Broker-Dealer Leverage and the Cross-Section of Stock Returns

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Broker-Dealer Leverage and the Cross-Section of Stock Returns"

Transcription

1 Broker-Dealer Leverage and the Cross-Section of Stock Returns Tobias Adrian Erkko Etula Tyler Muir January 2011 Abstract We document that average stock returns can be largely explained by their covariance with the aggregate leverage of security broker-dealers. Our single factor broker-dealer model compares favourably with standard multi-factor models in the cross-section size and book-to-market portfolios and outperforms such models when considering momentum and industry sorted portfolios. We show how to tie leverage to the rst order conditions of active investors portfolio choice and derive leverage as a state variable in the ICAPM. We interpret the risk captured by shocks to broker-dealer leverage as a re ection of unexpected changes in broader economic conditions that determine investors marginal utility of wealth. Keywords: cross sectional asset pricing, nancial intermediation, ICAPM JEl codes: G1, G12, G21 Capital Markets Function, Research and Statistics Group, Federal Reserve Bank of New York, 33 Liberty Street, New York, NY and Kellogg School of Management, Department of Finance. This paper is a revised combination of two previously circulated papers: Funding Liquidity and the Cross Section of Stock Returns (Adrian and Etula, 2010) and Intermediary Leverage and the Cross-Section of Expected Returns (Muir, 2010). We would like to thank Ariel Zucker for outstanding research assistance. We also thank Andrea Eisfeldt, Francesco Franzoni, Taejin Kim, Arvind Krishnamurthy, Ravi Jagannathan, Annette Vissing-Jorgensen, Jonathan Parker, Dimitris Papanikolaou, Stefan Nagel, Hans Dewachter, Wolfgang Lemke and seminar participants at Kellogg School of Management, the Bank of England, the European Central Bank, the Federal Reserve Bank of Boston, the Bank of Finland, HEC Paris, and Moody s KMV for useful comments and suggestions. The views expressed in this paper are those of the authors and do not necessarily re ect the position of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York or the Federal Reserve System.

2 1 Introduction Security brokers and dealers are active investors that aggressively adjust their risk exposures in response to changes in economic conditions. To the extent that the portfolio choice of broker-dealers satis es an optimality condition, broker-dealer aggregate balance sheets can be expected to contain information about economy-wide investment opportunities. By implication, it may be possible to use broker-dealer balance sheet aggregates to proxy for the stochastic discount factor that re ects the marginal utility of wealth in di erent states of the economy. In this paper, we present empirical evidence to support this hypothesis. Our crosssectional tests show that broker-dealer nancial leverage constitutes a state variable that passes important asset pricing tests. Speci cally, we show that shocks to brokerdealer leverage can alone explain the average returns on a wide variety of test assets, including portfolios sorted on size, book-to-market, momentum, and industries. The broker-dealer leverage factor is successful across all cross-sections in terms of high adjusted R-squared, low cross-sectional pricing errors (alphas), and prices of risk that are signi cant and remarkably consistent across portfolios. When taking all these criteria into account, our single factor outperforms standard multi-factor models tailored to price these cross-sections (see Fig. 1 for an example of our leverage factor s pricing performance in the cross section that spans 65 common test portfolios). However, we do not seek to argue that shocks to broker-dealer leverage drive aggregate asset prices. Rather, adjustments in broker-dealer leverage endogenously re ect changes in underlying economic state variables that may not be easily captured by an econometrician. While our strong empirical results are consistent with a number of rationalizations, our preferred theory builds on the intertemporal capital asset pricing model (ICAPM) 1

3 Realized Mean Return Factor Broker Dealer Model S1B5 Coal S3B5 Mom10 S2B5 S1B4 S2B4 S4B5 S2B3 S1B2 S1B3 S3B4 S4B4 ElcEq Beer S3B3 Oil S4B3 Food S2B2 S3B2 Carry Mom9 Mom Games Hlth Servs Rtail Mom8 Meals S5B5 Clths ChemsS4B1 S5B2 S5B4 S4B2 Fin FabPr Telcm Paper BusEq Mom6 Rm Rf Mom4Whlsl Mom3 S5B3 Books TxtlsHshld Mines Mom7 Util Cnstr Trans Autos S5B1 HML S3B1 Steel Mom5 S2B1 Mom2 SMB Other S1B1 Smoke Mom Predicted Expected Return Figure 1: Realized vs. Predicted Mean Returns. We plot the realized mean excess returns of 65 portfolios (25 Size and Book-to-Market Sorted Portfolios, 30 Industry Portfolios, and 10 Momentum Sorted Portfolios) and 4 factors (market, SMB, HML, MOM) against the mean excess returns predicted by a 1-factor broker-dealer model. The sample period is Q1/1968-Q4/2009. of Merton (1973). In the ICAPM, the endogenous portfolio choice of active, forwardlooking investors provides a window to expectations about economic conditions and investment opportunities and is therefore an important state variable for asset pricing. In our application of the ICAPM, active investors are risk-neutral leveraged nancial intermediaries subject to borrowing constraints related to the Value at Risk (VaR) of their balance sheet. The model shows that these risk constraints link economy-wide expectations of investment opportunities directly to the observable portfolio choice of 2

4 active investors. In this way, changes in leverage capture shifts in the marginal utility of wealth. By implication, investors require higher compensation for holding assets whose returns comove strongly with shocks to broker-dealer leverage. The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 provides a discussion of the related literature, reviewing a number of alternative rationalizations for the link between nancial intermediary leverage and aggregate asset prices. Section 3 shows how such a link can be motivated by a two-agent extension of the ICAPM. Section 4 describes the data and section 5 conducts a number of asset pricing tests in the cross-section of stock returns. Section 6 concludes. 2 Financial Intermediaries and Asset Prices 2.1 Broker-Dealers and Procyclical Leverage Financial institutions serve an important economic role in the allocation of savings from ultimate savers to ultimate borrowers. As agents of savers, nancial institutions are subject to constraints that can be interpreted as outcome of agency problems between savers and their nancial institutions. The managers of the nancial institutions can be expected to take dynamically optimal, rational decisions to maximize the institution s value subject to such constraints, which in practice take the form of restrictions on risk management and compensation. The pro t-maximizing balance sheet management of nancial institutions is in stark contrast to the portfolio choice of households, which may be subject to many potential issues, such as slow adjustment (Jagannathan and Wang, 2006; Calvet, Campbell and Sodini, 2009), habits (Campbell and Cochrane, 1999), limited participation (Vissing-Jorgensen, 2002), and model uncertainty (Hansen and Sargent, 2007). Financial institutions, on the other hand, optimize their portfolio holdings frequently based on sophisticated models and extensive historical data on the 3

5 distribution of returns, and report timely and accurate data to their regulators. The aggregate portfolio choice of nancial institutions can thus be expected to provide a better empirical window to the time-varying investment opportunity set than aggregate measures based on household behavior. Empirically, Adrian and Shin (2010) show that security broker-dealers adjust their nancial leverage aggressively in response to changing economic conditions. Unlike the dynamics of household consumption, time-variation in U.S. broker-dealer aggregate balance sheet components is easily quanti ed using the Federal Reserve s Flow of Funds quarterly database. These data reveal that broker-dealers balance sheet management practices lead to high leverage in economic booms and low leverage in economic downturns: that is, broker-dealer leverage is procyclical. 1 Table 1: Broker-dealer leverage is pro-cyclical. The correlation of broker-dealer leverage growth with a selection of state variables, Q1/1968-Q4/2009. Correlation of Broker-Dealer Leverage Growth Market Pro t Financials Broker-Dealer Return Growth Return Asset Growth The procyclicality of broker-dealer leverage can be understood in terms of its comovement with other state variables, which we compute in the Table 1. We display the correlations of broker-dealer leverage growth with the value-weighted return on the U.S. equity market, pro t growth of the U.S. nancial sector (obtained from the Bureau of Economic Analysis), the value-weighted stock return on the U.S. nancial sector, and the asset growth of broker-dealers. Positive correlation in each case shows that leverage growth is pro-cyclical and related to wealth, compensation, and investment opportunities. The strong correlation of leverage growth with broker-dealer asset 1 We measure leverage by the the ratio of nancial assets to equity. 4

6 growth moreover suggests that the ability of broker-dealers to borrow is close to the amount actually borrowed, making leverage a proxy for funding liquidity. 2.2 Literature on Financial Intermediaries and Aggregate Asset Prices While our version of the ICAPM and the accompanying empirical tests are new, a number of other papers have derived theoretical models relating nancial intermediaries to asset prices. While none of these give the direct empirical implications that we test, they are broadly consistent with our ndings that low leverage states are states where the marginal utility of wealth is high and therefore assets that covary positively with leverage earn higher average returns. He and Krishnamurthy (2010) derive an intermediary CAPM in which intermediaries are marginal investors and the return on intermediary wealth can be used as a pricing kernel. Since our leverage factor is positively related to wealth and compensation in the intermediary sector, our results support this view as well. Geanakoplos (2009) shows how leverage can drive the business cycle and how asset prices can depend on the ability of optimists to use leverage. While Geanakoplos s model does not deliver cross-sectional asset pricing implications, it gives an intuitive justi cation for why times of growing broker-dealer leverage are good times with low marginal utility of wealth. Our results are also closely linked to the literature on limits of arbitrage (Shleifer and Vishny, 1997): broker-dealers are forced to decrease leverage precisely when prices are decreasing and expected returns are rising. Gromb and Vayanos (2002) show how tightening of funding constraints can lead to losses of liquidity. Again, while such theoretical models aid in our intuitive understanding of the empirical results, they do not give the explicit formal cross-sectional prediction that leverage should be priced in 5

