Specialization Patterns in International Trade

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Specialization Patterns in International Trade"

Transcription

1 Specialization Patterns in International Trade Walter Steingress November 16, 2015 Abstract The pattern of specialization is key to understanding how trade affects the production structure of an economy. To measure specialization, I compute concentration indexes for the value of exports and imports and decompose the overall concentration into the extensive product margin (number of products traded) and intensive product margin (value of products traded). Using detailed product-level trade data for 130 countries, I find that exports are more concentrated than imports, specialization occurs mainly in the intensive product margin, and larger and richer have more diversified exports and imports because they trade more products. Based on these facts, I assess the ability of the Eaton-Kortum model, the workhorse model of modern Ricardian trade theory, to account for the observed patterns. The results show that specialization through comparative advantage induced by technological differences can explain the qualitative and quantitative facts. The key determinants of specialization are: the degree of absolute and comparative advantage, the elasticity of substitution and geography. Keywords: Ricardian Trade Theory, Comparative Advantage, Specialization, Import Concentration, Export Concentration I thank Kristian Behrens, Andriana Bellou, Rui Castro, Jonathan Eaton, Stefania Garetto, Ulrich Hounyo, Joseph Kaboski, Raja Kali, Baris Kaymak, Michael Siemer, Ari Van Assche, Silvana Tenreyro and Michael Waugh for their useful comments and suggestions. This paper also benefited greatly from comments by seminar participants at Boston University, Carleton University, Georgetown, the University of Laval, HEC Montreal and the University of Montreal. All errors are my own. Contact: Banque de France, 31 Rue Croix des Petites Champs, Paris 75001, France ( walter.steingress@banque-france.fr). 1

2 1 Introduction The pattern of specialization is at the core of international trade theory. A consequence of international trade is that countries do not need to produce all their goods: instead they can specialize in the production of certain goods in exchange for others. Trade theory offers different explanations of how countries specialize in the number and sales volume of goods. Assessing the empirical relevance of the underlying theory is of vital interest since it not only allows us to evaluate the gains from trade due to specialization but also informs on how trade affects the structure of an economy. For example, a high degree of specialization increases the likelihood that productspecific shocks will have aggregate effects in terms of output volatility and/or an impact on the terms of trade. 1 The main contribution of this paper is to assess the Eaton and Kortum (2002) model s ability to account for the observed specialization patterns. To do so, the paper first documents facts on the pattern of specialization by computing concentration indexes for both, exports and imports. In addition, it decomposes the overall level of concentration into a measure for the extensive and intensive product margin. The extensive product margin indicates the degree of specialization in the number of goods traded. The concentration index for the intensive margin measures specialization in the value of goods traded. Based on the the resulting stylized facts, it evaluates the model on three basic questions about specialization: What explains the level of specialization in exports and imports? Does specialization occur in the intensive or extensive product margin? How does specialization vary with income across countries? The starting point of my analysis is an empirical assessment of cross-country specialization patterns using several measures of concentration for exports and imports as in Cadot et al. (2011). Based on product-level trade data, the results show that countries specialize more in exports than imports and that specialization occurs predominately on the extensive margin for exports and on the intensive margin for imports. This implies that countries export few products and have their foreign sales fairly equally distributed. On the other, countries import a wide range of products but concentrate their expenditure in a small number of products. The difference between export and import concentration is explained by the fact that countries export fewer goods than they import. Focusing on cross-country differences, the results show that countries with higher income have more diversified imports and exports. This diversification is mostly along the extensive margin, i.e. rich economies export and import a wider product range. 2 Having documented the observed specialization pattern, I then simulate the standard Ricar- 1 An illustrating example is the case of Saudi Arabia s and its dependence on oil, which accounts for 90 percent of its export revenue and 55 percent of its GDP. Thus, any change in the price of oil will likely raise volatility and have important macroeconomic consequences. Papers that study the link between concentration of production and volatility are, for example, Jansen (2004), Koren and Tenreyro (2007), di Giovanni and Levchenko (2012) and Haddad et al. (2013). 2 These results are robust to different levels of aggregation and product classification schemes (NAICS, HS, SITC). 2

3 dian trade model developed by Eaton and Kortum (2002) (henceforth EK) and assess its ability to replicate the stylized facts. Following the standard calibration approach in the literature, the model can reproduce the observed specialization pattern qualitatively but not quantitatively. The obtained levels for exports are too high in comparison to the data. The main reason is the underlying productivity distribution. In the simulated model countries export their goods to too many countries in comparison with the data. However, a key benefit of the model is that it sheds light on the underlying determinants of specialization. The principal factors are trade costs together with technology, the elasticity of substitution and the degree of comparative advantage. To replicate the observed cross-country specialization patterns, trade costs have to be asymmetric trade costs as in Waugh (2010) with poor countries facing higher costs to export than rich countries. At this point, it is important to note that the Ricardian model shares with other models of international trade, most notably monopolistic competition models based on Krugman (1980) and Armington models like Anderson and Van Wincoop (2003), the ability to develop quantitative predictions about specialization patterns in the intensive and extensive product margin (see Hummels and Klenow (2005)). However, in these models, products are differentiated by country of origin by assumption. Instead, in EK suppliers from each country potentially supply the same good and a consumer purchases the good from the cheapest supplier only. Thus, the pattern of specialization arises endogenously. As the paper demonstrates, the presence of trade costs and different technologies across countries allows the model to reproduce the facts on the extensive and intensive margin. This paper contributes to the international trade literature on the relationship between income and trade concentration, see Brenton and Newfarmer (2007), Cadot et al. (2011), Koren and Tenreyro (2013) and Papageorgiou and Spatafora (2012). The evidence presented in these papers shows that developing countries have higher levels of export concentration and that these high levels of concentration may lead to more output volatility, Jansen (2004) and Koren and Tenreyro (2007), and less macroeconomic stability, IMF (2014). The results in this paper confirm previous results on exports and shows that the negative relationship between income and trade concentration extends to imports. The novelty of the paper is that it synthesizes the individual facts on export and import concentration along both, the extensive and intensive, margin and shows that the Ricardian model of Eaton-Kortum (EK) can replicate the observed cross-country patterns. As such, the Eaton-Kortum framework provides theoretical guidance for policy recommendations aimed at increasing trade diversification. The analysis also relates to the growing literature in quantifying the importance of Ricardian comparative advantage in explaining trade patterns using the EK framework, (for example, Shikher (2011), Levchenko and Zhang (2011) and Costinot et al. (2012)). These papers specify a multi-sector Ricardian model with both inter- and intra-industry trade in order to derive implications on a sectoral level. In contrast, I abstract from intra-industry trade and attach a sectoral 3

4 interpretation to the continuum of traded goods within the standard Eaton-Kortum framework. Given this notion, the number of traded sectors arises endogenously and is not fixed as in the previous papers. While the standard model has been primarily used to explain bilateral trade flows and trade volume, (see, for example, Eaton and Kortum (2002), Alvarez and Lucas (2007) and Waugh (2010)), I focus on the implications for the pattern of trade and analyze how technology, geography, tastes and comparative advantage induce countries to specialize in narrow sectors. The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 describes the data and presents the empirical evidence for import and export concentration. Section 3 lays out the theoretical framework. Section 4 describes the calibration and presents the simulation results. Section 5 discusses policy experiments that reduce export concentration. Section 6 shows the robustness of the results and discusses alternative empirical implication based on the Armington assumption. Section 7 concludes. 2 Empirical evidence and data The starting point of my analysis is an empirical assessment of the observed specialization patterns in world trade using detailed product-level trade data. Before describing the data and the empirical evidence, I examine the properties of the concentration measurements used, which form the basis for the qualitative and quantitative tests of the model. 2.1 Concentration measurements I compute two measures of specialization for product level sales, the Gini coefficient and the Theil index. For concreteness, I focus on exports - concentration measures for imports are entirely analogous. The two measurements are defined as follows. Let k index a product among the N products found in the world economy, let r ik be the corresponding export sales revenue, say, in a given country i. The export Gini in this country is defined as: G ix = 1 1 l=1 N x il x il 1 N k=1 N r ik (1) where x il = l k=1 r ik are the cumulative export revenues and indexed in increasing order of size, i.e. r ik < r ik+1. N denotes the total number of products in the world. The Gini coefficient ranges between zero and one. Zero expresses complete diversification, i.e. (1) a country exports all products and (2) each product generates the same amount of revenues. An index of one indicates complete specialization in which case export revenues stem from one product only. The Gini coefficient is independent of scale, follows the principle of population and adheres to the Weak Principle of Transfers, see Cowell (2009). Scale independence (multiplying each observation by a constant does not change the index) 4

5 ensures that cross-country differences in the Gini are solely due to differences in the shape of the export revenues distributions and do not depend on the level or unit of export sales. The Principle of Population (doubling the sample population does not change the index) minimizes the impact of the aggregation bias due to product classification standards in the trade data, in particular proportional changes in the level of disaggregation do not change the concentration index. 3 Differences in the concentration index between countries can stem from two underlying mechanisms. Either a country exports more products relative to another (i.e. differences in the extensive margin) or, given that two countries export the same number of products, the distribution of export revenues of one country is more skewed in comparison to another country (differences in the intensive margin). 4 Because the Gini index does not allow for this distinction, we use the Theil index as an alternative concentration measure. To capture differences in the intensive product margin, we define the intensive Theil as follows: Tix Int = 1 N ix r N ix ik ln r k=1 ix ( rik r ix ) (2) where N ix denotes the number of exported products by country i and r ix = N ix k=1 r ik represents the mean export revenue of country i. The intensive Theil index measures the concentration in export sales by a weighted average of the log distance from the mean. In addition, we define the extensive Theil of country i as follows: T Ext ix ( ) N = ln N ix where N ix denotes the number of products exported and N the total number of products in the world. Thus, the concentration between two countries may simply differ because one country exports more products. To assess the relative importance of each margin in terms of overall concentration, we sum the extensive and the intensive component to get the total Theil index, which is equal to: T ix = T Int ix + T Ext ix = 1 N N k=1 ( ) r ik rik ln R ix R ix where R ix = 1 N N k=1 r ik represents the mean export revenue over all products N. 5 (3) (4) The total Theil index takes the value of zero in the case of complete diversification, i.e. exporting all products (N ix = N) and export revenues are equal for all products, ( R ix = r ik, k). In the case of complete specialization, one product generates all export revenues, (N ix = 1, r ik = r ik, R ik = r ik /N ) 3 In the appendix we show that our results are robust to different levels of aggregation (4 digit versus 6 digit) and different classification systems (SITC versus HS). 4 The Weak Principle of Transfers ensures that if the export revenue of a low selling product increases by the same amount a high selling product decreases its revenue, then the export revenue distribution becomes less skewed and concentration decreases. 5 In the appendix, we show that the sum of the intensive and the extensive component indeed imply the total Theil index given in equation 4. 5

