on Risk and Insurance, 10, HOLT, C., and SHORE, R. [1980]: Bayesian Analysis in Economic Theory and Time Series Analysis, Studies in Bayesian Econometrics Series, North Holland: Amsterdam. HOSIOS, A., and PETERS, M. [1989]: Repeated Insurance Contracts with Adverse Selection and Limited Commitment, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 104, KLUGMAN, S. [1992]: Bayesian Statistics in Actuarial Science with Emphasis on Credibility. Kluwer Academic Publishers: Dordrecht. RILEY, J. [1979]: Informational Equilibrium, Econometrica, 47, ROTHSCHILD, M., and STIGLITZ, J. [1976]: Equilibrium in Competitive Insurance Markets: An Essay on the Economics of Imperfect Information, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 90, VAZQUEZ, F.J., and WATT, R. [1997]: Implicit Client Sorting and Bonus-Malus Contracts, Paper presented to the Annual Meeting of the Risk Theory Society, University of Alabama, April.

Unraveling versus Unraveling: A Memo on Competitive Equilibriums and Trade in Insurance Markets

Unraveling versus Unraveling: A Memo on Competitive Equilibriums and Trade in Insurance Markets Unraveling versus Unraveling: A Memo on Competitive Equilibriums and Trade in Insurance Markets Nathaniel Hendren January, 2014 Abstract Both Akerlof (1970) and Rothschild and Stiglitz (1976) show that

More information

Optimal insurance contracts with adverse selection and comonotonic background risk

Optimal insurance contracts with adverse selection and comonotonic background risk Optimal insurance contracts with adverse selection and comonotonic background risk Alary D. Bien F. TSE (LERNA) University Paris Dauphine Abstract In this note, we consider an adverse selection problem

More information

2. Information Economics

2. Information Economics 2. Information Economics In General Equilibrium Theory all agents had full information regarding any variable of interest (prices, commodities, state of nature, cost function, preferences, etc.) In many

More information

SELECTION IN INSURANCE MARKETS by Steven E. Landsburg University of Rochester

SELECTION IN INSURANCE MARKETS by Steven E. Landsburg University of Rochester SELECTION IN INSURANCE MARKETS by Steven E. Landsburg University of Rochester Consider an insurance market say, for insurance against accidental injuries. Agents face different levels of accident risk,

More information

Equilibrium in Competitive Insurance Markets: An Essay on the Economic of Imperfect Information

Equilibrium in Competitive Insurance Markets: An Essay on the Economic of Imperfect Information Equilibrium in Competitive Insurance Markets: An Essay on the Economic of Imperfect Information By: Michael Rothschild and Joseph Stiglitz Presented by Benjamin S. Barber IV, Xiaoshu Bei, Zhi Chen, Shaiobi

More information

Economics of Insurance

Economics of Insurance Economics of Insurance In this last lecture, we cover most topics of Economics of Information within a single application. Through this, you will see how the differential informational assumptions allow

More information

Moral Hazard. Itay Goldstein. Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania

Moral Hazard. Itay Goldstein. Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania Moral Hazard Itay Goldstein Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania 1 Principal-Agent Problem Basic problem in corporate finance: separation of ownership and control: o The owners of the firm are typically

More information

Lecture notes for Choice Under Uncertainty

Lecture notes for Choice Under Uncertainty Lecture notes for Choice Under Uncertainty 1. Introduction In this lecture we examine the theory of decision-making under uncertainty and its application to the demand for insurance. The undergraduate

More information

On Compulsory Per-Claim Deductibles in Automobile Insurance

On Compulsory Per-Claim Deductibles in Automobile Insurance The Geneva Papers on Risk and Insurance Theory, 28: 25 32, 2003 c 2003 The Geneva Association On Compulsory Per-Claim Deductibles in Automobile Insurance CHU-SHIU LI Department of Economics, Feng Chia

More information

Insurance Markets with Differential Information

Insurance Markets with Differential Information Insurance Markets with Differential Information S. Hun Seog [석승훈] Graduate School of Management, KAIST (KGSM) 207-43 Cheongryangri-Dong, Dongdaemun-Gu, Seoul, 130-722, KOREA Email: seogsh@kgsm.kaist.ac.kr

More information

CAN BONUS-MALUS ALLIEVIATE INSURANCE FRAUD?