7 the cross-section of returns. To the best of our knowledge, we are the rst to conduct a cross-sectional asset pricing test where intermediaries e ective risk aversion enters into the aggregate pricing kernel. More generally, our paper is related to the emerging strand of literature investigating the impact of balance sheet constraints on aggregate asset prices. In addition to the papers mentioned above, examples of such studies include Aiyagari and Gertler (1999), Basak and Croitoru (2000), and Caballero and Krishnamurthy (2004). The approach taken in this paper is closely related to the endogenous ampli cation mechanisms via the margin spiral of Brunnermeier and Pedersen (2009), where margin constraints are time-varying and can serve to amplify market uctuations through changes in riskbearing capacity. In this strand of literature, the empirical studies most relevant to ours are the investigations of foreign exchange markets by Adrian, Etula and Shin (2009) and of commodity markets by Etula (2009). Both papers introduce risk-based balance sheet constraints in a two-agent CAPM, generating time-varying e ective risk aversion that can be expressed in terms of observable state variables. Danielsson, Shin and Zigrand (2009) endogenize risk and e ective risk aversion simultaneously by solving for the equilibrium stochastic volatility function in a setting with value-at-risk constraints on nancial intermediaries. 2.3 Literature on Cross-Sectional Asset Pricing The idea that long-term investors care about shocks to investment opportunities originates in the ICAPM of Merton (1969, 1971, 1973). Kim and Omberg (1996) provide closed form solutions to a particular case of Merton s dynamic portfolio allocation behavior. Campbell (1993) solves a discrete-time empirical version of the ICAPM with a stochastic market premium, writing the solution in the form of a multifactor model. 6

8 Campbell (1996) tests this model on industry portfolios, but nds little improvement over the CAPM. Other empirical studies of the ICAPM include Li (1997), Hodrick, Ng, and Sengmueller (1999), Lynch (1999), Brennan, Wang, and Xia (2004), Guo (2002), Chen (2003), Ng (2004), Ang, Hodrick, Xing, Zhang (2006, 2009), Adrian and Rosenberg (2008), and Bali and Engle (2009). We also contribute to the vast literature of competing explanations for the size and value e ects (Fama and French, 1993), and the momentum e ect (Jegadeesh and Titman, 1993, 2001; Rouwenhorst, 1998, 1999; Chui, Titman, and Wei, 2000). It is well known that the Arbitrage Pricing Theory (APT) of Ross (1976) allows any pervasive source of common variation to be a priced risk factor. Fama and French (1993) follow the APT insight and describe the average returns on portfolios sorted by size and value using a three-factor speci cation, which complements the market model with a size factor and a value factor. However, since the APT is silent about the determinants of factor prices of risk, a model such as that of Fama and French cannot explain why the risk premia associated with certain factors are positive or negative, or the sources of the premia. The same caveat applies to other APT-motivated factor models constructed to explain asset pricing anomalies, including the the momentum factor of Carhart (1997). The failures of standard asset pricing models can also be interpreted in behavioral terms by arguing that the size, value, and momentum e ects are due to mispricing. Lakonishok, Shleifer, and Vishny (1994), for example, suggest that investors irrationally extrapolate past earnings growth and thereby overvalue companies that have performed well in the past. DeBondt and Thaler (1985, 1987), Barberis, Shleifer and Vishny (1998), Daniel, Hirshleifer, and Subrahmanyam (1998), Hong and Stein (1999), and Hong, Lim and Stein (2000) suggest that both momentum and long-term reversal are 7

9 the results of mispricing. In this paper, we seek to avoid these alternative explanations. Our preferred theoretical motivation combines insights from the literature on intermediaries and asset pricing with the literature on portfolio choice to develop a version of Merton s ICAPM based on the rst-order conditions of two rational investors, a long-horizon investor who is risk neutral but subject to a balance sheet risk constraint, and a myopic investor with constant relative risk aversion. Our empirical section may therefore be interpreted as an investigation of the extent to which cross-sectional asset pricing anomalies can be rationalized by intertemporal hedging considerations relevant for long-term investors. 3 ICAPM Motivation In the previous section, we considered a number of alternative explanations for why shocks to broker-dealer leverage might be priced in the cross-section of stocks. In this section, we show more formally how the insights from Merton s (1973) ICAPM may be used to yield some structure for our empirical tests. We make the basic conceptual assumption that equilibrium asset prices are determined by the interaction of two types of agents, A and P. Each agent j has a value function J j (w j ; x), where w j denotes wealth and x is a vector of state variables. Speci cally, x describes the stochastic evolution of the investment opportunity set. We denote by dr i the return on asset i in excess of the risk-free rate. Using this notation, the ICAPM Euler equations can be written as: i = A Cov dr i ; dwa + f A w A x Cov dr i ; dx ; i = P Cov dr i ; dwp + fx P Cov dr i ; dx ; w P where i is the expected excess returns on asset i, and j = J j www j J j w and f j x = J j wx J j w are 8

10 the sensitivities of the marginal utilities of wealth with respect to w j and x. Aggregation and market-clearing yields the ICAPM expression for equilibrium expected returns: i = Cov dr i ; dr M + Cov dr i ; dx F; (1) where dr M is the market excess return and = w A + w P w A = A + w P = P ; (2) F = f A x w A = A + f P x w P = P w A = A + w P = P ; (3) are the cross-sectional prices of risk. Note that and F are wealth-weighted combinations of the two agents preference parameters. 3.1 ICAPM with Financial Intermediaries The model in (1) is a completely generic two-agent ICAPM. In order to understand the equilibrium asset pricing implications of nancial intermediary portfolio choice, we next apply the model to an economy with Active nancial intermediaries (A) and P assive investors (P ). We let active investors be represented by leveraged nancial intermediaries, such as broker-dealers, who manage leverage in an active, procyclical fashion. Speci cally, we assume that active investors are risk neutral and maximize their expected portfolio 9

11 return subject to a risk constraint related to their Value at Risk (VaR): 2 J A t; w A ; x = max fy A i g i E e T w A (T ) (4) subject to : [V ar] : dw A 1 2 w A ; (5) [Budget] : dw A w A = iy A i dr i + r D dt; (6) where dw A is the quadratic variation of wealth and r D is the risk-free rate. The restriction on the VaR is a policy parameter times the instantanuous volatility of equity. Due to risk neutrality, the VaR constraint binds with equality. Appendix A.1 shows that the e ective risk aversion A = J A www A J A w of active investors is proportional to the Lagrange multiplier on the VaR constraint, which varies over time. We let passive investors represent the rest of the economy, including the remainder of the nancial rms, non- nancial rms and households. For simplicity, we assume that passive investors are myopic mean-variance optimizers with risk aversion given by the constant P. Appendix A.2 demonstrates that aggregation and market clearing yields the equilibrium ICAPM expressions (1) (3). In addition, we can nd reduced form expressions of the time varying e ective risk aversion A of active investors as a linear function of two state variables (x 1 ; x 2 ) 3 : A = A 1 x 1 + A 2 x 2 : (7) De ning the nancial leverage of active investors and passive investors as lev A = P i ya i and lev P = P i yp i, we nd: x 1 = 1 lev A ; x 2 = wa w P 1 1 : (8) lev A 2 A similar portfolio choice problem is examined in another context by Danielsson, Shin and Zigrand (2009). Adrian and Shin (2008) provide a microeconomic foundation for the Value-at-Risk constraint and show that it can be used to motivate the procyclical adjustment of leverage observed in the data. 3 See Equation (23) in the appendix. 10

12 Notably, this simple example shows how state variables x related to nancial intermediary leverage enter the economy s pricing kernel. Shocks to intermediary leverage may thus be priced in the cross-section of asset returns. 3.2 Empirical Implications The ICAPM equilibrium (1) along with state variables (8) motivate a linear factor model, which can be tested via the Fama and MacBeth (1973) cross-sectional regression for average excess returns Ert+1: i Note that im = Cov(ri t+1 ;rm t+1) V ar(r M t+1) Er i t+1 = + im M + 0 ix x + i ; (9) is the market beta with risk premium M = V ar r M t+1 and ix = Cov(ri t+1 ;x t+1 E tx t+1) V ar(x t+1 E tx t+1 ) are additional risk exposures with risk premia x = V ar (~x t+1 ) F, where ~x t+1 = x t+1 E t x t+1 are innovations to the state variables. As usual, the betas can be estimated from the time-series regression: r i t+1 = a i + im r M t ix~x t+1 + i t+1: (10) 4 Data and Construction of State Variables Our simple theoretical framework identi es two new potential risk factors for the pricing kernel. In this section, we construct proxies for these state variables using data on the aggregate balance sheets of U.S. security broker-dealers (active investors) and the rest of the U.S. economy (passive investors). Guided by our theoretical speci cation (8), we construct the following state vari- 11

13 ables (BD abbreviates Broker-Dealer ): x 1 t = 1 lev A t x 2 t = wa t w P t = EquityBD t Assets BD 1 1 lev A t t = CapitalRatio BD t (11) = EquityBD t Equity Non-BD t (1 CapitalRatio BD t ) (12) That is, our rst state variable is simply the capital ratio (inverse of nancial leverage) of broker-dealers. The second state variable is ratio of broker-dealer equity to nonbroker-dealer equity, multiplied by one minus broker-dealer capital ratio, which we will henceforth call the scaled wealth ratio. We construct quarterly series of these variables using data on the book values of total nancial assets and total nancial liabilities of broker-dealers and the rest of the U.S. economy as captured in the Federal Reserve Flow of Funds. 4 While the Flow of Funds data begins in the rst quarter of 1952, the data from the broker-dealer sector prior to 1968 raises suspicions. In particular, broker-dealer equity is negative over the period Q1/1952-Q4/1960 and extremely low for most of the 1960s, resulting in unreasonably low capital ratios. As a result, we begin our sample in the rst quarter of The state variables are plotted in Figure 2. To estimate the unconditional model (10), we construct shocks ~x t+1 to the log state variables as residuals from a vector autoregression conditioned on information available at time t. We incorporate a one-quarter announcement lag for the Flow of Funds variables. 5 As there is substantial multicollinearity between the two state variables, we orthogonalize the innovations of the scaled wealth ratio with respect to the innovations of the capital ratio. We obtain all data on equity portfolios and risk factors from Kenneth French s data library and cumulate these variables to quarterly frequency. 4 Note that equity t = (total nancial assets t - total nancial liabilities t ). 5 For instance, the conditional expectation at the end of March 2000 uses data from the most recent Flow of Funds release, which corresponds to December