6 and the index takes a value of ln(n). As the Gini index, the Theil is scale independent and adheres to the Principle of Population and the Weak Principle of Transfers. The advantage of the decomposition is that we can focus on differences in the underlying factors that determine overall concentration. This distinction is important from a policy perspective because higher export concentration is associated with higher volatility in export earnings, see Jansen (2004) and Koren and Tenreyro (2007), and may result in lower GDP growth, see Ramey and Ramey (1994). If concentration is mainly determined by the extensive margin, the main policy objective to reduce concentration consists of developing new export products, see Cadot et al. (2011). On the other hand, if the intensive margin is dominant, then the policy implication may be to export existing products to more destination countries in order to balance export revenues across products. Later, the Model section shows the determinants of concentration within the EK framework and discusses potential policy solutions facts about specialization This section establishes 3 facts about specialization. First, exports are more concentrated than imports. Second, the extensive margin determines the gap between export and import concentration. Third, cross-country patterns imply a negative relationship between concentration and income for both, exports and imports. To build the empirical evidence, I use the BACI data set provided by CEPII (Gaulier and Zignago (2009)) and choose the digit HS product classification scheme as the preferred level of disaggregation. I follow Hummels and Klenow (2005) and refer to import flows of the same 6-digit product from different trading partners as different varieties of the same product. I assume that the tradable goods sector corresponds to the manufacturing sector. 6 Using a correspondence table provided by Feenstra et al. (1997), I identify a total of 4,529 tradable products. Data on employment, capital and GDP per capita at international (PPP) prices come from the Penn World Table, see Heston et al. (2009). The baseline sample covers 130 countries representing all regions and all levels of development between 1995 and 2011 (17 years). In total, the sample consists of 2210 observations (country-years). Note that when assessing the model, I assume that a 6 digit HS code corresponds to a product in the model. The model is Ricardian and does not feature intra-industry trade flows within the product. However, in the data some countries export and import the same product. To address the discrepancy between the model and the data, I consider net trade flows instead of total trade flows. That is, I compute net exports for each product-country pair and consider a country as an exporter of a product if net exports are positive and as an importer otherwise. To measure the 6 This is a simplification, but it is reasonable as a first-order approximation because, for all countries in the sample, this represents on average 76 percent of all merchandise imports; the median is 91 percent. 6

7 importance of net trade flows relative to total trade flows, I calculate for each country the share of net trade flows with respect to total trade following the intra-industry measure of Grubel and Lloyd (1975). My results indicate an average intra-industry share of 19 percent. In terms of total value in world trade, the sum of all net trade value represents 66 percent of the total value in world trade. Both findings suggest that net trade flows are a reasonable approximation of total trade flows, particularly for developing countries where the share of intra-industry trade is very small. 7 Table 1: Summary statistics of the average concentration indexes for 130 countries over the period Concentration Gini Theil Exports Theil Imports Exports Imports Extensive Intensive Extensive Intensive Total Margin Margin Margin Margin Total Level Share of total 55% 45% 40% 60% Regression log(gdp per capita) *** *** *** *** *** *** *** [ ] [ ] [0.0414] [0.0383] [0.0539] [0.0381] [0.0166] [0.0410] log(population) *** *** *** *** *** *** [ ] [ ] [0.0240] [0.0250] [0.0348] [0.0299] [0.0196] [0.0325] Observations R-squared Based on net trade flows at the product level, I calculate concentration indexes for each country on all margins for each year and then take the average over the whole sample period. Because the concentration indexes used are independent of scale, the calculation on a year-to-year basis avoids the need to deflate the data. Table 1 summarizes the sample statistics by giving the average yearby-year indexes of the 130 countries. Fact 1: Exports are more concentrated than imports The summary statistics reveal that exports are more concentrated than imports on all margins. In terms of overall concentration, the Gini coefficients of exports is 0.98 and of imports 0.91 and the respective Theil indexes are 4.73 of exports and 2.71 of imports. The results also show that the gap between export and import 7 One reason for the discrepancy between the model and the data is that the level of aggregation in the data is too high. In the appendix I present an alternative approach, where I partition the continuum of goods in the model into product categories (think of HS or SITC codes) using a Poisson process. By aggregating several goods of the model randomly into a product category, two way trade may occur because some of the goods may be exported and some imported. This procedure allows examining specialization patterns based on total trade flows rather than net trade flows. In the rest of the paper, I follow the net trade flow approach. I present the estimation and results of the alternative procedure in the appendix. 7

8 Export Concentration Gini index HS 6 digit Mean of the index from KWT AGO BDI BOL BHR AZE BEN BGD CMR CPV COD CAF ECU ISL ARM BFA CHL CRI DOM KAZ GHA HND NGAETH JAM QAT FJI PRYMWI RWA TKM GMB LAO GNB MDG GEO MLT KGZ MRT NERSTP TCD TTO UZB YEM VENPER MUS TZAUGA SEN NPL SAU URY OMN MAR ALB BLR GTM IRL SLV LKA IRNMDA PHL BIH KEN SYR PAK CYP EGY COL ARG JOR NZL TUN HRV FIN ISR LBN LTUMEX CAN AUS EST LVA VNM PAN RUS UKR MYS SGP ROU ZAF NOR SVK BRA BGRGRC HUN KOR PRT IDN THA SVN SWE TUR CHE JPN HKG POL DNK CZE IND AUT CHN ESPBEL GBR NLD USA FRA GER ITA Import Concentration LCA BRN GAB MDV KNA TJK Export Concentration Total Theil index HS 6 digit Mean of the index from AGO BDI NER CAF COD JAMDV MRT TJK KNA GMB GABBRN TCD GNB TTO GHA KWT CMR CPV RWA BFA BEN ISLETH UGAQATKGZ ARM STP BOL CHL ECU BHR LCA PER NGA TZA PRY SEN YEM MWI UZB LAO MLT TKM CRI SAU MUS JOR KAZ MDGAZE NPL IRN HND LBN FJI GEO SGP CYP ARG VENDOM BGD ALB CAN GTM IRL MDA AUSKEN ISR BIH HKG OMN URY SLV PHL PAN MAR LVA MEX GRC NZL TUN MYS COL BLR HRVHUN FIN NOR EGY LTU LKA EST PAK PRT RUS ZAF VNM UKR SYR SVK ESP BRA ROU KOR POL FRA SVN TUR DNK SWE BGRTHA CZE AUT IDN GBR BEL CHE IND JPN NLDUSA GER CHN ITA Import Concentration (a) Gini coefficient (b) Theil index Export concentration index HS 6 digit Mean of the index from Import concentration index HS 6 digit Mean of the index from Extensive Theil index GNBTCD BDI STPRWA CPV AGO BEN GMB MDV KNA CAF MWI LCA BFA COD ETH GAB MRT TKM YEMUGA BRN NER AZENGA LAOQAT ARM BOL KWT GHA CMR JAMTJK SEN PRY TZA OMN ALB FJIGEO MDGBHRISL KGZ CYP KAZ UZB TTO LBN ECU BIH DOM BGD GRC GTM HND JOR MLT SLV VEN SAU MUS NPL MDA KEN URY PAN IRN CRI CHL HRV LKA LVA EGY LTU MAR PER SYR EST COL NOR TUN BLRNZL HKG AUSARG ROU BGR CAN ISR DNK HUN PAK FINMEX IRL PHL POL PRT VNM RUS AUT SVN SGP SVK UKR TUR BEL CZE IDN CHE ESP BRA MYS NLDGBR SWE ZAF THA FRAKOR USA ITA IND GER CHN JPN Extensive Theil index STP GNB TCD CAF LAO RWA ARM COD BDI TKM GMB CPV KGZMRT NER NPL MWI UZB BFA GEO BEN FJI AZE AGO MDA BIH YEM ALB UGA CMR BLR CHNBHR EST ETH SEN QAT TJK SYR KAZ MDG TZA GHA GER LVA BGRDOM HND ITA JAM JPN KNA LTU MUS PAK KEN IND CYP FRA CZE IDN BOL BGD CRI ISL KOR IRN KWT LCA LKA JOR ARG AUT BRA BEL BRN ESPEGY GTM FIN CAN CHE CHL COL DNK ECU GBR GAB HRV AUS HUN LBN MDV PRYOMN MLT SVN URY UKR VNM SLV TTO USA NGANLD ROU POL MAR PER SWE SVK THA TUR TUN RUS ZAF IRL ISR MYS PHL PRT VEN MEX NOR NZL GRC SGP SAU HKG PAN Intensive Theil index Intensive Theil index (c) Export Concentration (d) Import Concentration Figure 1: Average export versus import concentration for the period 1995 to 2011 for 130 countries concentration is mainly due to the fact that countries export few and import many products. These result also holds for the majorities of countries, see Figures 1(a) and 1(b). In case of the United States, China, Germany, Hong Kong, India, Italy and Panama export and import concentration are almost equal. Fact 2: Extensive product margin is more important for exports and the intensive product margin for imports Turning to the decomposition, Table 1 shows that for exports the main driver of concentration is the extensive product margin with a share of 55 percent. Thus, export concentration is more sensitive to changes in the number of products exported rather than to changes in export revenues. This result is in line with existing evidence on the importance of the extensive product margin on the level of export revenues, see Hummels and Klenow (2005) for product and Eaton et al. (2011) for firm level evidence. On the other hand, for imports the intensive product margin has a higher share with 60 percent in terms of overall concentration. Countries import a wide range of products, thus changes in the import expenditure are the main contributor to changes in overall import concentration. However, there are significant cross country differences in the relative importance of each margin, see 1(c) and 1(d). 8