CAN BONUS-MALUS ALLIEVIATE INSURANCE FRAUD? C The Journal of Risk and Insurance, 2006, Vol. 73, No. 1, 123-151 CAN BONUS-MALUS ALLIEVIATE INSURANCE FRAUD? Ignacio Moreno Francisco J. Vázquez Richard Watt ABSTRACT Traditionally, insurance companies

More information

Yes, No, Perhaps? - Explaining the Demand for Risk Classification Insurance with Fuzzy Private Information

Yes, No, Perhaps? - Explaining the Demand for Risk Classification Insurance with Fuzzy Private Information Yes, No, Perhaps? - Explaining the Demand for Risk Classification Insurance with Fuzzy Private Information Richard Peter, Andreas Richter, Petra Steinorth December 9, 010 Abstract We examine the demand

More information

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS YALE UNIVERSITY P.O. Box 208268 New Haven, CT 06520-8268

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS YALE UNIVERSITY P.O. Box 208268 New Haven, CT 06520-8268 DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS YALE UNIVERSITY P.O. Box 208268 New Haven, CT 06520-8268 http://www.econ.yale.edu/ Economics Department Working Paper No. 91 EQUILIBRIUM AND STRATEGIC COMMUNICATION IN THE ADVERSE

More information

Competitive Insurance Markets Under Asymmetric Information. When Agents Make Mistakes

Competitive Insurance Markets Under Asymmetric Information. When Agents Make Mistakes Competitive Insurance Markets Under Asymmetric Information When Agents Make Mistakes Mark Browne 1, Richard Peter 2, Andreas Richter 3 Abstract: We analyze a competitive insurance market under asymmetric

More information

Demand for Health Insurance

Demand for Health Insurance Demand for Health Insurance Demand for Health Insurance is principally derived from the uncertainty or randomness with which illnesses befall individuals. Consequently, the derived demand for health insurance

More information

Chapter 21: The Discounted Utility Model

Chapter 21: The Discounted Utility Model Chapter 21: The Discounted Utility Model 21.1: Introduction This is an important chapter in that it introduces, and explores the implications of, an empirically relevant utility function representing intertemporal

More information

Second degree price discrimination

Second degree price discrimination Bergals School of Economics Fall 1997/8 Tel Aviv University Second degree price discrimination Yossi Spiegel 1. Introduction Second degree price discrimination refers to cases where a firm does not have

More information

No Claim Bonus? by John D. Hey*

No Claim Bonus? by John D. Hey* The Geneva Papers on Risk and Insurance, 10 (No 36, July 1985), 209-228 No Claim Bonus? by John D. Hey* 1. Introduction No claim bonus schemes are a prominent feature of some insurance contracts, most

More information

Insurance. Michael Peters. December 27, 2013

Insurance. Michael Peters. December 27, 2013 Insurance Michael Peters December 27, 2013 1 Introduction In this chapter, we study a very simple model of insurance using the ideas and concepts developed in the chapter on risk aversion. You may recall

More information

Choice under Uncertainty

Choice under Uncertainty Choice under Uncertainty Part 1: Expected Utility Function, Attitudes towards Risk, Demand for Insurance Slide 1 Choice under Uncertainty We ll analyze the underlying assumptions of expected utility theory

More information

Optimal Accident Compensation Schemes

Optimal Accident Compensation Schemes Optimal Accident Compensation Schemes Abstract This paper considers the way in which accident compensation is offered as insurance against personal injury due to accidents. We firstly set up a simple microeconomic

More information

Analyzing the Demand for Deductible Insurance

Analyzing the Demand for Deductible Insurance Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 18:3 3 1999 1999 Kluwer Academic Publishers. Manufactured in The Netherlands. Analyzing the emand for eductible Insurance JACK MEYER epartment of Economics, Michigan State

More information

SCREENING IN INSURANCE MARKETS WITH ADVERSE SELECTION AND BACKGROUND RISK. Keith J. Crocker

SCREENING IN INSURANCE MARKETS WITH ADVERSE SELECTION AND BACKGROUND RISK. Keith J. Crocker SCREENING IN INSURANCE MARKETS WIT ADVERSE SEECTION AND BACKGROUND RISK Keith J. Crocker University of Michigan Business School 70 Tappan Street Ann Arbor, MI 4809 and Arthur Snow Department of Economics