14 Figure 2: Broker-dealer state variables. We plot the levels of broker-dealer capital ratio and the scaled broker-dealer wealth ratio (ratio of broker-dealer equity to nonbroker-dealer equity scaled by one minus broker-dealer capital ratio), as reported in the Federal Reserve s Flow of Funds Database. 5 Empirical Approach and Results We test speci cations of the linear factor model (9) in the cross-section of stock returns. The model predicts that the average cross-sectional pricing error () is zero such that all returns in excess of the risk-free rate are compensation for systematic risk. As test assets, we consider the following portfolios that address well-known shortcomings of the CAPM: 25 size and book-to-market portfolios, 25 size and momentum portfolios, and 30 industry portfolios. We compare the performance of our new pricing factors to existing benchmark models in each cross-section of test assets. Whenever a factor is a return, we include it also as a test asset since the model should apply to it as well. For instance, when pricing the portfolios sorted on size and book-to-market, we include the Fama-French (1993) factors market, SMB and HML also as test assets. This forces traded fac- 13

15 tors to price themselves and also allows us to evaluate how our model prices these important benchmark factors. A good pricing model features an economically small and statistically insigni cant alpha, statistically signi cant and stable prices of risk across di erent cross-sections of test assets, and high explanatory power as measured by the adjusted R-squared statistic. In order to correct the standard errors for the preestimation of betas, we report t-statistics of Jagannathan and Wang (1998) in addition to the t-statistics of Fama and MacBeth (1973). Following the above evaluation criteria, and by applying our model to a wide range of test assets, we seek to sidestep the criticism of traditional asset pricing tests of Lewellen, Nagel and Shanken (2010). Importantly, we show success of the model beyond the highly correlated size and book-to-market portfolios: Since the three Fama- French factors explain almost all time-series variation in these returns, the 25 portfolios essentially have only 3 degrees of freedom. As Lewellen, Nagel and Shanken point out, choosing factors that are even weakly correlated with the three Fama-French factors can give success in this cross-section and many existing models that show success in this cross-section have little or no power when other test portfolios are considered. We avoid this criticism by also including the more challenging momentum portfolios and industry portfolios as test assets. The sample considered in the main text is Q1/1968-Q4/2009. We display the results for the subsample that excludes the nancial crisis in the Appendix. 6 The results for the pre-crisis subsample, Q1/1968-Q4/2006, are similar to the results for the full sample. We also include the Pastor-Stambaugh market liquidity factor as a control in the pre-crisis sample and show that it does not a ect our comparisons. 7 6 See Tables A1-A4. The appendix also show the performance of our model in the cross-section sorted on size and long-term reversal (Table A5). 7 The Pastor-Stambaugh factor is included only in the shorter sample because it is not available 14

16 5.1 Size and Book-to-Market Portfolios We begin our asset pricing exercises with the the cross-section of 25 size and book-tomarket sorted portfolios, which since the seminal work of Fama and French (1993) has become a standard test benchmark for factor models. This cross-section highlights the inability of the CAPM to account for the over-performance of small and value stocks, a result that we con rm in column (i) of Table 1: The single market factor has no explanatory power for the average returns, yielding a large, highly statistically signi cant cross-sectional alpha of 1:54% per quarter. The cross-sectional price of risk associated with the market factor is economically small and statistically insigni cant. We contrast this failure of the CAPM with the performance of our single-factor brokerdealer model. Column (iii) shows that the broker-dealer capital ratio is able to explain 55% of the cross-sectional variation in average returns as measured by the adjusted R-squared statistic. Moreover, the cross-sectional alpha is only 0:3% per quarter and statistically indistinguishable from zero. As expected, the price of risk associated with the capital ratio is negative and statistically signi cant assets that hedge against adverse leverage shocks earn lower average returns. Column (iv) shows that including our second broker-dealer variable, the scaled wealth ratio, as an additional risk factor increases the explanatory power of the model to 64% while the alpha remains small and statistically insigni cant. As predicted by our theory, 8 the cross-sectional price of risk associated with shocks to the scaled wealth ratio is positive assets whose returns comove positively with broker-dealer wealth shocks are expected to earn higher average returns but statistically we cannot reject the hypothesis that the estimate is zero. Both broker-dealer factors are signi cant in past We thank Robert Stambaugh for posting the factor data on his website. 8 See Appendix A.2. 15

17 column (v), which adds the market factor to the speci cation. However, the adjusted explanatory power of the model remains unchanged. In the exercises that follow, we will nd that the price of risk associated with the scaled wealth ratio is often statistically insigni cant. Since our goal is to nd a robust, theoretically motivated pricing model that is able to explain average returns with consistent prices of risk across di erent sets of test assets and speci cations, our analysis will focus primarily on the rst brokerdealer factor, the capital ratio. We next compare the performance of our broker-dealer factor to the Fama-French three-factor benchmark. Column (ii) demonstrates that the Fama-French model tailored to price this cross-section produces an adjusted R-squared of 57%. Yet, this is only two percentage points greater than the explanatory power of our single-factor broker-dealer model. Note also that only the market factor and the HML factor have signi cant prices of risk. To complete the picture, column (vi) combines our brokerdealer factor with the three Fama-French factors in a four-factor speci cation. Stunningly, our broker-dealer factor drives out the value factor: the price of risk associated with HML nearly halves and the factor is no longer signi cant at 5% level. The additional explanatory power of the combined model is limited to about ten percentage points and the alpha remains small and statistically insigni cant. These observations suggest that the information content of capital ratio shocks overlap to an important extent with the information content of the Fama-French factors. The four panels of Figure 5 provide a graphical illustration of the performance of our broker-dealer models relative to the single and multi-factor benchmarks. 16

18 5.2 Size and Momentum Portfolios Table 2 and Figure 6 report the pricing results for the 25 size and momentum sorted portfolios. The format follows that of Table 1 but now the momentum factor of Carhart (1997) replaces the HML factor in the three-factor benchmark speci cation. Column (i) again con rms that the market model has no explanatory power for this cross-section. This is contrasted with column (iii), which shows that the brokerdealer capital ratio is alone capable of explaining as much as 75% of the cross-sectional returns with a small and statistically insigni cant alpha of 0:35%. As before, the price of risk associated with shocks to the capital ratio is negative and statistically signi cant. Columns (iv)-(v) demonstrate that the price of risk associated with the scaled broker-dealer wealth ratio is statistically insigni cant and neither it nor the market adds further explanatory power to the model. The alphas remain statistically insigni cant. The three-factor benchmark in column (ii) explains 77% of the crosssectional returns but produces a statistically signi cant alpha of 0:36%. Thus, our single-factor broker-dealer model again rivals the multi-factor benchmark on its very own turf. Combining our broker-dealer factor with the three-factor benchmark in column (vi) increases the explanatory power of the model to 87% and further decreases the magnitude of the alpha. In this combined speci cation, the magnitude of our leverage factor decreases, suggesting that its information content overlaps somewhat with that of the momentum factor. 5.3 Industry Portfolios Table 3 and Figure 7 display our pricing results for the 30 industry portfolios, which have posed a challenge to existing asset pricing models. Column (i) once again con- 17

19 rms the well-known result that the CAPM cannot price this simple cross-section, leaving as much as 1:44% of quarterly average returns unexplained. The results for our broker-dealer pricing models in columns (iii)-(v) tell a di erent story. In contrast to the CAPM, our single-factor broker-dealer model is able to explain 24% of the crosssectional variation with an economically smaller and statistically insigni cant alpha of 1:01%. Adding the scaled wealth ratio brings the explanatory power up to 44%, while our three-factor broker-dealer model explains 52% of the cross-section. However, consistent with our previous results, only shocks to the capital ratio receive a statistically signi cant price of risk. As multi-factor benchmark, we use the Fama-French model. The results in column (ii) show that the three Fama-French factors are able to explain only 6% of the industry cross-section with a larger and statistically signi cant alpha of 1:39%. Also, the prices of risk associated with the market, SMB and HML factors are statistically insigni cant. Thus, our single broker-dealer factor greatly outperforms the three-factor benchmark in this cross-section. The speci cation in column (vi) combines our broker-dealer factor with this benchmark to show that the price of risk associated with shocks to the capital ratio is hardly a ected by the Fama-French factors. The adjusted R-squared only increases by a few percentage points to 27% but the alpha becomes statistically signi cant, suggesting that the Fama-French factors may add more harm than good to our single-factor broker-dealer model. 5.4 Simultaneous Testing of Portfolios We have seen that our preferred broker-dealer factor, the capital ratio, has broad explanatory power with consistent prices of risk over a number of cross-sections. To further illustrate this property, we next conduct an exercise where the 25 size and book- 18