9 Fact 3: Concentration declines with income and size In terms of cross-country differences, the empirical evidence shows that richer and larger countries diversify more than smaller ones. Table 1 states the estimated coefficients when regressing the log of GDP per capita and the log of population onto the concentration indexes. The Gini as well as the Theil index of both, exports and imports, decrease as GDP per capita and size increase, i.e. smaller and poorer countries are more specialized. This relationship is equally pronounced for exports and for imports, with an R square of 0.63 and 0.66 respectively. Turning the attention to the decomposition reveals that the main driver of the negative relationship is the extensive product margin. The R square for exports is 0.76 and for imports Thus, richer and larger countries are more diversified because they export and import more products. These results differ from Cadot et al. (2011) in two important ways. They find that (1) the intensive Theil dominates the extensive Theil, and (2) the extensive Theil is decreasing in income until GDP per capita reaches a certain level after which the index starts to increase. The underlying reason for the difference in the importance of the extensive versus the intensive margin comes from the fact this study is build on net trade flows rather than gross trade flows as in Cadot et al. (2011). Table 12 in the appendix replicates Table 1 for gross trade flows and the results are similar to Cadot et al. (2011). However, there are key differences: (1) I focus on the cross section rather than on the panel and (2) I include the log of population as an additional regressor in Table 1. The reason I am focusing on the cross section is that the model I am assessing has implications on cross-country differences but no dynamic implications. Including population as a control variable allows me to look at the functional relationship between GDP per capita and concentration by controlling for size effects. Figure 2 shows that this relation is negative log-linear rather than a hump shape as in Cadot et al. (2011). However, in line with Cadot et al. I also find that extensive product margin is at the origin of this relationship, 2(c) and 2(d). In general, the theoretical explanation of why larger countries export more products are based on the Armington assumptions, see Hummels and Klenow (2005) and Koren and Tenreyro (2013). However, in these type of models, by assumption tradable goods are differentiated by location of production and each country is the sole producer of a good. In contrast, in the EK model all countries potentially supply the same good and consumer purchase the good from the cheapest supplier only. The next section presents the relevant parts of the Alvarez and Lucas (2007) extension of the Eaton-Kortum framework and highlights the key features that allows the model to reproduce the stylized facts. 9

10 Export Concentration COD Total Theil index HS 6 digit Mean of the index from AGO BDI NER CAF ETH TCD TJK NGA MRT BFA RWA UGA GHA CMR JAM GMB TZA BEN YEM UZB MWI GNB NPL SEN BGD KGZ BOL ARM ECU PER GAB MDG LAO PRY MDV IRNCHL PHL TKM PAN TTO KWT KAZ SAU CPV AZE LCA BRN KEN HND VNM PAKGEO JOR IND STP GTM MAR DOM KNA VEN ARG QAT MEX LBN ZAF CRI RUS SLV MDA ALB EGY BRA BHR MYS ISL HKG SGP CAN AUS UKRCOL MUS MLT SYR FJI LKABIH IDN CHN TUN THA URY OMN ISR BLR GRC IRL TUR KOR LVA NZL ESP ROU POL HUN FRA CYP PRT FIN GBR NOR JPN USA LTU HRV SVK BGR SWE EST CZE DNKGER BEL CHE AUT SVN ITA NLD Log of GDP per capita coef = , (robust) se = , t = Import Concentration COD GNB Total Theil index HS 6 digit Mean of the index from STP TCD ARM IND CAF NER TJK BEN PHL BDI BFA RWA GMB MRT LAO MWI NPL KGZ GEO TKM YEM AGO UZB CHN CPV AZE MYS MLT USA SEN ETHMDGTZA UGA CMR KEN BGD PAK OMN ITA GER GHA NGA MDA SYR VNM PRY ALB THA HND FJI BIH LCA KAZ IDN SLV BOL JOR LKA EGY MDVUKR DOM KNA JAM LBN IRN ZAF BRA BHR HKG JPN QAT ISR RUS KOR ECU GAB COL GTM MAR PER TUN CRI MUS VEN BGR BLR TTO URY LVA LTUTUR MEX HUN IRL BRN KWT NLD SGP GBR SAU EST ARG SVK ROUCHLPOL HRV SVN PRT CZE GRC BEL CHE NZL ISL FIN ESP DNK SWE AUT FRA AUS CAN NOR CYP Log of GDP per capita coef = , (robust) se = , t = 6.62 PAN (a) Overall concentration of exports (b) Overall concentration of imports Extensive Theil index HS 6 digit Mean of the index from Extensive Theil index HS 6 digit Mean of the index from Export Concentration COD TCD BDI RWA AGO ETH GNB CAF MWI BFA BENNGA UGA NER YEM GMB TZA MRT CPV STP GHA CMR TKM SEN MDG BGD LAO BOL AZE UZB MDV GAB NPL TJK ARM PRYJAM KEN KGZ GEO EGY VEN KAZ IRN SAU KWT SLV MDA HND VNM PAK JOR IND LKA GTM MAR ALB PHLLCA PER DOM BRN QAT KNA LBN COL FJI BIH IDN CHNBRA TTO CHLMEX OMN ARGRUS GRC UKR TUNCRI PAN MUS ZAF BHR BLR ROU TUR AUS THA HRVPOL CYPISL LVA LTU MYS MLT PRT ESP HKG CAN USA NZL BGR HUN ISRKORFRA GBR NOR JPN ESTSVK CZE FIN IRL ITA SGP GER DNK SWE BEL AUT NLD CHE SVN Import Concentration COD GNB STP TCD CAF LAO RWA BDI ARM NER GMB MWI NPLMRT TKM KGZ BFA BEN UZB CPV GEO YEM AGO FJIAZE CHN ETH UGA MDGTZA SEN TJK CMR MDA IND BIH NGA KEN GHA SYR PAK ALB GER KAZ BGD VNM BLR ITA JPN USA IDN UKR HND SLV BOL PRY LKA DOM JOR PHL GTM MAR JAM EGY ECU PER TUN LBN ZAF BGR THA IRN BRA LVA LTU EST COL CRI MUS URY TUR ROU TTO MYS ARG MDV LCA KNAVEN MLT MEX OMN POL BHR QAT RUS KORFRA SVK HUN SVN CZE ESP KWT NLD GBR GAB CHL HRV PAN CYP SAU PRT ISR SWE BEL GRC NZL ISL FIN DNK AUT CHE IRLAUS CAN HKG BRN SGP NOR Log of GDP per capita coef = , (robust) se = , t = Log of GDP per capita coef = , (robust) se = , t = 8.7 (c) Extensive product margin of exports (d) Extensive product margin of imports Intensive Theil index HS 6 digit Mean of the index from Intensive index HS 6 digit Mean of the index from Export Concentration COD TJK PAN NER JAM AGO PER TTO CHL SGP PHL CAF MRTCMR KGZ ECU ZAF MYS GHA LCA ARG MLT NPL MDG GMB TZA SEN BGD HND VNM PAK BOL ARM UZB CRI IRN ISL ISR IRL HKG BRN KWT CAN JOR IND PRY KNA GAB MUS MDV UGANGA BDI KEN LAO MDA GEO UKR LBNTHA KAZ MEX BHR RUS KOR AUS BRA SAU QAT ETHBFASLV YEM SYR FJI GTM URY MAR TUN DOM BLR LVA HUN NZLFIN FRA BIH IDN COL CHN VEN SVK ESP JPN SWE LKAAZE ALB EGY BGR BEN TKM ROU LTU EST TUR CYP PRT OMN POLSVN CZE GRCDNK GBR CHE BELGER NOR USA HRV AUT NLD MWI TCD RWA CPV ITA GNB STP Import Concentration COD PHL TJK IND MLT MYS HKG LCA BRN SGP MDV OMN ISR IRL USA TCD GNB BEN NER ETHMDG BFASLV TZA NGA KEN SEN BGD YEM STPUGA GHA CMR MRT HND AGO PAK VNM ARM PRY KNA GAB BOL GEO JOR EGY LBNTHA SAU ECU LKA GTM BDI MWI GMB SYR MAR JAM AZE IDN UZB PER TUN ALB UKR DOM COL ZAF CHN VEN CRI IRN BRA TTO BHR MEX HUN GRC NZL MUS KAZ CHL CAF RWA NPL KGZ CPV TKMBGR URY ROU LTU ARG TUR SVK RUSPRT ISL KOR FIN LVAEST HRV CZE DNK BEL ITA KWT CHE NLD QAT AUS GBR ESP SWE AUT CAN GER NOR JPN POLSVN FRA MDA BIH BLR CYP LAO FJI PAN Log of GDP per capita coef = , (robust) se = , t = Log of GDP per capita coef = , (robust) se = , t = 3.6 (e) Intensive product margin of exports (f) Intensive product margin of imports Figure 2: Average export and import concentration versus GDP per capita across 130 countries. Note: Each point in the scatter plots represents the difference from the average concentration index and the log of GDP per capita relative to the United States. The data have been adjusted to remove country size (population) effects. 10

11 3 Model The Eaton Kortum model is Ricardian, with a continuum of goods produced under a constantreturns technology. In this paper, I focus on the Alvarez and Lucas (2007) model and include capital as in Waugh (2010). Next, I derive the relevant theoretical predictions on the pattern of trade and evaluate the importance of the key model parameters for import and export specialization. Consider a world economy with I countries, where each country produces tradable intermediate goods as well as non-tradable composite and final goods. Following Alvarez and Lucas (2007), I define x = (x 1,..., x I ) as a vector of technology draws for any given tradable good and refer to it as good x with x R I +. The production of an intermediate good in country i is defined by: q i (x i ) = x θ i [k α i s1 α i ] β q 1 β mi. Technology x i differs between goods and is drawn independently from a common exponential distribution with density φ and a country specific technology parameter λ i, i.e. x i exp(1/λ i ). I denote the interest rate by r i, the wage by w i and the price of the intermediate aggregate good by p m,i. The intermediate good sector is perfectly competitive. Producers of the intermediate good minimize input costs and sell the tradable intermediate good at price p i (x i ) = Bxi θ[rα i w1 α i ] β p 1 β mi. The continuum of intermediate input good x goes into the production of the composite good q i symmetrically with a constant elasticity of substitution (η > 0) [ˆ η/(1 η) q i = q(x) φ(x)dx] 1 1/η. 0 The aggregate output of intermediate good q i can then be allocated at no cost to the production of final goods or can be used as an input in the production of other intermediate goods. Similarly, capital and labor can be used either to produce intermediate or final goods. Finally, consumers draw utility linearly from the final good. All markets are perfectly competitive. Since these features are not central to the implications I derive in this paper, I omit them. I refer interested readers to Alvarez and Lucas (2007) for a full description of the model. 3.1 General equilibrium Once a country opens up to international goods markets, intermediate goods are the only goods traded. Final goods are not traded and capital and labor are immobile between countries. Trading intermediate goods between countries is costly. We define Iceberg transportation costs for good x from country i to country j by κ ij where κ ij < 1 i = j and κ ii = 1 i. As in Alvarez and Lucas (2007), we also consider tariffs. ω ij is the tariff levied by country i on goods imported 11