More information

Explaining Insurance Policy Provisions via Adverse Selection

Explaining Insurance Policy Provisions via Adverse Selection The Geneva Papers on Risk and Insurance Theory, 22: 121 134 (1997) c 1997 The Geneva Association Explaining Insurance Policy Provisions via Adverse Selection VIRGINIA R. YOUNG AND MARK J. BROWNE School

More information

ECONOMICS AND FINANCE OF PENSIONS Lecture 8

ECONOMICS AND FINANCE OF PENSIONS Lecture 8 ECONOMICS AND FINANCE OF PENSIONS Lecture 8 ANNUITIES MARKETS Dr David McCarthy Today s lecture Why study annuities? Annuity demand Theoretical demand for annuities The demand puzzle Asymmetric information

More information

Regret and Rejoicing Effects on Mixed Insurance *

Regret and Rejoicing Effects on Mixed Insurance * Regret and Rejoicing Effects on Mixed Insurance * Yoichiro Fujii, Osaka Sangyo University Mahito Okura, Doshisha Women s College of Liberal Arts Yusuke Osaki, Osaka Sangyo University + Abstract This papers

More information

Working Paper Series

Working Paper Series RGEA Universidade de Vigo http://webs.uvigo.es/rgea Working Paper Series A Market Game Approach to Differential Information Economies Guadalupe Fugarolas, Carlos Hervés-Beloso, Emma Moreno- García and

More information

Adverse Selection and the Market for Health Insurance in the U.S. James Marton

Adverse Selection and the Market for Health Insurance in the U.S. James Marton Preliminary and Incomplete Please do not Quote Adverse Selection and the Market for Health Insurance in the U.S. James Marton Washington University, Department of Economics Date: 4/24/01 Abstract Several

More information

Notes - Gruber, Public Finance Section 12.1 Social Insurance What is insurance? Individuals pay money to an insurer (private firm or gov).

Notes - Gruber, Public Finance Section 12.1 Social Insurance What is insurance? Individuals pay money to an insurer (private firm or gov). Notes - Gruber, Public Finance Section 12.1 Social Insurance What is insurance? Individuals pay money to an insurer (private firm or gov). These payments are called premiums. Insurer promises to make a

More information

Institute for Empirical Research in Economics University of Zurich. Working Paper Series ISSN 1424-0459. Working Paper No. 229

Institute for Empirical Research in Economics University of Zurich. Working Paper Series ISSN 1424-0459. Working Paper No. 229 Institute for Empirical Research in Economics University of Zurich Working Paper Series ISSN 1424-0459 Working Paper No. 229 On the Notion of the First Best in Standard Hidden Action Problems Christian

More information

1 Uncertainty and Preferences

1 Uncertainty and Preferences In this chapter, we present the theory of consumer preferences on risky outcomes. The theory is then applied to study the demand for insurance. Consider the following story. John wants to mail a package

More information

Financial Markets. Itay Goldstein. Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania

Financial Markets. Itay Goldstein. Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania Financial Markets Itay Goldstein Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania 1 Trading and Price Formation This line of the literature analyzes the formation of prices in financial markets in a setting

More information

3 Introduction to Assessing Risk

3 Introduction to Assessing Risk 3 Introduction to Assessing Risk Important Question. How do we assess the risk an investor faces when choosing among assets? In this discussion we examine how an investor would assess the risk associated

More information

Rafal Borkowski, Hipoteczna 18/22 m. 8, 91-337 Lodz, POLAND, E-mail: r-borkowski@go2.pl

Rafal Borkowski, Hipoteczna 18/22 m. 8, 91-337 Lodz, POLAND, E-mail: r-borkowski@go2.pl Rafal Borkowski, Hipoteczna 18/22 m. 8, 91-337 Lodz, POLAND, E-mail: r-borkowski@go2.pl Krzysztof M. Ostaszewski, Actuarial Program Director, Illinois State University, Normal, IL 61790-4520, U.S.A., e-mail:

More information

Adverse selection and moral hazard in health insurance.

Adverse selection and moral hazard in health insurance. Adverse selection and moral hazard in health insurance. Franck Bien David Alary University Paris Dauphine November 10, 2006 Abstract In this paper, we want to characterize the optimal health insurance

More information

Insurance under moral hazard and adverse selection: the case of pure competition

Insurance under moral hazard and adverse selection: the case of pure competition Insurance under moral hazard and adverse selection: the case of pure competition A. Chassagnon P.A. Chiappori March 1997 Abstract We consider a model of pure competition between insurers a la Rothschild-

More information

Deductibles in Health Insurance: Pay or Pain?