20 to-market portfolios, 10 momentum portfolios, and 30 industry portfolios are included simultaneously as test assets. These results are reported in Table 4 with graphical illustrations in Figure 8. This set of 65 test assets presents a fair test of a model s ability to t the cross-section of average returns, avoiding the critiques of Lewellen, Nagel, and Shanken (2010), and captures simultaneously four well-known asset pricing anomalies: size, book-to-market, momentum, and industry. Column (ii) shows that the Fama-French three-factor model has no explanatory power in this cross-section, with a negative adjusted R-squared statistic. The fourfactor benchmark in column (iii) which appends the Fama-French model with the momentum factor explains 42% of the cross-sectional variation in average returns but produces an alpha of 0:80% per quarter that is highly statistically signi cant. We contrast this result with column (iv), which demonstrates that our single broker-dealer factor alone outperforms the four-factor benchmark with an adjusted R-squared of 45%. Importantly, the alpha for the single broker-dealer factor is 0:67% and statistically insigni cant while the price of risk associated with shocks to broker-dealer capital ratio is 0:23% and highly statistically signi cant. These results for the combined crosssection re ect the consistent price of risk that shocks to the broker-dealer capital ratio bear across di erent cross-sections of test portfolios. In order to understand the successes and failures of the above models at a portfolio level, Figures 1, 3, and 4 plot the realized average returns against predicted average returns with labels on the individual portfolios. Figure 1 shows that the strong performance of the single broker-dealer factor stems mainly from the correct pricing of the industry portfolios and the momentum portfolios, except for the lowest momentum portfolio (Mom1) where even the four-factor model fails (see Fig. 4). The value/size cross-section is also priced well apart from the extreme small growth and extreme small 19

21 value portfolios (S1B1 and S1B5). Yet, and perhaps most notably, the broker-dealer factor is able to correctly price the value factor (HML) and size factor (SMB) a dimension where the Fama-French model itself fails miserably (see Fig. 3). 5.5 Discussion of Pricing Results The results in Tables 1-4 demonstrate that our single broker-dealer factor, the capital ratio, does remarkably well in pricing well-known asset pricing anomalies. The single factor model exhibits consistently strong pricing performance across all cross-sections of test assets, as judged by the explanatory power, the pricing error, and the economic magnitude and signi cance of the prices of risk. The performance of our model rivals and in some cases even exceeds that of the portfolio-based benchmarks that were speci cally tailored to explain each anomaly. Yet, what we nd most notable is that the prices of risk associated with our preferred broker-dealer factor are not only statistically signi cant across di erent sets of test assets, but are also relatively stable in magnitude across all four cross-sections, which was con rmed above in the combined cross-section of 65 test assets. In the singlefactor broker-dealer model (column (iii) of Tables 1-3) the price of risk associated with shocks to the broker-dealer capital ratio varies from 0:33% (size/book-to-market) to 0:36% (size/momentum) to 0:13% per quarter (industries). Including many portfolios at once (size/book-to-market, momentum, and industries) gives a price of risk of 0:23%. These ndings lend additional support to the broad-based performance of our broker-dealer model. 20

22 5.6 Further Tests In order to better understand the commonality between our two state variables and existing benchmarks, including both portfolio-based and macroeconomic models, we next examine how the factor prices of risk implied by our broker-dealer model relate to the factor prices of risk implied by such benchmarks. Table 5 conducts this comparison for three benchmark speci cations: the Fama-French three-factor model, the Lettau and Ludvigson (2001) conditional consumption CAPM model, and a three-factor macro model adapted from the speci cation of Chen, Roll and Ross (1986). 9 The results in the rst panel show that the price of risk of the capital ratio is negatively correlated with the price of HML risk, while the price of risk of the scaled wealth ratio is positively correlated with HML risk, each with a correlation parameter around 0:75. Both correlations are statistically signi cant at the 1% level. This suggests that a high value premium is associated with a high price of insurance against adverse leverage shocks (recall that capital ratio is the inverse of leverage) as well as adverse wealth shocks. Because the price of risk of the capital ratio is negative, and HML correlates negatively with the price of risk of the capital ratio, it follows that the broker-dealer leverage premium correlates positively with the growth premium, i.e. it tends to increase when growth stocks are doing well relative to value stocks. While our tests certainly do not show that broker-dealers are driving the value premium, the ndings are however consistent with the notion that a common source of risk may be driving both the value premium and the uctuations in broker-dealer leverage. For the size factor SMB, its price of risk correlates negatively with that of the capital ratio; it is not signi cantly related to the price of risk associated with shocks to the scaled 9 We thank Martin Lettau for making the factors used in Lettau and Ludvigson (2001) available on his website. All other macroeconomic data are obtained from Haver Analytics. 21

23 wealth ratio. In the second panel, we show that the prices of risk of our state variables correlate positively with the price of risk of Lettau and Ludvigson s cay factor. The capital ratio is negatively correlated with consumption growth c and the consumption growth interaction cay c, whereas the scaled wealth ratio is positively correlated with each. This suggests that adverse shocks to investment opportunities as proxied by positive shocks to broker-dealer capital ratio or negative shocks to broker-dealer wealth tend to coincide with adverse shocks to consumption growth. Finally, the third panel shows that the prices of risk associated with shocks to the broker-dealer capital ratio is also highly negatively correlated with the compensation for shocks to industrial production and for in ation risk. Conversely, the scaled wealth ratio is highly positively correlated with compensation for industrial production risk and highly negatively correlated with the compensation for con dence risk. Intuitively, adverse shocks to investment opportunities tend to coincide with lower-than-expected industrial production and higher unexpected in ation and default spreads. Taken together, the economically meaningful and statistically signi cant correlations between the prices of risk of our states variables and other common risk factors lend support to the view that shocks to our broker-dealer factors re ect unexpected changes in underlying economic and nancial fundamentals. It is in this light that we interpret the robust pricing performance of our broker-dealer model across a wide range of test assets. 6 Conclusion Broker-dealers are active investors that aggressively adjust their portfolios and risk exposure in response to economic conditions. In this paper, we ask whether broker- 22

24 dealer leverage can capture the marginal utility of wealth of active investors and hence be used as reduced form representation of the pricing kernel. We show that our brokerdealer model, with the broker-dealer capital ratio as the single pricing factor, does remarkably well in pricing the challenging cross-section of industry portfolios, clearly dominating benchmark models. Furthermore, the single factor compares favourably to the Fama-French model in the cross section of size and book-to-market sorted portfolios and it rivals the benchmark tailored to explain the cross section of size and momentum sorted portfolios. Our factor is successful across all these cross-sections in terms of high adjusted R-squared statistics, small and statistically insigni cant cross-sectional pricing errors (alphas), and prices of risk that are signi cant and consistent across portfolios. When taking all these criteria into account, our single factor outperforms standard multi-factor models tailored to price the cross-sections considered. As a theoretical motivation to our approach, we demonstrate how leverage enters the pricing kernel in an intertemporal asset pricing model through the investment decisions of long-term active investors subject to a balance sheet risk constraint (VaR). While our representative active investors the security broker-dealers have been studied extensively in the context of market making literature, the study of the information content of aggregate broker-dealer balance sheets in pricing the cross-section of stock returns is new. We regard our study as a rst step in understanding the aggregate asset pricing implications of active intermediaries in the context of long-term portfolio choice. Our results lend support to the view that the portfolio choice of active forward-looking investors provides a window to economy-wide expectations of future investment opportunities. 23

25 A Appendix A.1 Portfolio Choice of Active Investors In order to solve the portfolio choice problem (4) (6), we write the Hamilton-Jacobi- Bellman equation: E t dj A 0 = max fy A g i dt dw F w F! 2 1 ; (13) 1 where is the Lagrange multiplier on the value-at-risk constraint. We make the following guess for the value function (see Merton, 1973): J A t; x; w A = e f(t;x) w A f (T; x) = T, which implies E t dj A = f J A t +fx 0 dt E t [dx] dw A dw A dx 0 +E t + f dt w A dt w A x + 1 hdx 0 dxi f xx + fx 0 dt 2 dt hdx 0 dxi f x, dt where partial derivatives are denoted by subscripts. De ning A = J A, one obtains the rst order condition: By the binding VaR constraint, dw A 1 2 dw A 1 2 y A = 1 A (0 ) 1 ( + 0 xf x ). (14) = wa, such that: = w Ap y A0 ( 0 ) y A = wa A q ( + 0 xf x ) 0 ( 0 ) 1 ( + 0 xf x ) = wa, which implies that the e ective risk aversion is given by: q A = ( + 0 xf x ) 0 ( 0 ) 1 ( + 0 xf x ). (15) From (14), we see that the asset demands of the active investors are identical to the standard ICAPM choices, but where the risk-aversion parameter A is the scaled 24

26 Lagrange multiplier associated with the risk constraint. Even though the active investor is risk-neutral, it behaves as if it were risk-averse. In other words, the risk-aversion of the active investor uctuates with shifts in funding conditions. As the risk constraint binds more strongly, A increases and leverage must be reduced. Note that A is proportional to the generalized Sharpe ratio (adjusted for hedging costs) for the set of risky securities traded in the market as a whole. A.2 Equilibrium Returns To close the model, we assume that there is a second, passive (P ) group of investors that are non nancial corporations or households with constant relative risk aversion P. For expositional simplicity, we assume that their demands are myopic: 10 Market clearing implies: y A y P = 1 P (0 ) 1. (16) w A w A + w P + yp where s is a value-weighted aggregate supply of assets. w P = s; (17) w A + wp Plugging the asset demands (14) and (16) of the two investor types in the market clearing condition gives: w P P + wa ( 0 ) 1 + A w A A ( 0 ) 1 0 xf x = w A + w P s; or = 0 S w P = P + w A = A w A = A w P = P + w A = A 0 xf x : (18) 10 Allowing for intertemporal asset choice of passive investors is straightforward. However, for the purposes of this paper there is little value added to justify the cost of additional complexity in the equilibrium expressions. 25