12 from country j. Incorporating the trade costs, composite good producers in country i will buy the intermediate good x from country j that offers the lowest price p i (x) = B min j [rα j w1 α j κ ij ω ij ] β p 1 β mj x θ j. (5) Equation 5 shows that whether country i specializes in the production of good x depends on the productivity realizations, factor prices and trade costs. If country i does not offer a good at the lowest cost in the local market, the good is imported. Following Alvarez and Lucas, the resulting price index of tradable goods in country i is p mi = (AB) I j=1 [rα j w1 α j κ ij ω ij ] β p 1 β mj 1/θ λ j θ. (6) Next, we calculate the expenditure shares for each country i. Let D ij be the fraction of country i s per capita spending p mi q i on tradables that is spent on goods from country j. Then, we can write total spending of i on goods from j as ˆ p mi q i D ij = p i (x)q i (x)φ(x)dx B ij where B ij defines the set of goods country j attains as a minimum in equation 5. Note that D ij is simply the probability that country j is selling good x in country i at the lowest price and calculated to be D ij = (AB) 1/θ [rα j w1 α j ] β p 1 β mj p mi κ ij ω ij 1/θ λ j. (7) Equation 7 shows that in this model the sensitivity of trade between countries i and j depends on the level of technology λ, trade costs ω, geographic barriers κ and the technological parameter θ (reflecting the heterogeneity of goods in production) and is independent of the elasticity of substitution η. This result is due to the assumption that η is common across countries and does not distort relative good prices across countries. Note also that, by the law of large numbers, the probability that country i imports from country j is identical to the share of goods country i imports from j. In this sense, trade shares respond to costs and geographic barriers on the extensive margin: as a source becomes more expensive or remote it exports/imports a narrower range of goods. It is important to keep in mind that the number of intermediate input industries that enter into the production of the composite good is fixed. Each country uses the whole continuum of intermediate goods to produce composite goods. There are no gains from trade due to an increased number of varieties. Welfare gains are realized through incomplete specialization. Domestic production competes with imports and countries specialize through the reallocation of resources made available by the exit of inefficient domestic producers. 12

13 To close the model, we impose that total payments to foreigners (imports) are equal to total receipts from foreigners (exports) for all countries i L i p mi q i I I D ij ω ij = L j p mj q j D ji ω ji (8) j=1 j=1 The previous equation implies an excess demand system which depends only on wages. Solving this system, describes the equilibrium wage for each country together with the corresponding equilibrium prices and quantities. Next, I describe the calibration and the simulation of the model. 4 Calibration and results To simulate the theoretical model, which assumes an infinite amount of goods, I "discretize" the Fréchet distribution of total factor productivity and calculate the respective trade value for each product x. Regarding the parameters of the model, we need values for α, β, γ, η and θ. For α, β and γ, I use the same values as Alvarez and Lucas (2007): I set the capital share to α = 0.3, the share of value added in the tradable goods sector to β = 0.5 and the share of value added in the production of non-tradable final goods to α = To calibrate the elasticity of substitution (η) and the variance of the productivity distribution (θ), I use more recent estimates from the literature. In line with Simonovska and Waugh (2011) and Bas et al. (2015), I set θ = 0.25 and η = 4. The remaining parameters that need to be calibrated are trade costs and technology. To do so, I follow Waugh (2010) and use the structural log-linear gravity equation, which relates bilateral trade shares to trade costs and model s structural parameters. To derive the relationship, I simply divide each country i s trade share from country j, see equation 7, by country i s home trade share. Taking logs yields I 1 equations for each country i : log ( Dij D ii ) = S j S i + 1 θ log(κ ij) + 1 θ log(ω ij) (9) in which S i represents the structural parameters and is defined as S i = log([ri αw1 α i ] β/θ p (1 β)/θ mi λ i ). In order to estimate the trade costs κ and technology λ implied by equation 9 I use data on bilateral trade shares across 130 countries. I follow Bernard et al. (2003) and calculate the corresponding bilateral trade share matrix as the ratio of total gross imports of country i from country j, M ij, divided by absorption Abs i D ij = M ij Abs i. Absorption is defined as total gross manufacturing output plus total imports, M i, minus total exports, X i. To compute absorption, I use gross manufacturing output data from UNIDO. 8 Combined with trade data from BACI, I get the expenditure share, D ij, which equals the value of the 8 Details are provided in the appendix. 13

14 inputs consumed by country i and imported from country j divided by the total value of inputs in country i. Note that instead of focusing on a particular year, I compute the expenditure share for each year of the period and take the average expenditure share over the sample period. 9 In total, there are only I 2 I informative moments and I 2 parameters of interest. Thus, restrictions to the parameter space are necessary. To create them, I follow Eaton and Kortum (2002) and assume the following functional form of trade costs. log ( κ ij ) = bij + d k + ω ij + ex j + ɛ ij Trade costs are a logarithmic function of distance (d k ) a shared border effect between country i and j (b ij ), a tariff charged by country i to country j and an exporter fixed effect (ex j ). Tariff (ω ij ) represents the weighted average ad valorem tariff rate applied by country i to country j. The distance function is represented by a step function divided into 6 intervals. Intervals are in miles: [0, 375); [375, 750); [750, 1,500); [1,500, 3,000); [3,000, 6,000); and [6,000, maximum]. ɛ ij reflects barriers to trade arising from all other factors and is orthogonal to the regressors. The distance and common border variables are obtained from the comprehensive geography database compiled by CEPII. To recover technology, I use the estimated trade costs, ˆκ, and structural parameters, Ŝ, to compute the implied tradable good prices, ˆp m, by rewriting equation 6 in terms of Ŝ: ( I ˆp mi = (AB) ( ) θ ) 1/θ eŝj ˆκ ij ω ij j=1 From the obtained prices and the estimates Ŝ i, I get the convolution of wages and technology. Given the bilateral trade shares D ij and the balanced trade condition in equation 8, I follow Alvarez and Lucas (2007) and use the relationship between factor payments and total revenue to calculate equilibrium wages. 10 ( 1 w i = (1 s f i )L i ) ( I j=1 ) (1 s f j ) L j w j D ji ω ji F j where s f i is the share of labor in the production of final goods s f i = γ(1 (1 β)f i ) (1 γ)βf i + γ(1 (1 β)f i ) 9 The resulting sample consists of 130 times 129 potential observations if each country trades with all other countries. In our sample the total number of observations is implying a small number of zeros in the bilateral matrix. I conduct a robustness test where I estimate the model with the Poisson estimator proposed by Silva and Tenreyro (2006). The results are similar and are available upon request. 10 Given factor endowments and optimal factor choice, the interest rates equals: r i = α/(1 α)w i (L i /K i ) 14

15 Table 2: Estimation Results Summary Statistics Observations TSS SSR R E E Geographical barriers Barrier Paremeter estimate Standard error % effect on cost [0,375) % [375,740) % [750,1500) % [1500,3000) % [3000,6000) % [6000,max) % Tariff % Shared border % Note: All parameters were estimated by OLS for an estimated parameter ˆb, the implied percentage effect on costs is 100 (e θb 1) with θ = and F i is the fraction of country i spending on tradable goods net of tariff expenses. F i = I D ji ω ji j=1 The obtained equilibrium wages together with tradable good prices, determine the implied technology levels ˆλ for each country given the structural estimates of the gravity equation. Table 2 summarizes the regression outcome of the gravity equation. In terms of fitting bilateral trade flows, I obtain an R 2 of 0.82, which is slightly lower than the R 2 of 0.83 reported by Waugh. The coefficients obtained for trade costs are consistent with the gravity literature, where distance and tariffs are an impediment to trade. The magnitudes of the coefficients reported in Table 2 are similar to those in Eaton and Kortum (2002) and in Waugh (2010), which consider a similar sample of countries without tariffs. The overall size of the trade costs in percentage terms are higher than those reported in Anderson and Van Wincoop (2004) and Waugh (2010). The main reason for the higher cost effect lies in the underlying trade elasticity. Waugh (2010) uses an elasticity of 5.5 whereas this paper uses The trade elasticity equals to 1 θ, see equation 9. 15

16 4.1 Results Next, I feed the model with the estimated trade costs and technology levels. 12 Table 3 shows the mean concentration levels for the simulated countries. The results show that the calibrated model replicates the Fact 1, i.e. countries are more concentrated in exports than in imports on all margins. However, the levels of export concentration are almost twice as high as the ones observed in the data: mean export (import) concentration on the extensive product margin is 5.04 (0.82) compared to 2.60 (1.10) in the data. This implies that, in the simulated model, countries export (import) 0.8 (43.2) percent of the product space compared to 7.4 (33.3) percent in the data. On the hand, the simulated import levels are close to the one observed in the data. Table 3: Summary statistics of the average simulated concentration indexes for 130 countries. Concentration Gini Theil Exports Theil Imports Exports Imports Extensive Intensive Extensive Intensive Total Margin Margin Margin Margin Total Level Share of total 62% 38% 30% 70% Correlation Regression (Simulation θ = 0.25, η = 4)) log(gdppc) *** *** *** *** [0.0010] [0.0023] [0.0305] [0.0500] [0.0524] [0.0190] [0.0108] [0.0244] log(population) *** * *** *** *** *** [0.0016] [0.0034] [0.0455] [0.0747] [0.0783] [0.0283] [0.0162] [0.0364] Observations R-squared Turing the attention to the decomposition shows that consistent with Fact 2, the extensive product margin is more important for exports and the intensive product margin for imports. In quantitative terms, the share of the extensive margin of exports (imports) is 62% (30%) compared to 55% (40%) in the data. This result reflects the previous point that, in the model, countries specialize much more in the extensive margin of exports relative to the intensive margin. On the import side, the opposite is true. The lower part of Table 3 shows the simulated relationship between income per capita, size and trade concentration. The model can replicate Fact 3 (Concentration declines with income and size) for exports but not for imports. Also in line with the empirical evidence is that the negative relationship is driven by the extensive margin with a strikingly similar elasticity between income and export concentration. Next, I plot the corresponding cross-country pattern for simulated and empirically observed concentration levels against the log of GDP. Figure 4 shows the relationship between income and 12 See Table 6 at the end of the paper. 16