Deductibles in Health Insurance: Pay or Pain? International Journal of Health Care Finance and Economics, 3, 253 266, 2003 C 2003 Kluwer Academic Publishers. Manufactured in The Netherlands. Deductibles in Health Insurance: Pay or Pain? GEIR B. ASHEIM

More information

Price Dispersion. Ed Hopkins Economics University of Edinburgh Edinburgh EH8 9JY, UK. November, 2006. Abstract

Price Dispersion. Ed Hopkins Economics University of Edinburgh Edinburgh EH8 9JY, UK. November, 2006. Abstract Price Dispersion Ed Hopkins Economics University of Edinburgh Edinburgh EH8 9JY, UK November, 2006 Abstract A brief survey of the economics of price dispersion, written for the New Palgrave Dictionary

More information

Department of Mathematics University of Michigan Ann Arbor, Michigan 48109. E-mail: mludkov@umich.edu, vryoung@umich.edu

Department of Mathematics University of Michigan Ann Arbor, Michigan 48109. E-mail: mludkov@umich.edu, vryoung@umich.edu Ex Post Moral Hazard and Bayesian Learning in Insurance Michael Ludkovski 1 and Virginia R. Young Department of Mathematics University of Michigan Ann Arbor, Michigan 48109 E-mail: mludkov@umich.edu, vryoung@umich.edu

More information

Guaranteed Renewability Uniquely Prevents Adverse Selection in Individual Health Insurance

Guaranteed Renewability Uniquely Prevents Adverse Selection in Individual Health Insurance Guaranteed Renewability Uniquely Prevents Adverse Selection in Individual Health Insurance Mark V. Pauly Bendheim Professor Health Care Management Department The Wharton School University of Pennsylvania

More information

Oligopoly: How do firms behave when there are only a few competitors? These firms produce all or most of their industry s output.

Oligopoly: How do firms behave when there are only a few competitors? These firms produce all or most of their industry s output. Topic 8 Chapter 13 Oligopoly and Monopolistic Competition Econ 203 Topic 8 page 1 Oligopoly: How do firms behave when there are only a few competitors? These firms produce all or most of their industry

More information

Endogenous Information and Privacy in Automobile Insurance Markets

Endogenous Information and Privacy in Automobile Insurance Markets BGPE Discussion Paper No. 5 Endogenous Information and Privacy in Automobile Insurance Markets ilia Filipova October 2006 ISSN 1863-5733 Editor: Prof. Regina T. Riphahn, Ph.D. Friedrich-Alexander-University

More information

The Stewardship Role of Accounting

The Stewardship Role of Accounting The Stewardship Role of Accounting by Richard A. Young 1. Introduction One important role of accounting is in the valuation of an asset or firm. When markets are perfect one can value assets at their market

More information

Exam Introduction Mathematical Finance and Insurance

Exam Introduction Mathematical Finance and Insurance Exam Introduction Mathematical Finance and Insurance Date: January 8, 2013. Duration: 3 hours. This is a closed-book exam. The exam does not use scrap cards. Simple calculators are allowed. The questions

More information

How To Find Out If A Person Is More Or Less Confident

How To Find Out If A Person Is More Or Less Confident Web Appendix for Overconfidence, Insurance and Paternalism. Alvaro Sandroni Francesco Squintani Abstract This paper is not self-contained. It is the mathematical appendix of the paper "Overconfidence,

More information

Applied Economics For Managers Recitation 5 Tuesday July 6th 2004

Applied Economics For Managers Recitation 5 Tuesday July 6th 2004 Applied Economics For Managers Recitation 5 Tuesday July 6th 2004 Outline 1 Uncertainty and asset prices 2 Informational efficiency - rational expectations, random walks 3 Asymmetric information - lemons,

More information

Lecture Note 16 Adverse Selection, Risk Aversion and Insurance Markets.

Lecture Note 16 Adverse Selection, Risk Aversion and Insurance Markets. Lecture Note 16 Adverse Selection, Risk Aversion and Insurance Markets. 14.03/14003 Applied Microeconomic Theory and Public Policy, Fall 2010 David Autor, Massachusetts Institute of Technology November

More information

Part 2: Screening and Signaling in Games with Incomplete Information.