27 Denote the covariance matrix of individual asset returns with the market portfolio by 0 M = ( 0 ) s; and the wealth-weighted risk aversion and the prices of risk of the state variables by = F x = w P + w A w P = P + w A = ; A w A = A w P = P + w A = f x; A such that the expected returns (18) can be written in the usual ICAPM form: = 0 M 0 xf x A.2.1 Equilibrium, F x, and A = Cov t (dr; dr M ) Cov t (dr; dx) F x : (19) We can now solve for the equilibrium prices of risk and F x, and for the scaled Lagrange multiplier A in terms of observable variables. Plugging (19) into the two investors rst order conditions gives: y A = s 1 A A (0 ) 1 0 x (F x f x ) ; (20) y P = s 1 P P (0 ) 1 0 xf x : (21) De ning the nancial leverage of active investors and passive investors as lev A = P i ya i and lev P = P i yp i, and normalizing P i s i = 1, we can rewrite (17) as: w P + w A w P lev A wa w P = levp : Using (21), it follows that: w P + w A w P lev A wa w P = P 1 P Q xf x ; 26

28 where we have de ned Q x = 1 0 ( 0 ) 1 0 x. We can rewrite the above as: = P 1 + wa w 1 leva + Q P x F x = P 1 + wa w 1 leva w A = A + Q P x w P = P + w A = f x: A On the other hand, we know that = w P +w A w P = P +w A = A, which allows us to solve for A : Since F x = = P wa w P A = P + Q x f x 1 lev A P wa w P w A = A w P = P +w A = A f x, we use the latter to obtain: F x = and wa lev A w P A5 (22) 1 + wa w P + Q P x f x 1 ; (23) 1 lev A w A w P lev A f x 1 + wa w P + Q x f x = P : (24) To gain intuition in (22) reduce to: (24), note that if both investors are myopic, the solutions = P 1 + wa w 1 leva ; P A = lev A ; F x = 0: That is, the e ective risk aversion of the economy,, decreases in the leverage of the active investors. The greater the wealth share of active investors, the greater the impact of their leverage on. 27

29 A.2.2 State Variables By inspection of (22) (24), we nominate the following two state variables: It follows that: Fx1 (x) F x2 (x) = P 2 x 1 = x 2 = wa w P 41 + x 2 1 x 1 1 lev ; A (25) 1 : (26) 1 lev A 1 x 1 fx1 1 + x 2 1 x 1 P 13 A5 ; (27) 1 + x 2 1 x 1 P + Q x f x ; (28) = 1 x 2 1 x 1 x x 2 1 x 1 + Q x f x = P f x2 A (x) = P + Q x f x x1 P x 2 : (29) Note that we can use (29) to solve for the value function of active investors. This is what we do next. A.2.3 Solving for the Value Function of Active Investors Plugging the optimal portfolio choice of active investors (14) back into the Hamilton- Jacobi-Bellman equation (13) gives: 0 = f t + f 0 x x + y A0 + r D + y A0 hdrdx 0 i f x (f xx x 0 x + f 0 x x 0 xf x ) = f t + f 0 x x + 1 A ( + 0 xf x ) 0 ( 0 ) 1 ( + 0 xf x ) + r D (f xx x 0 x + f 0 x x 0 xf x ) : Using the expression for A from (15), we obtain: 0 = f t + f 0 x x + A 2 + rd (f xx x 0 x + f 0 x x 0 xf x ) : (30) In order to solve the PDE in (30), we make the simplifying assumption that all second moments are constant. Using the equilibrium expression (29) for the scaled Lagrange 28

30 multiplier, the PDE becomes a ne in x 1 and x 2. Hence, we make the following guess for the value function: f (t; x) = A (T t) + B 1 (T t) x 1 + B 2 (T t) x 2 ; which implies: f x1 = B 1 (T t) ; f x2 = B 2 (T t) ; f xx = 0; f t = A 0 B 0 1x 1 B 0 2x 2 : Under the assumption that x (x) = k (x x), the PDE (30) simpli es to: A 0 + B 0 1x 1 + B 0 2x 2 = B 1 k 1 (x 1 x 1 ) + B 2 k 2 (x 2 x 2 ) + P + Q x1 B 1 + Q x2 B 2 P x 2 1 x 2 2 +r D B B with boundary conditions A (0) = and B (0) = 0. Thus, the problem can be expressed as a system of four equations: A 0 = B 1 k 1 x 1 B 2 k 2 x 2 + r D B B ; B 0 1 = B 1 k 1 + P + Q x1 B 1 + Q x2 B 2 2 ; B 0 2 = B 2 k 2 P 2 ; all of which have straightforward analytical solutions. Steady State Value Function. In steady states where the time derivatives are 29

31 zero, we obtain: f x1 = P + Q x2 f x2 2 k 1 Q x1 ; (31) f x2 = P k 2 2 ; (32) Note that f x2 < 0. Recall also that Q x = 1 0 ( 0 ) 1 0 x; in other words, Q x1 and Q x2 are sums of OLS regression coe cients from time-series regressions of each state variable on the set of test assets. Estimated from quarterly data, Q x1 and Q x2 are of similar magnitudes and lie between 0:05 and 0:03 (depending on the set of test assets), implying that the denominator of (31) is positive. It follows that f x1 is positive if: P + Q x2 f x2 > 0 which holds since Q x2 < 0., 2 Q x2 k 2 > 0; Steady-State Prices of Risk. The prices of risk F x associated with the state variables are given by (24) as: Fx1 = F x2 w A lev A w P 1 + wa + Q w P x f x = P fx1 Thus, the signs of F x are the same as the signs of f x if the common multiplier w A lev A = 1 + wa + Q w P w P x f x = P is positive. Since the numerator of the expression is always positive, this condition holds if: P 1 + wa + Q w P x f x > 0: A su cient (but not necessary) condition is P +Q x f x > 0, which by (29) is equivalent to requiring that the e ective risk aversion of broker-dealers A is positively related to inverse of broker-dealer leverage x 1. Thus, we may expect F x1 > 0 and F x2 < 0, which implies that the expected factor risk premia are x1 < 0 and x2 > 0. f x2 : 30

Broker-Dealer Leverage and the Cross-Section of Stock Returns 1

Broker-Dealer Leverage and the Cross-Section of Stock Returns 1 Broker-Dealer Leverage and the Cross-Section of Stock Returns 1 Tobias Adrian, Erkko Etula and Tyler Muir Federal Reserve Bank of New York and Northwestern University Bank of England, January -5, 11 1

More information

econstor zbw www.econstor.eu

econstor zbw www.econstor.eu econstor www.econstor.eu Der Open-Access-Publikationsserver der ZBW Leibniz-Informationszentrum Wirtschaft The Open Access Publication Server of the ZBW Leibniz Information Centre for Economics Adrian,

More information

Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Reports

Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Reports Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Reports Financial Intermediaries and the Cross-Section of Asset Returns Tobias Adrian Erkko Etula Tyler Muir Staff Report no. 464 July 2010 Revised April 2011 This

More information

Financial Intermediaries and the Cross-Section of Asset Returns

Financial Intermediaries and the Cross-Section of Asset Returns Financial Intermediaries and the Cross-Section of Asset Returns Tobias Adrian - Federal Reserve Bank of New York 1 Erkko Etula - Goldman Sachs Tyler Muir - Kellogg School of Management May, 2012 1 The

More information

CAPM, Arbitrage, and Linear Factor Models

CAPM, Arbitrage, and Linear Factor Models CAPM, Arbitrage, and Linear Factor Models CAPM, Arbitrage, Linear Factor Models 1/ 41 Introduction We now assume all investors actually choose mean-variance e cient portfolios. By equating these investors

More information

Financial Intermediaries and the Cross-Section of Asset Returns

Financial Intermediaries and the Cross-Section of Asset Returns Financial Intermediaries and the Cross-Section of Asset Returns Tobias Adrian tobias.adrian@ny.frb.org Erkko Etula etula@post.harvard.edu Tyler Muir t-muir@kellogg.northwestern.edu August 2013 Capital

More information

Risk Appetite and Commodity Returns

Risk Appetite and Commodity Returns Risk Appetite and Commodity Returns Erkko Etula Harvard University etula@fas.harvard.edu February 2009 Abstract This paper shows that the risk appetite of leveraged nancial institutions such as security

More information

Discussion of Momentum and Autocorrelation in Stock Returns

Discussion of Momentum and Autocorrelation in Stock Returns Discussion of Momentum and Autocorrelation in Stock Returns Joseph Chen University of Southern California Harrison Hong Stanford University Jegadeesh and Titman (1993) document individual stock momentum:

More information

Chap 3 CAPM, Arbitrage, and Linear Factor Models

Chap 3 CAPM, Arbitrage, and Linear Factor Models Chap 3 CAPM, Arbitrage, and Linear Factor Models 1 Asset Pricing Model a logical extension of portfolio selection theory is to consider the equilibrium asset pricing consequences of investors individually

More information

Internet Appendix for Institutional Trade Persistence and Long-term Equity Returns

Internet Appendix for Institutional Trade Persistence and Long-term Equity Returns Internet Appendix for Institutional Trade Persistence and Long-term Equity Returns AMIL DASGUPTA, ANDREA PRAT, and MICHELA VERARDO Abstract In this document we provide supplementary material and robustness

More information

Online appendix to paper Downside Market Risk of Carry Trades

Online appendix to paper Downside Market Risk of Carry Trades Online appendix to paper Downside Market Risk of Carry Trades A1. SUB-SAMPLE OF DEVELOPED COUNTRIES I study a sub-sample of developed countries separately for two reasons. First, some of the emerging countries

More information

Dynamic Leverage Asset Pricing

Dynamic Leverage Asset Pricing Dynamic Leverage Asset Pricing Tobias Adrian Emanuel Moench Hyun Song Shin This version: February 28, 2015 Abstract We empirically investigate predictions from alternative intermediary asset pricing theories.