17 concentration conditional on population and the mean. The model replicates the empirical pattern with export concentration decreasing as income increases, see 4(a). However, the cross country differences in terms of income and concentration are much larger in the model than in the data. In the model, the difference from the mean level of concentration ranges from -2 to +2, whereas in the model from -4 to +4. The reason for the larger dispersion is the extensive margin, see 4(c). On the import side, the cross country differences in terms of concentration in the calibrated model are similar to the data, see 4(b). With regard to the intensive margin, see 4(f), the results show that, in line with the data, the model predicts no relationship between concentration and income. Overall, the calibrated model is able to replicate the qualitative pattern but produces relatively high levels of concentration compared to the data, particularly for the extensive margin of exports. A potential explanation for the excessive export concentration lies in the underlying productivity distribution. While the model reproduces the bilateral trade volumes, it fails to capture the underlying distribution of trade volumes across products. To shed light on why countries trade in too few products, I follow Haveman and Hummels (2004) and plot the empirical and simulated density of the number of exporters and importers per product. 13 Figure 5 shows the results. The simulated countries export their goods to too many destinations. The assumed productivity distribution generates producers that are so efficient that even firms facing high trade costs can sell their products to numerous destinations around the world. As a consequence, the number of exporting countries per product is small. In the data (in blue) more than a third of the products are exported by 25 or more countries. In the simulation (in red) no product is exported by more than 25 countries. With regard to imports, Figure 5(b) shows that, contrary to exports, the simulated distribution of the number of countries importing a product is closely related to the empirical one. 5 Policy experiments This section considers the following policy experiment: suppose a country wants to diversity its exports. This policy was advocated by many policy institutions in order to reduce the negative impact of volatility on growth, see De Ferranti et al. (2002) and IMF (2014). In order to show the model s implications of such a policy, I consider the free trade equilibrium (κ ij = w ij = 1, i, j), which is simple and can be solved by hand. Later, I will use the calibrated model to calculate precisely the policy effects for each country. Within the Alvarez and Lucas (2007), there are basically two ways to decrease export concentration. The first one is an increase in the level of technology (λ), for example through R&D investment, and the second policy is by increasing competitiveness, for example through an exchange rate depreciation. I consider a change in the level of technology as a long term effect, while a change in the exchange rate as a short run effect. 13 To get the empirical distribution of the number of exporters and importers per product, I count for each HS code the number of countries that net export or net import the product. Similarly, the model implied distribution represents the number of exporters and importers for each simulated product. 17

18 5.1 Short run (partial equilibrium) For the moment, I consider the short run equilibrium, where wages cannot adjust. Note that the Theil index of exports is defined as the sum of the extensive and the intensive component, i.e. T ix = T Ext ix + Tix Int. The extensive component is given by T Ext ix and the intensive component is given by T Int ix = 1 N ix = ln N i k=1 ( ) Nix N r ik ln r ix where r ik are export revenues of product k, r ix = N ix k=1 r ik represents the mean export revenue of country i, N ix denotes the number of exported products by country i and N is the total number of products in the world. In the free trade equilibrium, all goods a country produces are exported. Thus, the total value of exports is ( rik r ix ) X i = L j p mj q j D ji j =i and, given that the share of goods produced equals the number of goods produced, we can write the share of goods exported by country i as, n X i : n X i = D ii. In the special case of the free trade equilibrium, every country exports the same goods to all countries. Thus, the distribution of the export revenues is identical to the import expenditure distribution. In the appendix I show that the import and export concentration in the free trade equilibrium are Frechet distributed. The resulting Theil index of the intensive margin equals T Int ix = (ˆ 1 ( Γ(1 1 α ) ln u ( 1/α)) ) u ( 1/α) e u du ln (Γ(1 1α ) ) 0 (10) Concentration on the intensive margin is completely determined by the shape parameter α = 1/(θ(η 1)), which is a function of the elasticity of substitution η and the degree of comparative advantage θ. 14 To compute the Theil of the extensive component of exports, I use equation 7 and impose the free trade equilibrium to get the number of goods exported as a function of wages and 14 The integral in equation 10 cannot be solved analytically. To compute the exact Theil index implied by the shape parameter α, I approximate the integral numerically via the Gauss Laguerre procedure. The derivation can be found in the appendix. 18

19 technology: ix = ln ni X = ln T Ext k αβ θ i k=1 N k αβ θ k w β θ i λ i β w θ k λ k Suppose now that a country wants to diversify its exports and decrease the Theil by 0.1 units. In the free trade equilibrium, the only way to achieve this is goal is by diversifying on the extensive margin. The diversification of exports can be achieved by reducing the local unit labor costs relative to other countries, for example by depreciating the currency (in this framework, this is equal to subsidizing production). To show how an exchange rate depreciation helps to increase exports, I express the unit costs of production in local currency by introducing country i s exchange rate vis-a-vis the US dollar 15, s i, into the free trade version of the model. In this case, the number of goods exported is given by the ratio of local unit costs of production relative to the average unit costs in the importing country and equals ix = ln ni X = ln T Ext s 1 θ i k αβ θ i N k=1 s 1 θ k w β θ i λ i k αβ θ k β w θ k λ k The resulting elasticity on the extensive margin of exports equals to T Ext ix ln s i = ln nx i ln s i = 1 θ (1 nx i ) Hence, the percentage depreciation in the exchange rate needed to increase the share of goods exported by 1 percent is ln s i = ( θ/(1 n X i ) ). The smaller the share of products exported (1 n X i ), the less depreciation is needed to diversify exports Long run (general equilibrium) The general equilibrium version of the policy experiment accounts for the endogenous response of wages. In the free trade version, the equilibrium wage is given by which can be solved to L i w i = w i = k I L j w j D ji. j=1 αβ ( ) θ (β+θ) λi (β+θ) i L i Substituting back into D ii we get the elasticity in the general equilibrium framework. 15 I chose the US dollar as international currency. Of course, I could have chosen any other currency as the common currency denominator. 19

20 (β+θ) ix = ln ni X i L = ln αβ k=1 N k T Ext and the elasticity equals to αβ β θ k (β+θ) (β+θ) i λi β θ (β+θ) (β+θ) (β+θ) k Lk λk T Ext ix ln λ i = ln nx i ln λ i = θ (β + θ) (1 nx i ) Thus, within the general equilibrium, we will have a weaker response to a technology shock in comparison to the partial equilibrium, where the elasticity is TExt ix ln λ i = (1 D ii ). The reason is that an increase in technology will also increase wages, which will partly reduce the pro-competitive effects on the export markets. If we consider now the case of an exchange rate depreciation, the market clearing conditions in US dollars becomes whereas the trade share equation equals I L i w i L j w j D ji = s i, s j=1 j ( [k D ji = (AB) 1/θ α i w i ] β p 1 β mi p mj s j s i ) 1/θ λ i. p mj s i Note that in the free trade equilibrium, prices in US dollars equalize across countries, = p m and the equilibrium wage in local currency becomes: p mi s i = w i = k αβ ( ) β (β+θ) λi (β+θ) i si L i Changes in the exchange rate lead to a one to one change in the wage. Plugging the obtained wage back into the trade share matrix (D ij ), we observe that changes in the exchange rate have no effects on trade. D ji = p β θ m k αβ (β+θ) i Note that the described effects in the partial and the general equilibrium only hold in the free trade equilibrium. Once we introduce trade costs, exchange rate changes will have real effects in the general equilibrium framework because the gain in competitiveness from an exchange rate depreciation is not uniform across countries. Still, the free trade case highlights that policies aiming to diversify in exports (1) depend on the initial share of goods exported and (2) are more effective under the assumption of rigid prices (short run) than in the case of full price flexibility (long run). Next, I show the simulation elasticities for both, the general as well as the partial equilib- λ θ β+θ i L β β+θ i 20

The new gold standard? Empirically situating the TPP in the investment treaty universe

The new gold standard? Empirically situating the TPP in the investment treaty universe Graduate Institute of International and Development Studies Center for Trade and Economic Integration Working Paper Series Working Paper N IHEIDCTEI2015-08 The new gold standard? Empirically situating

More information

Figure 1.1 The Parade of World Income. Copyright 2005 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 1-1

Figure 1.1 The Parade of World Income. Copyright 2005 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 1-1 Figure 1.1 The Parade of World Income Copyright 2005 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 1-1 Copyright 2005 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 1-2 Growth and Development: The Questions

More information

A new metrics for the Economic Complexity of countries and products

A new metrics for the Economic Complexity of countries and products A new metrics for the Economic Complexity of countries and products Andrea Tacchella Dept. of Physics, La Sapienza - University of Rome Istituto dei Sistemi Complessi, CNR Roma CRISISLAB ANALYTICS FOR

More information

Addressing institutional issues in the Poverty Reduction Strategy Paper process

Addressing institutional issues in the Poverty Reduction Strategy Paper process SESSION 1 Addressing institutional issues in the Poverty Reduction Strategy Paper process Scoping notes, detailed diagnostics, and participatory processes Public Sector Reform and Capacity Building Unit

More information

THE QUALITY OF GOVERNMENT CA FOSCARI INTERNATIONAL LECTURE

THE QUALITY OF GOVERNMENT CA FOSCARI INTERNATIONAL LECTURE THE QUALITY OF GOVERNMENT CA FOSCARI INTERNATIONAL LECTURE Andrei Shleifer December 12, 2012 1 Richer countries almost always have better governments Less corrupt More efficient Quality of government improves

More information

Does Absolute Latitude Explain Underdevelopment?

Does Absolute Latitude Explain Underdevelopment? AREC 345: Global Poverty and Economic Development Lecture 4 Professor: Pamela Jakiela Department of Agricultural and Resource Economics University of Maryland, College Park Does Absolute Latitude Explain

More information

Ken Jackson. January 31st, 2013

Ken Jackson. January 31st, 2013 Wilfrid Laurier University January 31st, 2013 Recap of the technology models Do the models match historical data? growth accounting Estimating technology change through history A revised model of technology

More information

Bringing Up Incentives: A Look at the Determinants of Poverty. Alice Sheehan

Bringing Up Incentives: A Look at the Determinants of Poverty. Alice Sheehan Bringing Up Incentives: A Look at the Determinants of Poverty Alice Sheehan Outline presentation What s going on out there? Growth, Human Development indicators, Poverty rates, etc. A look at determinants

More information

Economic Growth: the role of institutions

Economic Growth: the role of institutions ECON 184 Economic Growth: the role of institutions ECON 184: Institutions and Growth January 26, 2010 1 Contents 1 Institutions and growth: initial analysis 3 2 How can institutions affect economic growth?