Part 2: Screening and Signaling in Games with Incomplete Information. Lecture 9 Part 2: Screening and Signaling in Games with Incomplete Information. 1 Lecture Outline Screening and signaling incentives arise in games where uncertainty is exogenous and some players are better

More information

Research Summary Saltuk Ozerturk

Research Summary Saltuk Ozerturk Research Summary Saltuk Ozerturk A. Research on Information Acquisition in Markets and Agency Issues Between Investors and Financial Intermediaries An important dimension of the workings of financial markets

More information

On the Efficiency of Competitive Stock Markets Where Traders Have Diverse Information

On the Efficiency of Competitive Stock Markets Where Traders Have Diverse Information Finance 400 A. Penati - G. Pennacchi Notes on On the Efficiency of Competitive Stock Markets Where Traders Have Diverse Information by Sanford Grossman This model shows how the heterogeneous information

More information

The gain from insurance (full information)

The gain from insurance (full information) The gain from insurance (full information) W 2 U U 1 E W W 2 W 45 W c E(W ) W 1 W 1 Figure 1: Demand for insurance Risk aversion: u (EW ) >Eu(W ), Risk averse individuals dislike uncertainty Assumptions:

More information

A Simple Model of Price Dispersion *

A Simple Model of Price Dispersion * Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas Globalization and Monetary Policy Institute Working Paper No. 112 http://www.dallasfed.org/assets/documents/institute/wpapers/2012/0112.pdf A Simple Model of Price Dispersion

More information

. In this case the leakage effect of tax increases is mitigated because some of the reduction in disposable income would have otherwise been saved.

. In this case the leakage effect of tax increases is mitigated because some of the reduction in disposable income would have otherwise been saved. Chapter 4 Review Questions. Explain how an increase in government spending and an equal increase in lump sum taxes can generate an increase in equilibrium output. Under what conditions will a balanced

More information

Capital Structure. Itay Goldstein. Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania

Capital Structure. Itay Goldstein. Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania Capital Structure Itay Goldstein Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania 1 Debt and Equity There are two main types of financing: debt and equity. Consider a two-period world with dates 0 and 1. At

More information

Problem Set 9 Solutions

Problem Set 9 Solutions Problem Set 9 s 1. A monopoly insurance company provides accident insurance to two types of customers: low risk customers, for whom the probability of an accident is 0.25, and high risk customers, for

More information

Moral Hazard and Repeated Insurance Contracts

Moral Hazard and Repeated Insurance Contracts Moral Hazard and Repeated Insurance Contracts Chris Robinson The University of Western Ontario Bingyong Zheng Shanghai University of Finance and Economics October 30, 2006 Abstract We develop a model of

More information

EC247 FINANCIAL INSTRUMENTS AND CAPITAL MARKETS TERM PAPER

EC247 FINANCIAL INSTRUMENTS AND CAPITAL MARKETS TERM PAPER EC247 FINANCIAL INSTRUMENTS AND CAPITAL MARKETS TERM PAPER NAME: IOANNA KOULLOUROU REG. NUMBER: 1004216 1 Term Paper Title: Explain what is meant by the term structure of interest rates. Critically evaluate

More information

Not Only What But also When: A Theory of Dynamic Voluntary Disclosure

Not Only What But also When: A Theory of Dynamic Voluntary Disclosure Not Only What But also When: A Theory of Dynamic Voluntary Disclosure Ilan Guttman, Ilan Kremer, and Andrzej Skrzypacz Stanford Graduate School of Business September 2012 Abstract The extant theoretical

More information

The Effect of Ambiguity Aversion on Insurance and Self-protection

The Effect of Ambiguity Aversion on Insurance and Self-protection The Effect of Ambiguity Aversion on Insurance and Self-protection David Alary Toulouse School of Economics (LERNA) Christian Gollier Toulouse School of Economics (LERNA and IDEI) Nicolas Treich Toulouse

More information

Chapter 7. Sealed-bid Auctions

Chapter 7. Sealed-bid Auctions Chapter 7 Sealed-bid Auctions An auction is a procedure used for selling and buying items by offering them up for bid. Auctions are often used to sell objects that have a variable price (for example oil)

More information

How To Understand The Effects Of A Black Box On A Car Insurance Policy

How To Understand The Effects Of A Black Box On A Car Insurance Policy Endogenous Information and Privacy in Automobile Insurance Markets ilia Filipova Beitrag Nr. 284, Mai 2006 Endogenous Information and Privacy in Automobile Insurance Markets ilia Filipova* Universität