More information

Value, momentum, and short-term interest rates

Value, momentum, and short-term interest rates Value, momentum, and short-term interest rates Paulo Maio 1 Pedro Santa-Clara 2 First version: July 2011 This version: December 2011 3 1 Hanken School of Economics. E-mail: paulofmaio@gmail.com. 2 Millennium

More information

Appendices with Supplementary Materials for CAPM for Estimating Cost of Equity Capital: Interpreting the Empirical Evidence

Appendices with Supplementary Materials for CAPM for Estimating Cost of Equity Capital: Interpreting the Empirical Evidence Appendices with Supplementary Materials for CAPM for Estimating Cost of Equity Capital: Interpreting the Empirical Evidence This document contains supplementary material to the paper titled CAPM for estimating

More information

Broker-Dealer Risk Appetite and Commodity Returns

Broker-Dealer Risk Appetite and Commodity Returns Broker-Dealer Risk Appetite and Commodity Returns Erkko Etula Federal Reserve Bank of New York erkko.etula@ny.frb.org First Draft: November 2008 This Draft: November 2009 Abstract This paper shows that

More information

Does Mutual Fund Performance Vary over the Business Cycle?

Does Mutual Fund Performance Vary over the Business Cycle? Does Mutual Fund Performance Vary over the Business Cycle? Anthony W. Lynch New York University and NBER Jessica Wachter New York University and NBER Walter Boudry New York University First Version: 15

More information

The Cost of Capital of the Financial Sector

The Cost of Capital of the Financial Sector Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Reports The Cost of Capital of the Financial Sector Tobias Adrian Evan Friedman Tyler Muir Staff Report No. 755 December 2015 This paper presents preliminary findings

More information

Chapter 5. Conditional CAPM. 5.1 Conditional CAPM: Theory. 5.1.1 Risk According to the CAPM. The CAPM is not a perfect model of expected returns.

Chapter 5. Conditional CAPM. 5.1 Conditional CAPM: Theory. 5.1.1 Risk According to the CAPM. The CAPM is not a perfect model of expected returns. Chapter 5 Conditional CAPM 5.1 Conditional CAPM: Theory 5.1.1 Risk According to the CAPM The CAPM is not a perfect model of expected returns. In the 40+ years of its history, many systematic deviations

More information

Models of Asset Pricing The implications for asset allocation

Models of Asset Pricing The implications for asset allocation Models of Asset Pricing The implications for asset allocation 2004 Finance & Investment Conference 28 June 2004 Tim Giles CHARLES RIVER ASSOCIATES Vice President CRA London CRA 2004 Agenda New orthodoxy

More information

EVALUATION OF THE PAIRS TRADING STRATEGY IN THE CANADIAN MARKET

EVALUATION OF THE PAIRS TRADING STRATEGY IN THE CANADIAN MARKET EVALUATION OF THE PAIRS TRADING STRATEGY IN THE CANADIAN MARKET By Doris Siy-Yap PROJECT SUBMITTED IN PARTIAL FULFILLMENT OF THE REQUIREMENTS FOR THE DEGREE OF MASTER IN BUSINESS ADMINISTRATION Approval

More information

DOES IT PAY TO HAVE FAT TAILS? EXAMINING KURTOSIS AND THE CROSS-SECTION OF STOCK RETURNS

DOES IT PAY TO HAVE FAT TAILS? EXAMINING KURTOSIS AND THE CROSS-SECTION OF STOCK RETURNS DOES IT PAY TO HAVE FAT TAILS? EXAMINING KURTOSIS AND THE CROSS-SECTION OF STOCK RETURNS By Benjamin M. Blau 1, Abdullah Masud 2, and Ryan J. Whitby 3 Abstract: Xiong and Idzorek (2011) show that extremely

More information

The Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM)

The Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM) Prof. Alex Shapiro Lecture Notes 9 The Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM) I. Readings and Suggested Practice Problems II. III. IV. Introduction: from Assumptions to Implications The Market Portfolio Assumptions

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES CARRY TRADES AND RISK. Craig Burnside. Working Paper 17278 http://www.nber.org/papers/w17278

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES CARRY TRADES AND RISK. Craig Burnside. Working Paper 17278 http://www.nber.org/papers/w17278 NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES CARRY TRADES AND RISK Craig Burnside Working Paper 17278 http://www.nber.org/papers/w17278 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge, MA 02138 August

More information

Asymmetric Volatility and the Cross-Section of Returns: Is Implied Market Volatility a Risk Factor?

Asymmetric Volatility and the Cross-Section of Returns: Is Implied Market Volatility a Risk Factor? Asymmetric Volatility and the Cross-Section of Returns: Is Implied Market Volatility a Risk Factor? R. Jared Delisle James S. Doran David R. Peterson Florida State University Draft: June 6, 2009 Acknowledgements:

More information

Illiquidity frictions and asset pricing anomalies

Illiquidity frictions and asset pricing anomalies Illiquidity frictions and asset pricing anomalies Björn Hagströmer a, Björn Hansson b, Birger Nilsson,b a Stockholm University, School of Business, S-10691 Stockholm, Sweden b Department of Economics and

More information

Normalization and Mixed Degrees of Integration in Cointegrated Time Series Systems

Normalization and Mixed Degrees of Integration in Cointegrated Time Series Systems Normalization and Mixed Degrees of Integration in Cointegrated Time Series Systems Robert J. Rossana Department of Economics, 04 F/AB, Wayne State University, Detroit MI 480 E-Mail: r.j.rossana@wayne.edu

More information

LIQUIDITY AND ASSET PRICING. Evidence for the London Stock Exchange

LIQUIDITY AND ASSET PRICING. Evidence for the London Stock Exchange LIQUIDITY AND ASSET PRICING Evidence for the London Stock Exchange Timo Hubers (358022) Bachelor thesis Bachelor Bedrijfseconomie Tilburg University May 2012 Supervisor: M. Nie MSc Table of Contents Chapter

More information

The capital asset pricing model (CAPM) of William Sharpe (1964) and John

The capital asset pricing model (CAPM) of William Sharpe (1964) and John Journal of Economic Perspectives Volume 18, Number 3 Summer 2004 Pages 25 46 The Capital Asset Pricing Model: Theory and Evidence Eugene F. Fama and Kenneth R. French The capital asset pricing model (CAPM)

More information

Market Efficiency and Behavioral Finance. Chapter 12

Market Efficiency and Behavioral Finance. Chapter 12 Market Efficiency and Behavioral Finance Chapter 12 Market Efficiency if stock prices reflect firm performance, should we be able to predict them? if prices were to be predictable, that would create the

More information

The Real Business Cycle Model

The Real Business Cycle Model The Real Business Cycle Model Ester Faia Goethe University Frankfurt Nov 2015 Ester Faia (Goethe University Frankfurt) RBC Nov 2015 1 / 27 Introduction The RBC model explains the co-movements in the uctuations

More information

Review for Exam 2. Instructions: Please read carefully

Review for Exam 2. Instructions: Please read carefully Review for Exam 2 Instructions: Please read carefully The exam will have 25 multiple choice questions and 5 work problems You are not responsible for any topics that are not covered in the lecture note

More information

B.3. Robustness: alternative betas estimation

B.3. Robustness: alternative betas estimation Appendix B. Additional empirical results and robustness tests This Appendix contains additional empirical results and robustness tests. B.1. Sharpe ratios of beta-sorted portfolios Fig. B1 plots the Sharpe

More information

Models of Risk and Return

Models of Risk and Return Models of Risk and Return Aswath Damodaran Aswath Damodaran 1 First Principles Invest in projects that yield a return greater than the minimum acceptable hurdle rate. The hurdle rate should be higher for

More information

The Risk-Free Rate s Impact on Stock Returns with Representative Fund Managers

The Risk-Free Rate s Impact on Stock Returns with Representative Fund Managers School of Economics and Management Department of Business Administration FEKN90 Business Administration- Degree Project Master of Science in Business and Economics Spring term of 2013 The Risk-Free Rate

More information

Foundations of Asset Management Goal-based Investing the Next Trend

Foundations of Asset Management Goal-based Investing the Next Trend Foundations of Asset Management Goal-based Investing the Next Trend Robert C. Merton Distinguished Professor of Finance MIT Finance Forum May 16, 2014 #MITSloanFinance 1 Agenda Goal-based approach to investment

More information

How To Explain Momentum Anomaly In International Equity Market

How To Explain Momentum Anomaly In International Equity Market Does the alternative three-factor model explain momentum anomaly better in G12 countries? Steve Fan University of Wisconsin Whitewater Linda Yu University of Wisconsin Whitewater ABSTRACT This study constructs

More information

Equity Risk Premium Article Michael Annin, CFA and Dominic Falaschetti, CFA

Equity Risk Premium Article Michael Annin, CFA and Dominic Falaschetti, CFA Equity Risk Premium Article Michael Annin, CFA and Dominic Falaschetti, CFA This article appears in the January/February 1998 issue of Valuation Strategies. Executive Summary This article explores one

More information

Asset Management Contracts and Equilibrium Prices

Asset Management Contracts and Equilibrium Prices Asset Management Contracts and Equilibrium Prices ANDREA M. BUFFA DIMITRI VAYANOS PAUL WOOLLEY Boston University London School of Economics London School of Economics September, 2013 Abstract We study

More information

A note on the impact of options on stock return volatility 1

A note on the impact of options on stock return volatility 1 Journal of Banking & Finance 22 (1998) 1181±1191 A note on the impact of options on stock return volatility 1 Nicolas P.B. Bollen 2 University of Utah, David Eccles School of Business, Salt Lake City,