More information

Today s tips for the Country Buy Report

Today s tips for the Country Buy Report High level outline Today s tips for the Country Buy Report Stephen Malpezzi Introduction Overview of the country and economy Basic indicators (GDP, employment, etc.) Key institutions, the setting How does

More information

Building Capacity in PFM

Building Capacity in PFM Building Capacity in PFM Measuring economic governance in the context of national development planning LAMIA MOUBAYED BISSAT Beirut, Lebanon, 13 June 2014 The Institut des Finances Basil Fuleihan 1996

More information

Economic Complexity and the Wealth of Nations

Economic Complexity and the Wealth of Nations Economic Complexity and the Wealth of Nations Cesar A. Hidalgo ABC Career Development Professor MIT Media Lab Faculty Associate, Center for International Development Harvard University EARTH WIND WATER

More information

Addressing The Marketing Problem of the Social Market Economy

Addressing The Marketing Problem of the Social Market Economy Addressing The Marketing Problem of the Social Prepared for: KAS-Conference on 60 Years of Social Market Economy Sankt Augustin, November 30, 2009 Marcus Marktanner, American University of Beirut Outline

More information

Estimating Global Migration Flow Tables Using Place of Birth Data

Estimating Global Migration Flow Tables Using Place of Birth Data Estimating Global Migration Flow Tables Using Place of Birth Data Guy J. Abel Wittgenstein Centre (IIASA, VID/ÖAW, WU) Vienna Institute of Demography/Austrian Academy of Sciences 1 Introduction International

More information

Natural Resources and Development in the Middle East and North Africa: An Alternative Perspective

Natural Resources and Development in the Middle East and North Africa: An Alternative Perspective Natural Resources and Development in the Middle East and North Africa: An Alternative Perspective Daniel Lederman and Mustapha K. Nabli The World Bank Presentation at the Workshop on Natural Resources

More information

Lecture 12 The Solow Model and Convergence. Noah Williams

Lecture 12 The Solow Model and Convergence. Noah Williams Lecture 12 The Solow Model and Convergence Noah Williams University of Wisconsin - Madison Economics 312 Spring 2010 Recall: Balanced Growth Path All per-capita variables grow at rate g. All level variables

More information

China: How to maintain balanced growth? Ricardo Hausmann Kennedy School of Government Harvard University

China: How to maintain balanced growth? Ricardo Hausmann Kennedy School of Government Harvard University China: How to maintain balanced growth? Ricardo Hausmann Kennedy School of Government Harvard University China s growth process An unprecedented miracle China has been the fastest growing country in the

More information

Infrastructure and Economic. Norman V. Loayza, World ldbank Rei Odawara, World Bank

Infrastructure and Economic. Norman V. Loayza, World ldbank Rei Odawara, World Bank Infrastructure and Economic Growth thin Egypt Norman V. Loayza, World ldbank Rei Odawara, World Bank Motivation Questions How does Egypt compare internationally regarding public infrastructure? Is Egypt

More information

Financial services and economic development

Financial services and economic development GDP per capita growth 03/11/2014 Financial services and economic development Thorsten Beck Finance why do we care? 0.04 BWA 0.02 0.00-0.02 COG SLE ALB GAB IND KOR TUR SGP MUS SDN MOZ IRLLUX IDN MAR EGY

More information

Macroeconomics II. Growth

Macroeconomics II. Growth Macroeconomics II Growth Growth Possibilities We previously referred to the aggregate production function Y = A K α L 1- α. The growth rate of real GDP, Y, is generated by the contributions of A, K and

More information

Fear of flying: Policy stances in a troubled world economy

Fear of flying: Policy stances in a troubled world economy Fear of flying: Policy stances in a troubled world economy UNCTAD G-24 Technical Meeting Luxor, 10-11 March 2014 Session 1 Global Economy A weakening economic performance reflects inability to address

More information

The Fall of the Final Mercantilism

The Fall of the Final Mercantilism The Fall of the Final Mercantilism Labour Mobility in the Caribbean and the World, from Arthur Lewis to the 21 st Century Eastern Caribbean Central Bank Michael Clemens November 3, 2010 1 2 Migration

More information

Lecture 21: Institutions II

Lecture 21: Institutions II Lecture 21: Institutions II Dave Donaldson and Esther Duflo 14.73 Challenges of World Poverty Institutions II: Plan for the lecture Discussion of assigned reading (Acemoglu, Johnson and Robinson) Causes

More information

Deep Roots of Comparative Development

Deep Roots of Comparative Development Deep Roots of Comparative Development Oded Galor AEA Continuing Education Program Lecture III - AEA 2014 Oded Galor Roots of Comparative Development Lecture III - AEA 2014 1 / 41 Deep Roots of Comparative

More information

Human Resources for Health Why we need to act now

Human Resources for Health Why we need to act now Human Resources for Health Why we need to act now Progress towards the MDGs, particularly in Africa is slow, or even stagnating. Poor people cannot access basic services for want of doctors, nurses and

More information

Trade and International Integration: A Developing Program of Research

Trade and International Integration: A Developing Program of Research Trade and International Integration: A Developing Program of Research World Bank Development Economics Research Group Geneva, June 2013 Three areas of focus I. Implications of the changing patterns of

More information

Trade Policy Restrictiveness in Transportation Services

Trade Policy Restrictiveness in Transportation Services Trade Policy Restrictiveness in Transportation Services Ingo Borchert, Batshur Gootiiz and Aaditya Mattoo Development Research Group Trade and International Integration, The World Bank OECD Expert Meeting

More information

Lecture 9: Institutions, Geography and Culture. Based on Acemoglu s L. Robbins lectures

Lecture 9: Institutions, Geography and Culture. Based on Acemoglu s L. Robbins lectures Lecture 9: Institutions, Geography and Culture Based on Acemoglu s L. Robbins lectures 1 The Wealth of Nations Vast differences in prosperity across countries today. Income per capita in sub-saharan Africa

More information

Economic Growth: The Neo-classical & Endogenous Story

Economic Growth: The Neo-classical & Endogenous Story Density of countries Economic Growth: The Neo-classical & Endogenous Story EC307 ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT 1960 Dr. Kumar Aniet University of Cambridge & LSE Summer School Lecture 4 1980 2000 created on July

More information

Export Survival and Comparative Advantage

Export Survival and Comparative Advantage Export Survival and Comparative Advantage (Work in progress) Regional Seminar on Export Diversification, October 27-28, 2010 Bolormaa Tumurchudur, UNCTAD Miho Shirotori, UNCTAD Alessandro Nicita, UNCTAD

More information

In Defense of Wall Street - Does Finance Cause Creative Destruction?

In Defense of Wall Street - Does Finance Cause Creative Destruction? In Defense of Wall Street The Social Productivity of the Financial System Finance is powerful Mobilizes Researches and allocates Monitors and exerts corporate control Provides risk diversification and

More information

Subjective Well-Being, Income, Economic Development and Growth

Subjective Well-Being, Income, Economic Development and Growth Subjective Well-Being, Income, Economic Development and Growth Dan Sacks, Betsey Stevenson and Justin Wolfers Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania and NBER Annual Bank Conference on Development Economics--Stockholm,

More information

ECON 260 Theories of Economic Development. Instructor: Jorge Agüero. Fall 2008. Lecture 1 September 29, 2008 1

ECON 260 Theories of Economic Development. Instructor: Jorge Agüero. Fall 2008. Lecture 1 September 29, 2008 1 ECON 260 Theories of Economic Development. Instructor: Jorge Agüero. Fall 2008. Lecture 1 September 29, 2008 1 General information Time and location: TR 2:10-3:30 p.m. SPR 3123 Office hours: T 10am-11am,

More information

Geography and Economic Transition

Geography and Economic Transition Global Spatial Analysis at the Grid Cell Level Mesbah Motamed Raymond Florax Will Masters Department of Agricultural Economics Purdue University March 2009 Urbanization at the grid cell level Growth regimes

More information

Political Economy of Growth

Political Economy of Growth 1 Political Economy of Growth Daron Acemoglu Department of Economics, MIT Milan, DEFAP June 11, 2007 The Wealth of Nations Vast differences in prosperity across countries today. Income per capita in sub-saharan

More information

Relative Prices and Sectoral Productivity

Relative Prices and Sectoral Productivity Relative Prices and Sectoral Productivity Margarida Duarte University of Toronto Diego Restuccia University of Toronto August 2012 Abstract The relative price of services rises with development. A standard

More information

Finance, Growth & Opportunity. Implications for policy

Finance, Growth & Opportunity. Implications for policy Finance, Growth & Opportunity Implications for policy Today, I will make three points 1) Finance matters for human welfare beyond crises. 2) Financial innovation is associated with arguably necessary for

More information

The distribution of household financial contributions to the health system: A look outside Latin America and the Caribbean

The distribution of household financial contributions to the health system: A look outside Latin America and the Caribbean The distribution of household financial contributions to the health system: A look outside Latin America and the Caribbean Priyanka Saksena and Ke Xu 3 November, 2008 Santiago 1 The distribution of household

More information

Governance, Rule of Law and Transparency Matters: BRICs in Global Perspective

Governance, Rule of Law and Transparency Matters: BRICs in Global Perspective Governance, Rule of Law and Transparency Matters: BRICs in Global Perspective Daniel Kaufmann * Senior Fellow, Brookings Institution http://www.brookings.edu/experts/kaufmannd.aspx Panel on Transparency

More information

Institutional Change and Growth-Enabling Governance Capabilities

Institutional Change and Growth-Enabling Governance Capabilities Institutional Change and Growth-Enabling Governance Capabilities Nicolas Meisel Strategy and Research Dept - French Development Agency (AFD) Jacques Ould Aoudia Treasury and Economic Policy Directorate

More information

Accounting For Cross-Country Income Di erences

Accounting For Cross-Country Income Di erences Accounting For Cross-Country Income Di erences January 2011 () Aggregation January 2011 1 / 10 Standard Primal Growth Accounting Aggregate production possibilities frontier: where Change in output is )