More information

ECON 312: Oligopolisitic Competition 1. Industrial Organization Oligopolistic Competition

ECON 312: Oligopolisitic Competition 1. Industrial Organization Oligopolistic Competition ECON 312: Oligopolisitic Competition 1 Industrial Organization Oligopolistic Competition Both the monopoly and the perfectly competitive market structure has in common is that neither has to concern itself

More information

MULTIPLE LOSSES, EX ANTE MORAL HAZARD, AND THE IMPLICATIONS FOR UMBRELLA POLICIES

MULTIPLE LOSSES, EX ANTE MORAL HAZARD, AND THE IMPLICATIONS FOR UMBRELLA POLICIES C The Journal of Risk and Insurance, 2005, Vol. 72, No. 4, 525-538 MULTIPLE LOSSES, EX ANTE MORAL HAZARD, AND THE IMPLICATIONS FOR UMBRELLA POLICIES Michael Breuer ABSTRACT Under certain cost conditions

More information

Screening by the Company You Keep: Joint Liability Lending and the Peer Selection Maitreesh Ghatak presented by Chi Wan

Screening by the Company You Keep: Joint Liability Lending and the Peer Selection Maitreesh Ghatak presented by Chi Wan Screening by the Company You Keep: Joint Liability Lending and the Peer Selection Maitreesh Ghatak presented by Chi Wan 1. Introduction The paper looks at an economic environment where borrowers have some

More information

FAIR TRADE IN INSURANCE INDUSTRY: PREMIUM DETERMINATION OF TAIWAN AUTOMOBILE INSURANCE. Emilio Venezian Venezian Associate, Taiwan

FAIR TRADE IN INSURANCE INDUSTRY: PREMIUM DETERMINATION OF TAIWAN AUTOMOBILE INSURANCE. Emilio Venezian Venezian Associate, Taiwan FAIR TRADE IN INSURANCE INDUSTRY: PREMIUM DETERMINATION OF TAIWAN AUTOMOBILE INSURANCE Emilio Venezian Venezian Associate, Taiwan Chu-Shiu Li Department of Economics, Feng Chia University, Taiwan 100 Wen

More information

Midterm Exam:Answer Sheet

Midterm Exam:Answer Sheet Econ 497 Barry W. Ickes Spring 2007 Midterm Exam:Answer Sheet 1. (25%) Consider a portfolio, c, comprised of a risk-free and risky asset, with returns given by r f and E(r p ), respectively. Let y be the

More information

On the Existence of Nash Equilibrium in General Imperfectly Competitive Insurance Markets with Asymmetric Information

On the Existence of Nash Equilibrium in General Imperfectly Competitive Insurance Markets with Asymmetric Information analysing existence in general insurance environments that go beyond the canonical insurance paradigm. More recently, theoretical and empirical work has attempted to identify selection in insurance markets

More information

Week 7 - Game Theory and Industrial Organisation

Week 7 - Game Theory and Industrial Organisation Week 7 - Game Theory and Industrial Organisation The Cournot and Bertrand models are the two basic templates for models of oligopoly; industry structures with a small number of firms. There are a number

More information

Nonparametric adaptive age replacement with a one-cycle criterion

Nonparametric adaptive age replacement with a one-cycle criterion Nonparametric adaptive age replacement with a one-cycle criterion P. Coolen-Schrijner, F.P.A. Coolen Department of Mathematical Sciences University of Durham, Durham, DH1 3LE, UK e-mail: Pauline.Schrijner@durham.ac.uk

More information

Introduction. Asymmetric Information and Adverse selection. Problem of individual insurance. Health Economics Bill Evans

Introduction. Asymmetric Information and Adverse selection. Problem of individual insurance. Health Economics Bill Evans Introduction Asymmetric Information and Adverse selection Health Economics Bill Evans Intermediate micro build models of individual, firm and market behavior Most models assume actors fully informed about

More information

What we ll be discussing

What we ll be discussing Teaching programmes: Master of Public Health, University of Tromsø, Norway HEL-3007 Health Economics and Policy Master of Public Health, Monash University, Australia ECC-5979 Health Economics Master of

More information

Coverage Denied: Excluding Bad Risks, Inefficiency, and Pooling in Insurance

Coverage Denied: Excluding Bad Risks, Inefficiency, and Pooling in Insurance Coverage Denied: Excluding Bad Risks, Inefficiency, and Pooling in Insurance Hector Chade Arizona State University Department of Economics Edward Schlee Arizona State University Department of Economics