More information

HARVARD UNIVERSITY Department of Economics

HARVARD UNIVERSITY Department of Economics HARVARD UNIVERSITY Department of Economics Economics 970 Behavioral Finance Science Center 103b Spring 2002 M, W 7-8:30 pm Mr. Evgeny Agronin Teaching Fellow agronin@fas.harvard.edu (617) 868-5766 Course

More information

Price-Earnings Ratios: Growth and Discount Rates

Price-Earnings Ratios: Growth and Discount Rates Price-Earnings Ratios: Growth and Discount Rates Andrew Ang Columbia University and NBER Xiaoyan Zhang Purdue University This Version: 20 May 2011 We thank Geert Bekaert, Sigbjørn Berg, and Tørres Trovik

More information

Cash Holdings and Mutual Fund Performance. Online Appendix

Cash Holdings and Mutual Fund Performance. Online Appendix Cash Holdings and Mutual Fund Performance Online Appendix Mikhail Simutin Abstract This online appendix shows robustness to alternative definitions of abnormal cash holdings, studies the relation between

More information

When Variance Risk Has Two Prices: Evidence from the Equity and Option Markets

When Variance Risk Has Two Prices: Evidence from the Equity and Option Markets When Variance Risk Has Two Prices: Evidence from the Equity and Option Markets Laurent Barras y Aytek Malkhozov z October 13, 2014 Abstract We estimate the quarterly dynamics of the Variance Risk Premium

More information

4. Only one asset that can be used for production, and is available in xed supply in the aggregate (call it land).

4. Only one asset that can be used for production, and is available in xed supply in the aggregate (call it land). Chapter 3 Credit and Business Cycles Here I present a model of the interaction between credit and business cycles. In representative agent models, remember, no lending takes place! The literature on the

More information

Equity Market Risk Premium Research Summary. 12 April 2016

Equity Market Risk Premium Research Summary. 12 April 2016 Equity Market Risk Premium Research Summary 12 April 2016 Introduction welcome If you are reading this, it is likely that you are in regular contact with KPMG on the topic of valuations. The goal of this

More information

Forecasting Japanese Stock Returns with

Forecasting Japanese Stock Returns with JSPS Grants-in-Aid for Creative Scientific Research Understanding Inflation Dynamics of the Japanese Economy Working Paper Series No.63 Forecasting Japanese Stock Returns with Financial Ratios and Other

More information

Discussion: In Search of Distress Risk and Default Risk, Shareholder Advantage, and Stock Returns

Discussion: In Search of Distress Risk and Default Risk, Shareholder Advantage, and Stock Returns Discussion: In Search of Distress Risk and Default Risk, Shareholder Advantage, and Stock Returns Kent D. Daniel 1 1 Goldman Sachs Asset Management and Kellogg, Northwestern NYU/Moody s Credit Conference,

More information

Real Business Cycle Theory. Marco Di Pietro Advanced () Monetary Economics and Policy 1 / 35

Real Business Cycle Theory. Marco Di Pietro Advanced () Monetary Economics and Policy 1 / 35 Real Business Cycle Theory Marco Di Pietro Advanced () Monetary Economics and Policy 1 / 35 Introduction to DSGE models Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium (DSGE) models have become the main tool for

More information

Internet Appendix to Stock Market Liquidity and the Business Cycle

Internet Appendix to Stock Market Liquidity and the Business Cycle Internet Appendix to Stock Market Liquidity and the Business Cycle Randi Næs, Johannes A. Skjeltorp and Bernt Arne Ødegaard This Internet appendix contains additional material to the paper Stock Market

More information

Real Business Cycle Models

Real Business Cycle Models Real Business Cycle Models Lecture 2 Nicola Viegi April 2015 Basic RBC Model Claim: Stochastic General Equlibrium Model Is Enough to Explain The Business cycle Behaviour of the Economy Money is of little

More information

Online Appendix to Impatient Trading, Liquidity. Provision, and Stock Selection by Mutual Funds

Online Appendix to Impatient Trading, Liquidity. Provision, and Stock Selection by Mutual Funds Online Appendix to Impatient Trading, Liquidity Provision, and Stock Selection by Mutual Funds Zhi Da, Pengjie Gao, and Ravi Jagannathan This Draft: April 10, 2010 Correspondence: Zhi Da, Finance Department,

More information

Salvaging the C-CAPM: Currency Carry Trade Risk Premia and Conditioning Information

Salvaging the C-CAPM: Currency Carry Trade Risk Premia and Conditioning Information Salvaging the C-CAPM: Currency Carry Trade Risk Premia and Conditioning Information Abhay Abhyankar y, Angelica Gonzalez z, Olga Klinkowska x, This version: December 2011 First Version: Sept 2011 Abstract

More information

Internet Appendix to CAPM for estimating cost of equity capital: Interpreting the empirical evidence

Internet Appendix to CAPM for estimating cost of equity capital: Interpreting the empirical evidence Internet Appendix to CAPM for estimating cost of equity capital: Interpreting the empirical evidence This document contains supplementary material to the paper titled CAPM for estimating cost of equity

More information

Asymmetry and the Cost of Capital

Asymmetry and the Cost of Capital Asymmetry and the Cost of Capital Javier García Sánchez, IAE Business School Lorenzo Preve, IAE Business School Virginia Sarria Allende, IAE Business School Abstract The expected cost of capital is a crucial

More information

Stocks with Extreme Past Returns: Lotteries or Insurance?

Stocks with Extreme Past Returns: Lotteries or Insurance? Stocks with Extreme Past Returns: Lotteries or Insurance? Alexander Barinov Terry College of Business University of Georgia E-mail: abarinov@terry.uga.edu http://abarinov.myweb.uga.edu/ This version: June

More information

The Cross-Section of Volatility and Expected Returns

The Cross-Section of Volatility and Expected Returns THE JOURNAL OF FINANCE VOL. LXI, NO. 1 FEBRUARY 2006 The Cross-Section of Volatility and Expected Returns ANDREW ANG, ROBERT J. HODRICK, YUHANG XING, and XIAOYAN ZHANG ABSTRACT We examine the pricing of

More information

8.1 Summary and conclusions 8.2 Implications

8.1 Summary and conclusions 8.2 Implications Conclusion and Implication V{tÑàxÜ CONCLUSION AND IMPLICATION 8 Contents 8.1 Summary and conclusions 8.2 Implications Having done the selection of macroeconomic variables, forecasting the series and construction

More information

Oil Volatility Risk and Expected Stock Returns. Peter Christoffersen and Xuhui (Nick) Pan. CREATES Research Paper 2015-6

Oil Volatility Risk and Expected Stock Returns. Peter Christoffersen and Xuhui (Nick) Pan. CREATES Research Paper 2015-6 Oil Volatility Risk and Expected Stock Returns Peter Christoffersen and Xuhui (Nick) Pan CREATES Research Paper 215-6 Department of Economics and Business Aarhus University Fuglesangs Allé 4 DK-821 Aarhus

More information

Does Mutual Fund Performance Vary over the Business Cycle?

Does Mutual Fund Performance Vary over the Business Cycle? Does Mutual Fund Performance Vary over the Business Cycle? Anthony W. Lynch New York University and NBER Jessica A. Wachter University of Pennsylvania and NBER First Version: 15 November 2002 Current Version:

More information

Chapter 1. Vector autoregressions. 1.1 VARs and the identi cation problem

Chapter 1. Vector autoregressions. 1.1 VARs and the identi cation problem Chapter Vector autoregressions We begin by taking a look at the data of macroeconomics. A way to summarize the dynamics of macroeconomic data is to make use of vector autoregressions. VAR models have become

More information

Topic 5: Stochastic Growth and Real Business Cycles

Topic 5: Stochastic Growth and Real Business Cycles Topic 5: Stochastic Growth and Real Business Cycles Yulei Luo SEF of HKU October 1, 2015 Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) Macro Theory October 1, 2015 1 / 45 Lag Operators The lag operator (L) is de ned as Similar

More information

The Supply and Demand of S&P 500 Put Options

The Supply and Demand of S&P 500 Put Options The Supply and Demand of S&P 500 Put Options George Constantinides University of Chicago Lei Lian University of Massachusetts at Amherst October 28 2015 George Constantinides; Lei Lian The Supply and Demand

More information

Stock market booms and real economic activity: Is this time different?

Stock market booms and real economic activity: Is this time different? International Review of Economics and Finance 9 (2000) 387 415 Stock market booms and real economic activity: Is this time different? Mathias Binswanger* Institute for Economics and the Environment, University

More information

Momentum and Autocorrelation in Stock Returns

Momentum and Autocorrelation in Stock Returns Momentum and Autocorrelation in Stock Returns Jonathan Lewellen MIT Sloan School of Management This article studies momentum in stock returns, focusing on the role of industry, size, and book-to-market

More information

Do the asset pricing factors predict future economy growth? An Australian study. Bin Liu Amalia Di Iorio

Do the asset pricing factors predict future economy growth? An Australian study. Bin Liu Amalia Di Iorio Do the asset pricing factors predict future economy growth? An Australian study. Bin Liu Amalia Di Iorio Abstract In this paper we examine whether past returns of the market portfolio (MKT), the size portfolio

More information

Online Appendix for External Equity Financing Shocks, Financial Flows, and Asset Prices

Online Appendix for External Equity Financing Shocks, Financial Flows, and Asset Prices NOT FOR PUBLICATION Online Appendix for External Equity Financing Shocks, Financial Flows, and Asset Prices FREDERICO BELO, XIAOJI LIN, AND FAN YANG 1 This appendix contains tables and figures that supplement

More information

Lecture 6: Arbitrage Pricing Theory

Lecture 6: Arbitrage Pricing Theory Lecture 6: Arbitrage Pricing Theory Investments FIN460-Papanikolaou APT 1/ 48 Overview 1. Introduction 2. Multi-Factor Models 3. The Arbitrage Pricing Theory FIN460-Papanikolaou APT 2/ 48 Introduction

More information

Investing in Foreign Currency is like Betting on your Intertemporal Marginal Rate of Substitution.