More information

Growing Together with Growth Polarization and Income Inequality

Growing Together with Growth Polarization and Income Inequality Growing Together with Growth Polarization and Income Inequality Sudip Ranjan Basu, Ph.D. Economist, United Nations ESCAP UN DESA Expert Group Meeting on the World Economy (LINK Project) United Nations

More information

Life-cycle Human Capital Accumulation Across Countries: Lessons From U.S. Immigrants

Life-cycle Human Capital Accumulation Across Countries: Lessons From U.S. Immigrants Life-cycle Human Capital Accumulation Across Countries: Lessons From U.S. Immigrants David Lagakos, UCSD and NBER Benjamin Moll, Princeton and NBER Tommaso Porzio, Yale Nancy Qian, Yale and NBER Todd Schoellman,

More information

Subjective Well Being, Income, Economic Development and Growth

Subjective Well Being, Income, Economic Development and Growth Subjective Well Being, Income, Economic Development and Growth Dan Sacks, Betsey Stevenson and Justin Wolfers Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania and NBER CSLS ICP Conference on Happiness December

More information

Specialization Patterns in International Trade

Specialization Patterns in International Trade Specialization Patterns in International Trade Walter Steingress March 2, 213 Abstract I document new facts on the pattern of specialization by looking at export and import concentration. As a result of

More information

Movement and development. Australian National University Jan. 17, 2013 Michael Clemens

Movement and development. Australian National University Jan. 17, 2013 Michael Clemens Movement and development Australian National University Jan. 17, 2013 Michael Clemens ? 60% Benefits Little Haiti Cap-Haïtien Gibson and McKenzie 2010 Tongan seasonal workers in NZ NZ$1,400/family

More information

Does Export Concentration Cause Volatility?

Does Export Concentration Cause Volatility? Does Export Concentration Cause Volatility? Christian Busch 14. Januar 2010 Overview Countries with undiversified export structure are plausibly more vulnerable to external shocks. But difficult to evaluate

More information

Institute for Development Policy and Management (IDPM)

Institute for Development Policy and Management (IDPM) Institute for Development Policy and Management (IDPM) Development Economics and Public Policy Working Paper Series WP No. 33/212 Published by: Development Economics and Public Policy Cluster, Institute

More information

Diversification versus Polarization: Role of industrial policy in Asia and the Pacific

Diversification versus Polarization: Role of industrial policy in Asia and the Pacific TOWARDS A RETURN OF INDUSTRIAL POLICY? ARTNeT SYMPOSIUM 25-26 JULY 211 ESCAP, BANGKOK Diversification versus Polarization: Role of industrial policy in Asia and the Pacific Sudip Ranjan Basu* International

More information

Trends in global income inequality and their political implications

Trends in global income inequality and their political implications Trends in global income inequality and their political implications LIS Center; Graduate School City University of New York Talk at the Stockholm School of Economics, September 1, 2014 A. National inequalities

More information

Infrastructure and Economic Growth in Egypt

Infrastructure and Economic Growth in Egypt Public Disclosure Authorized Policy Research Working Paper 5177 WPS5177 Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Infrastructure and Economic Growth in Egypt Norman V. Loayza Rei Odawara

More information

TRADE WATCH DATA JANUARY T RVSFRRTVL

TRADE WATCH DATA JANUARY T RVSFRRTVL Public Disclosure Authorized TRADE WATCH DATA JANUARY T RVSFRRTVL Public Disclosure Authorized A C F D H T W B DECRG Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized *TRADE WATCH is a monthly

More information

Online Appendix to The Missing Food Problem: Trade, Agriculture, and International Income Differences

Online Appendix to The Missing Food Problem: Trade, Agriculture, and International Income Differences Online Appendix to The Missing Food Problem: Trade, Agriculture, and International Income Differences Trevor Tombe, Uversity of Calgary Contents 1 Proof of Propositions 2 2 Data and Sample of Countries

More information

Evaluation with stylized facts

Evaluation with stylized facts Evaluation with stylized facts AMPERE Subgroup on IAM Validation Valeria Jana Schwanitz Potsdam Institute for Climate Impact Research 27. Mai 2013 Content Fundamental laws and stylized facts Systematic

More information

The Macroeconomic Implications of Financial Globalization

The Macroeconomic Implications of Financial Globalization The Macroeconomic Implications of Financial Globalization Eswar Prasad, IMF Research Department November 10, 2006 The views expressed in this paper are those of the author(s) ) only, and the presence of

More information

Rethinking the Wealth of Nations. Daron Acemoglu, MIT FEEM Lecture, December 14, 2009.

Rethinking the Wealth of Nations. Daron Acemoglu, MIT FEEM Lecture, December 14, 2009. Rethinking the Wealth of Nations Daron Acemoglu, MIT FEEM Lecture, December 14, 2009. 1 The Failure of Nations Vast differences in prosperity across countries today. Income per capita in sub-saharan Africa

More information

DEPENDENT ELITES IN POST- SOCIALISM: ARE LAND-BASED POST- COLONIAL SYSTEMS SO DIFFERENT FROM THE TRANSCONTINENTAL ONES? by Pal TAMAS [Institute of

DEPENDENT ELITES IN POST- SOCIALISM: ARE LAND-BASED POST- COLONIAL SYSTEMS SO DIFFERENT FROM THE TRANSCONTINENTAL ONES? by Pal TAMAS [Institute of DEPENDENT ELITES IN POST- SOCIALISM: ARE LAND-BASED POST- COLONIAL SYSTEMS SO DIFFERENT FROM THE TRANSCONTINENTAL ONES? by Pal TAMAS [Institute of Sociology, HAS Budapest] STRUCTURE OF THE PAPER 1. STATE

More information

Employment, Structural Change, and Economic Development. Dani Rodrik March 15, 2012

Employment, Structural Change, and Economic Development. Dani Rodrik March 15, 2012 Employment, Structural Change, and Economic Development Dani Rodrik March 15, 2012 A remarkable reversal in fortunes since 1990s -.04 -.02 0.02.04.06 1950 1955 1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000

More information

Incen%ves The Good, the Bad and the Ugly

Incen%ves The Good, the Bad and the Ugly Incen%ves The Good, the Bad and the Ugly Vale Columbia Center Interna%onal Investment Conference New York, Nov 13-14, 2013 Sebas%an James The World Bank Group 1 Prevalence of Tax Incen%ves around the Number

More information

Non-market strategy under weak institutions

Non-market strategy under weak institutions Lectures 5-6 Non-market strategy under weak institutions 1 Outline 1. Does weakness of institutions matter for business and economic performance? 2. Which institutions matter most? 3. Why institutions

More information

Measuring the Pollution Terms of Trade with Technique Effects

Measuring the Pollution Terms of Trade with Technique Effects Measuring the Pollution Terms of Trade with Technique Effects Jean-Marie Grether, University of Neuchâtel Nicole Mathys, Swiss Federal Office of Energy and University of Neuchâtel Conference on the International

More information

Informality in Latin America and the Caribbean

Informality in Latin America and the Caribbean WPS4888 Policy Research Working Paper 4888 Informality in Latin America and the Caribbean Norman V. Loayza Luis Servén Naotaka Sugawara The World Bank Development Research Group Macroeconomics and Growth

More information

The Role of Trade in Structural Transformation

The Role of Trade in Structural Transformation 1 The Role of Trade in Structural Transformation Marc Teignier UNIVERSIDAD DE ALICANTE European Summer Symposium in International Macroeconomics 23 May 2012, Tarragona Question Contributions Road Map Motivation

More information

NGO PERSPECTIVE: FROM WORDS TO DEEDS

NGO PERSPECTIVE: FROM WORDS TO DEEDS MMSD & IIED Managing Mineral Wealth NGO PERSPECTIVE: FROM WORDS TO DEEDS Miguel Schloss Executive Director Transparency International Issues Policy distortions Institutional incentives Governance Implications

More information

2006/SOM1/ACT/WKSP/007a Recasting Governance for the XXI Century - Presentation

2006/SOM1/ACT/WKSP/007a Recasting Governance for the XXI Century - Presentation 2006/SOM1/ACT/WKSP/007a Recasting Governance for the XXI Century - Presentation Submitted by: Miguel Schloss, Managing Partner DamConsult Ltd. APEC Workshop on Anti-Corruption Measures for the Development

More information

Fertility Convergence

Fertility Convergence Fertility Convergence Tiloka De-Silva a Silvana Tenreyro a,b a London School of Economics, CfM; b CEP, CEPR July 2015 Abstract A vast literature has sought to explain large cross-country differences in

More information

Informality in Latin America and the Caribbean

Informality in Latin America and the Caribbean Public Disclosure Authorized Policy Research Working Paper 4888 WPS4888 Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Informality in Latin America and the Caribbean Norman V. Loayza Luis Servén

More information

The contribution of trade in financial services to economic growth and development. Thorsten Beck

The contribution of trade in financial services to economic growth and development. Thorsten Beck The contribution of trade in financial services to economic growth and development Thorsten Beck Finance why do we care? 0.04 BWA GDP per capita growth 0.02 0.00-0.02 COG SLE ALB GAB IND KOR TUR SGP MUS

More information

International Investment Patterns. Philip R. Lane WBI Seminar, Paris, April 2006

International Investment Patterns. Philip R. Lane WBI Seminar, Paris, April 2006 International Investment Patterns Philip R. Lane WBI Seminar, Paris, April 2006 Introduction What determines aggregate capital inflows and outflows? What determines bilateral patterns in international

More information

Outline 4/22/2011. Koc University April, 2011

Outline 4/22/2011. Koc University April, 2011 4/22/211 Koc University April, 211 Outline Main messages Crisis experience and focus Reserves trends Review of existing approaches Proposed new approach and metric Cost of reserves Reserve alternatives

More information

Rodolfo Debenedetti Lecture

Rodolfo Debenedetti Lecture Rodolfo Debenedetti Lecture Andrei Shleifer March 2005 Legal Origin Distribution Legal Origins = English = French = German = Scandinavian = Socialist Institution Procedural Formalism Outcomes Time to evict

More information

Tripartite Agreements for MEPC.2/Circ. Lists 1, 3, 4 received by IMO following issuance of MEPC.2/Circ.20

Tripartite Agreements for MEPC.2/Circ. Lists 1, 3, 4 received by IMO following issuance of MEPC.2/Circ.20 The following is a list of tripartite agreements reported to IMO during the period between the issuance of the annual MEPC.2/Circular, disseminated in December of each year. Any countries wishing to join