More information

Demand and supply of health insurance. Folland et al Chapter 8

Demand and supply of health insurance. Folland et al Chapter 8 Demand and supply of health Folland et al Chapter 8 Chris Auld Economics 317 February 9, 2011 What is insurance? From an individual s perspective, insurance transfers wealth from good states of the world

More information

Distribution-Based Pricing Formulas. Are Not Arbitrage-Free

Distribution-Based Pricing Formulas. Are Not Arbitrage-Free Author s Response To Michael G. Wacek s Discussion Of a Paper Published In Proceedings Volume XC Distribution-Based Pricing Formulas Are Not Arbitrage-Free By David L. Ruhm Author s reply to discussion

More information

Non-Exclusive Competition in the Market for Lemons

Non-Exclusive Competition in the Market for Lemons Non-Exclusive Competition in the Market for Lemons Andrea Attar Thomas Mariotti François Salanié October 2007 Abstract In order to check the impact of the exclusivity regime on equilibrium allocations,

More information

Online Appendix Feedback Effects, Asymmetric Trading, and the Limits to Arbitrage

Online Appendix Feedback Effects, Asymmetric Trading, and the Limits to Arbitrage Online Appendix Feedback Effects, Asymmetric Trading, and the Limits to Arbitrage Alex Edmans LBS, NBER, CEPR, and ECGI Itay Goldstein Wharton Wei Jiang Columbia May 8, 05 A Proofs of Propositions and

More information

Optimal health insurance contract: Is a deductible useful?

Optimal health insurance contract: Is a deductible useful? Economics Letters 87 (2005) 313 317 www.elsevier.com/locate/econbase Optimal health insurance contract: Is a deductible useful? David Bardey a, T, Romain Lesur b a GREMAQ UMR CNRS 5604-Manufacture des

More information

Genetic Information: Comparing Alternative Regulatory Approaches when Prevention Matters

Genetic Information: Comparing Alternative Regulatory Approaches when Prevention Matters Genetic Information: Comparing Alternative Regulatory Approaches when Prevention Matters Francesca Barigozzi and Dominique Henriet August 2008 Abstract We compare the alternative approaches for regulating

More information

15. Adverse Selection in Insurance Markets

15. Adverse Selection in Insurance Markets ECO 317 Economics of Uncertainty Fall Term 2009 Slides to accompany 15. Adverse Selection in Insurance Markets ADVERSE SELECTION GENERAL ISSUES One party in a trade or contract has advance private information

More information

Financial Institutions I: The Economics of Banking

Financial Institutions I: The Economics of Banking Financial Institutions I: The Economics of Banking Prof. Dr. Isabel Schnabel Gutenberg School of Management and Economics Johannes Gutenberg University Mainz Summer term 2011 V4 1/30 I. Introduction II.

More information

4: SINGLE-PERIOD MARKET MODELS

4: SINGLE-PERIOD MARKET MODELS 4: SINGLE-PERIOD MARKET MODELS Ben Goldys and Marek Rutkowski School of Mathematics and Statistics University of Sydney Semester 2, 2015 B. Goldys and M. Rutkowski (USydney) Slides 4: Single-Period Market

More information

NTA s and the annuity puzzle

NTA s and the annuity puzzle NTA s and the annuity puzzle David McCarthy NTA workshop Honolulu, 15 th June 2010 hello Today s lecture Was billed as Pension Economics But I teach a 70-hour course on pension economics and finance at

More information

What we ll be discussing

What we ll be discussing Teaching programme: Course: Main text: Master of Public Health, University of Tromsø, Norway Health economics and policy (HEL3007) JA Olsen (2009): Principles in Health Economics and Policy, Oxford University

More information

Fund Manager s Portfolio Choice

Fund Manager s Portfolio Choice Fund Manager s Portfolio Choice Zhiqing Zhang Advised by: Gu Wang September 5, 2014 Abstract Fund manager is allowed to invest the fund s assets and his personal wealth in two separate risky assets, modeled

More information

Impact of Genetic Testing on Life Insurance

Impact of Genetic Testing on Life Insurance Agenda, Volume 10, Number 1, 2003, pages 61-72 Impact of Genetic Testing on Life Insurance he Human Genome project generates immense interest in the scientific community though there are also important