More information

Bands (considered to be) Shared on an Equal Basis Between Space and Terrestrial Services (for Region 1)

Bands (considered to be) Shared on an Equal Basis Between Space and Terrestrial Services (for Region 1) Bands (considered to be) Shared on an Equal Basis Between Space and Terrestrial Services (for Region 1) Source: RR2012 Art 5, Art 9, Art 21, App 5, App 7; Rules of Procedure 2012 Rev. 5 Lower 137 137.025

More information

The Role of Women in Society: from Preindustrial to Modern Times

The Role of Women in Society: from Preindustrial to Modern Times CESifo Economic Studies Advance Access published May 22, 2014 CESifo Economic Studies, 2014, doi:10.1093/cesifo/ifu019 The Role of Women in Society: from Preindustrial to Modern Times Paola Giuliano UCLA

More information

COMPLEXITY AND INDUSTRIAL POLICY

COMPLEXITY AND INDUSTRIAL POLICY IPD/JICA Task Force on Industrial Policy and Transformation Amman, Jordan, June 5-6, 2014 COMPLEXITY AND INDUSTRIAL POLICY Luciano Pietronero Measuring the Intangible Growth Potential of Countries Collaborators:

More information

Tripartite Agreements for MEPC.2/Circ. Lists 1, 3, 4 received by IMO following issuance of MEPC.2/Circ.21

Tripartite Agreements for MEPC.2/Circ. Lists 1, 3, 4 received by IMO following issuance of MEPC.2/Circ.21 The following is a list of tripartite agreements reported to IMO during the period between the issuance of the annual MEPC.2/Circular, disseminated in December of each year. Any countries wishing to join

More information

The Effects of Infrastructure Development on Growth and Income Distribution

The Effects of Infrastructure Development on Growth and Income Distribution The Effects of Infrastructure Development on Growth and Income Distribution César Calderón Luis Servén (Central Bank of Chile) (The World Bank) ALIDE - The World Bank - Banco BICE Reunión Latinoamericana

More information

A Pragmatic Approach to Capital Account Liberalization. Eswar Prasad Cornell University

A Pragmatic Approach to Capital Account Liberalization. Eswar Prasad Cornell University A Pragmatic Approach to Capital Account Liberalization Eswar Prasad Cornell University Presentation partly based on my joint work with: Ayhan Kose, Kenneth Rogoff, Shang-Jin Wei (2003, 2006) Raghuram Rajan

More information

Subjective Well Being and Income: Is There Any Evidence of Satiation? *

Subjective Well Being and Income: Is There Any Evidence of Satiation? * Subjective Well Being and Income: Is There Any Evidence of Satiation? * Betsey Stevenson The Gerald R. Ford School of Public Policy, University of Michigan & CESifo and NBER betseys@umich.edu www.nber.org/~bstevens

More information

Session 5x: Bonus material

Session 5x: Bonus material The Social Statistics Discipline Area, School of Social Sciences Session 5x: Bonus material Mitchell Centre for Network Analysis Johan Koskinen http://www.ccsr.ac.uk/staff/jk.htm! johan.koskinen@manchester.ac.uk

More information

The Impact of Primary and Secondary Education on Higher Education Quality 1

The Impact of Primary and Secondary Education on Higher Education Quality 1 The Impact of Primary and Secondary Education on Higher Education Quality 1 Katharina Michaelowa University of Zurich katja.michaelowa@pw.unizh.ch 1. Introduction Undoubtedly, the overall education system

More information

Industrial Policy, Capabilities, and Growth: Where does the Future of Singapore lie? Jesus Felipe Asian Development Bank

Industrial Policy, Capabilities, and Growth: Where does the Future of Singapore lie? Jesus Felipe Asian Development Bank Industrial Policy, Capabilities, and Growth: Where does the Future of Singapore lie? Jesus Felipe Asian Development Bank Purpose of the talk Understand the economic challenges that Singapore faces Discuss

More information

BUILDING A DATASET FOR BILATERAL MARITIME CONNECTIVITY

BUILDING A DATASET FOR BILATERAL MARITIME CONNECTIVITY Région et Développement n - BUILDING A DATASET FOR BILATERAL MARITIME CONNECTIVITY Marco FUGAZZA *, Jan HOFFMANN *, Rado RAZAFINOMBANA * Abstract - This paper presents a unique database reporting the shortest

More information

A Survey of Securities Laws and Enforcement

A Survey of Securities Laws and Enforcement A Survey of Securities Laws and Enforcement Preliminary Draft By Florencio Lopez-de-Silanes YALE University and NBER October 2003 *I am indebted to Patricio Amador, Jose Caballero and Manuel Garcia-Huitron

More information

The Marginal Product of Capital. Francesco Caselli. Discussion by

The Marginal Product of Capital. Francesco Caselli. Discussion by 7 TH JACQUES POLAK ANNUAL RESEARCH CONFERENCE NOVEMBER 9-10, 2006 The Marginal Product of Capital Francesco Caselli Discussion by Chang-Tai Hsieh University of California, Berkeley The views expressed

More information

DOCUMENT DE TRAVAIL N 542

DOCUMENT DE TRAVAIL N 542 DOCUMENT DE TRAVAIL N 542 SPECIALIZATION PATTERNS IN INTERNATIONAL TRADE Walter Steingress March 2015 DIRECTION GÉNÉRALE DES ÉTUDES ET DES RELATIONS INTERNATIONALES DIRECTION GÉNÉRALE DES ÉTUDES ET DES

More information

Overview of Growth Research in the Past Two Decades

Overview of Growth Research in the Past Two Decades Overview of Growth Research in the Past Two Decades by Pete Klenow Stanford University and NBER September 21, 2010 Early Growth Research 1950s Solow (1956) 1960s Nelson and Phelps (1966) 1970s Dark Ages

More information

First Credit Bureau Conference

First Credit Bureau Conference First Credit Bureau Conference Riga, Latvia 13.1.15 Presentation by: Leora Klapper Lead Economist Development Research Group, World Bank DEVELOPING A NATIONAL CREDIT BUREAU Financial Development What is

More information

Inequality of Opportunity in Educational Achievements

Inequality of Opportunity in Educational Achievements Inequality of Opportunity in Educational Achievements Cross-Country and Intertemporal Comparisons P. Luongo University of Bari Inequality Measurement, trend, impacts and policies UNU-WIDER Conference September

More information

BUILDING A DATASET FOR BILATERAL MARITIME CONNECTIVITY. Marco Fugazza Jan Hoffmann Rado Razafinombana

BUILDING A DATASET FOR BILATERAL MARITIME CONNECTIVITY. Marco Fugazza Jan Hoffmann Rado Razafinombana U N I T E D N AT I O N S C O N F E R E N C E O N T R A D E A N D D E V E L O P M E N T POLICY ISSUES IN INTERNATIONAL TRADE AND COMMODITIES STUDY SERIES No. BUILDING A DATASET FOR BILATERAL MARITIME CONNECTIVITY

More information

FEDERATION INTERNATIONALE DE GYMNASTIQUE

FEDERATION INTERNATIONALE DE GYMNASTIQUE Individual Competitions Qualifications C-I 22, 23, 24 and 25 September 2014 1st day of qualification 2nd day of qualification 3rd day of qualification 4th day of qualification 22 September 2014 23 September

More information

Technology Choice. Francesco Caselli. Summer School 2005

Technology Choice. Francesco Caselli. Summer School 2005 Technology Choice Francesco Caselli Summer School 2005 1 Motivation All of the evidence and all of the models we have studied so far assume that cross-country technology differences are factor-neutral.

More information

Design of efficient redistributive fiscal policy

Design of efficient redistributive fiscal policy Fiscal Policy and Income Inequality Sanjeev Gupta Deputy Director Fiscal Affairs Department, IMF IMF-Hitotsubashi University Workshop March 12, Tokyo Structure of the presentation Trends in inequality

More information

How To Understand The World'S Governance

How To Understand The World'S Governance Metrics Matters: Measures of Governance and Security and the Business Perspective An initial empirical exploration Daniel Kaufmann, World Bank Institute www.worldbank.org/wbi/governance For presentation

More information

The Global Crisis in Low- and Middle-Income Countries: How the IMF Responded

The Global Crisis in Low- and Middle-Income Countries: How the IMF Responded The Global Crisis in Low- and Middle-Income Countries: How the IMF Responded Andrea F. Presbitero Alberto Zazzaro 1 Università Politecnica delle Marche 2 Money and Finance Research group (MoFiR) Real and

More information

EC 2725 April 2009. Law and Finance. Effi Benmelech Harvard & NBER

EC 2725 April 2009. Law and Finance. Effi Benmelech Harvard & NBER EC 2725 April 2009 Law and Finance Effi Benmelech Harvard & NBER Broad Picture A market economy is not only laissez faire but it also requires a set of institutions that allow markets to work their magic.

More information

Country Risk Classifications of the Participants to the Arrangement on Officially Supported Export Credits

Country Risk Classifications of the Participants to the Arrangement on Officially Supported Export Credits Country Risk Classifications of the Participants to the Arrangement on Officially Supported Export Credits 19992013 8 9 10 11 12 13 01Jan99 22Jan99 19Mar99 1Jun99 14Oct99 24Jan00 29Jan99 26Mar99 24Jun99

More information

Redistribution. E. Glen Weyl. Lecture 11 Turbo Section Elements of Economic Analysis II Fall 2011. University of Chicago

Redistribution. E. Glen Weyl. Lecture 11 Turbo Section Elements of Economic Analysis II Fall 2011. University of Chicago E. Glen Weyl University of Chicago Lecture 11 Turbo Section Elements of Economic Analysis II Fall 2011 Midterm reminder and introduction The midterm exam is tonight 4:30-6 in SS122 Open everything, no

More information

Global Value Chains in the Current Trade Slowdown

Global Value Chains in the Current Trade Slowdown MARCH 14 Number 137 Global Value Chains in the Current Trade Slowdown Michael J. Ferrantino and Daria Taglioni Real growth in global trade has decelerated significantly since its sharp recovery in 1. Year-on-year

More information

The Shift to Government Banking:

The Shift to Government Banking: The Shift to Government Banking: Risks for the Netherlands and other Developed Countries Prof. Florencio Lopez de Silanes EDHEC Business School, NBER and DSF April 28, 2011 Amsterdam Outline I. The Policy

More information