More information

Insurance and Public Pensions : (b) Adverse Selection

Insurance and Public Pensions : (b) Adverse Selection Insurance and Public Pensions : (b) Adverse Selection Adverse selection is said to occur if potential buyers of insurance know their own probabilities of loss better than do insurance companies. So suppose

More information

Financial Market Microstructure Theory

Financial Market Microstructure Theory The Microstructure of Financial Markets, de Jong and Rindi (2009) Financial Market Microstructure Theory Based on de Jong and Rindi, Chapters 2 5 Frank de Jong Tilburg University 1 Determinants of the

More information

Inequality, Mobility and Income Distribution Comparisons

Inequality, Mobility and Income Distribution Comparisons Fiscal Studies (1997) vol. 18, no. 3, pp. 93 30 Inequality, Mobility and Income Distribution Comparisons JOHN CREEDY * Abstract his paper examines the relationship between the cross-sectional and lifetime

More information

Why the government should do cost-effectiveness analysis in a health insurance market

Why the government should do cost-effectiveness analysis in a health insurance market Government Why the government should do cost-effectiveness analysis in a health insurance market TILEC, Tilburg University April 17, 2012 Government Outline 1 Motivation 2 3 4 Government 5 6 Government

More information

The Time Value of Money

The Time Value of Money The Time Value of Money This handout is an overview of the basic tools and concepts needed for this corporate nance course. Proofs and explanations are given in order to facilitate your understanding and

More information

Credible Discovery, Settlement, and Negative Expected Value Suits

Credible Discovery, Settlement, and Negative Expected Value Suits Credible iscovery, Settlement, and Negative Expected Value Suits Warren F. Schwartz Abraham L. Wickelgren Abstract: This paper introduces the option to conduct discovery into a model of settlement bargaining

More information

On the effect of taxation in the online sports betting market

On the effect of taxation in the online sports betting market On the effect of taxation in the online sports betting market Juan Vidal-Puga Research Group in Economic Analysis Departamento de Estatística e IO Universidade de Vigo, Spain June 8, 2 We analyze the effect

More information

Saving and the Demand for Protection Against Risk

Saving and the Demand for Protection Against Risk Saving and the Demand for Protection Against Risk David Crainich 1, Richard Peter 2 Abstract: We study individual saving decisions in the presence of an endogenous future consumption risk. The endogeneity

More information

Economics 101A (Lecture 26) Stefano DellaVigna

Economics 101A (Lecture 26) Stefano DellaVigna Economics 101A (Lecture 26) Stefano DellaVigna April 30, 2015 Outline 1. The Takeover Game 2. Hidden Type (Adverse Selection) 3. Empirical Economics: Intro 4. Empirical Economics: Home Insurance 5. Empirical

More information

11.2 Monetary Policy and the Term Structure of Interest Rates

11.2 Monetary Policy and the Term Structure of Interest Rates 518 Chapter 11 INFLATION AND MONETARY POLICY Thus, the monetary policy that is consistent with a permanent drop in inflation is a sudden upward jump in the money supply, followed by low growth. And, in

More information

Participating insurance contracts and the Rothschild-Stiglitz equilibrium puzzle

Participating insurance contracts and the Rothschild-Stiglitz equilibrium puzzle Participating insurance contracts and the Rothschild-Stiglitz equilibrium puzzle Pierre Picard Ecole Polytechnique July 2009 Pierre Picard (Ecole Polytechnique) July 2009 1 / 25 Overview 1 Motivation and

More information

Work incentives and household insurance: Sequential contracting with altruistic individuals and moral hazard

Work incentives and household insurance: Sequential contracting with altruistic individuals and moral hazard Work incentives and household insurance: Sequential contracting with altruistic individuals and moral hazard Cécile Aubert Abstract Two agents sequentially contracts with different principals under moral

More information

Chapter 9 Experience rating

Chapter 9 Experience rating 0 INTRODUCTION 1 Chapter 9 Experience rating 0 Introduction The rating process is the process of deciding on an appropriate level of premium for a particular class of insurance business. The contents of

More information

Decision & Risk Analysis Lecture 6. Risk and Utility

Decision & Risk Analysis Lecture 6. Risk and Utility Risk and Utility Risk - Introduction Payoff Game 1 $14.50 0.5 0.5 $30 - $1 EMV 30*0.5+(-1)*0.5= 14.5 Game 2 Which game will you play? Which game is risky? $50.00 Figure 13.1 0.5 0.5 $2,000 - $1,900 EMV

More information