Investing in Foreign Currency is like Betting on your Intertemporal Marginal Rate of Substitution. Investing in Foreign Currency is like Betting on your Intertemporal Marginal Rate of Substitution. Hanno Lustig UCLA and NBER Adrien Verdelhan Boston University December 13, 2005 Abstract Investors earn

More information

How To Predict Stock Returns

How To Predict Stock Returns Irreversible Investment and the Cross-Section of Stock Returns in General Equilibrium Vito D. Gala February 2007 London Business School. Correspondence to vgala@london.edu. This paper is based on my doctoral

More information

Journal of Exclusive Management Science May 2015 -Vol 4 Issue 5 - ISSN 2277 5684

Journal of Exclusive Management Science May 2015 -Vol 4 Issue 5 - ISSN 2277 5684 Journal of Exclusive Management Science May 2015 Vol 4 Issue 5 ISSN 2277 5684 A Study on the Emprical Testing Of Capital Asset Pricing Model on Selected Energy Sector Companies Listed In NSE Abstract *S.A.

More information

A Mean-Variance Framework for Tests of Asset Pricing Models

A Mean-Variance Framework for Tests of Asset Pricing Models A Mean-Variance Framework for Tests of Asset Pricing Models Shmuel Kandel University of Chicago Tel-Aviv, University Robert F. Stambaugh University of Pennsylvania This article presents a mean-variance

More information

A Panel Data Analysis of Corporate Attributes and Stock Prices for Indian Manufacturing Sector

A Panel Data Analysis of Corporate Attributes and Stock Prices for Indian Manufacturing Sector Journal of Modern Accounting and Auditing, ISSN 1548-6583 November 2013, Vol. 9, No. 11, 1519-1525 D DAVID PUBLISHING A Panel Data Analysis of Corporate Attributes and Stock Prices for Indian Manufacturing

More information

What Determines Chinese Stock Returns?

What Determines Chinese Stock Returns? What Determines Chinese Stock Returns? Fenghua Wang and Yexiao Xu * Abstract Size, not book-to-market, helps to explain cross-sectional differences in Chinese stock returns from 1996-2002. Similar to the

More information

René Garcia Professor of finance

René Garcia Professor of finance Liquidity Risk: What is it? How to Measure it? René Garcia Professor of finance EDHEC Business School, CIRANO Cirano, Montreal, January 7, 2009 The financial and economic environment We are living through

More information

1 Another method of estimation: least squares

1 Another method of estimation: least squares 1 Another method of estimation: least squares erm: -estim.tex, Dec8, 009: 6 p.m. (draft - typos/writos likely exist) Corrections, comments, suggestions welcome. 1.1 Least squares in general Assume Y i

More information

Solution: The optimal position for an investor with a coefficient of risk aversion A = 5 in the risky asset is y*:

Solution: The optimal position for an investor with a coefficient of risk aversion A = 5 in the risky asset is y*: Problem 1. Consider a risky asset. Suppose the expected rate of return on the risky asset is 15%, the standard deviation of the asset return is 22%, and the risk-free rate is 6%. What is your optimal position

More information

Why are Some Diversified U.S. Equity Funds Less Diversified Than Others? A Study on the Industry Concentration of Mutual Funds

Why are Some Diversified U.S. Equity Funds Less Diversified Than Others? A Study on the Industry Concentration of Mutual Funds Why are Some Diversified U.S. Equity unds Less Diversified Than Others? A Study on the Industry Concentration of Mutual unds Binying Liu Advisor: Matthew C. Harding Department of Economics Stanford University

More information

Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Reports

Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Reports Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Reports Financial Intermediation, Asset Prices, and Macroeconomic Dynamics Tobias Adrian Emanuel Moench Hyun Song Shin Staff Report no. 422 January 2010 Revised September

More information

Absolute Strength: Exploring Momentum in Stock Returns

Absolute Strength: Exploring Momentum in Stock Returns Absolute Strength: Exploring Momentum in Stock Returns Huseyin Gulen Krannert School of Management Purdue University Ralitsa Petkova Weatherhead School of Management Case Western Reserve University March

More information

ON THE RISK ADJUSTED DISCOUNT RATE FOR DETERMINING LIFE OFFICE APPRAISAL VALUES BY M. SHERRIS B.A., M.B.A., F.I.A., F.I.A.A. 1.

ON THE RISK ADJUSTED DISCOUNT RATE FOR DETERMINING LIFE OFFICE APPRAISAL VALUES BY M. SHERRIS B.A., M.B.A., F.I.A., F.I.A.A. 1. ON THE RISK ADJUSTED DISCOUNT RATE FOR DETERMINING LIFE OFFICE APPRAISAL VALUES BY M. SHERRIS B.A., M.B.A., F.I.A., F.I.A.A. 1. INTRODUCTION 1.1 A number of papers have been written in recent years that

More information

Chapter 9. The Valuation of Common Stock. 1.The Expected Return (Copied from Unit02, slide 36)

Chapter 9. The Valuation of Common Stock. 1.The Expected Return (Copied from Unit02, slide 36) Readings Chapters 9 and 10 Chapter 9. The Valuation of Common Stock 1. The investor s expected return 2. Valuation as the Present Value (PV) of dividends and the growth of dividends 3. The investor s required

More information

Monetary Policy Surprises, Credit Costs. and. Economic Activity

Monetary Policy Surprises, Credit Costs. and. Economic Activity Monetary Policy Surprises, Credit Costs and Economic Activity Mark Gertler and Peter Karadi NYU and ECB BIS, March 215 The views expressed are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the offi

More information

Research Division Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Working Paper Series

Research Division Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Working Paper Series Research Division Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Working Paper Series Market Timing with Aggregate and Idiosyncratic Stock Volatilities Hui Guo and Jason Higbee Working Paper 2005-073B http://research.stlouisfed.org/wp/2005/2005-073.pdf

More information

6. Budget Deficits and Fiscal Policy

6. Budget Deficits and Fiscal Policy Prof. Dr. Thomas Steger Advanced Macroeconomics II Lecture SS 2012 6. Budget Deficits and Fiscal Policy Introduction Ricardian equivalence Distorting taxes Debt crises Introduction (1) Ricardian equivalence

More information

Do Implied Volatilities Predict Stock Returns?

Do Implied Volatilities Predict Stock Returns? Do Implied Volatilities Predict Stock Returns? Manuel Ammann, Michael Verhofen and Stephan Süss University of St. Gallen Abstract Using a complete sample of US equity options, we find a positive, highly

More information

Integration of the Mexican Stock Market. Abstract

Integration of the Mexican Stock Market. Abstract Integration of the Mexican Stock Market Alonso Gomez Albert Department of Economics University of Toronto Version 02.02.06 Abstract In this paper, I study the ability of multi-factor asset pricing models

More information

The CAPM (Capital Asset Pricing Model) NPV Dependent on Discount Rate Schedule

The CAPM (Capital Asset Pricing Model) NPV Dependent on Discount Rate Schedule The CAPM (Capital Asset Pricing Model) Massachusetts Institute of Technology CAPM Slide 1 of NPV Dependent on Discount Rate Schedule Discussed NPV and time value of money Choice of discount rate influences

More information

Norges Bank s Expert Group on Principles for Risk Adjustment of Performance Figures Final Report

Norges Bank s Expert Group on Principles for Risk Adjustment of Performance Figures Final Report Norges Bank s Expert Group on Principles for Risk Adjustment of Performance Figures Final Report November 16, 2015 Magnus Dahlquist Professor, Stockholm School of Economics Christopher Polk Professor,

More information

Betting Against Beta

Betting Against Beta Betting Against Beta Andrea Frazzini AQR Capital Management LLC Lasse H. Pedersen NYU, CEPR, and NBER Preliminary Copyright 2010 by Andrea Frazzini and Lasse H. Pedersen Motivation Background: Security

More information

The Tangent or Efficient Portfolio

The Tangent or Efficient Portfolio The Tangent or Efficient Portfolio 1 2 Identifying the Tangent Portfolio Sharpe Ratio: Measures the ratio of reward-to-volatility provided by a portfolio Sharpe Ratio Portfolio Excess Return E[ RP ] r

More information

W ORKING PAPERS SES. A Note on the Impact of Portfolio Overlapping in Tests of the Fama and French Three-Factor Model 11.

W ORKING PAPERS SES. A Note on the Impact of Portfolio Overlapping in Tests of the Fama and French Three-Factor Model 11. 11.2012 N 433 W ORKING PAPERS SES A Note on the Impact of Portfolio Overlapping in Tests of the Fama and French Three-Factor Model Martin Wallmeier and Kathrin Tauscher F ACULTÉ DES SCIENCES ECONOMIQUES

More information

Dividends and Momentum

Dividends and Momentum WORKING PAPER Dividends and Momentum Owain ap Gwilym, Andrew Clare, James Seaton & Stephen Thomas October 2008 ISSN Centre for Asset Management Research Cass Business School City University 106 Bunhill

More information

Discussion of Betermier, Calvet, and Sodini Who are the Value and Growth Investors?

Discussion of Betermier, Calvet, and Sodini Who are the Value and Growth Investors? Discussion of Betermier, Calvet, and Sodini Who are the Value and Growth Investors? NBER Summer Institute Asset Pricing Meeting July 11 2014 Jonathan A. Parker MIT Sloan finance Outline 1. Summary 2. Value

More information

The Impact of Interest Rate Shocks on the Performance of the Banking Sector

The Impact of Interest Rate Shocks on the Performance of the Banking Sector The Impact of Interest Rate Shocks on the Performance of the Banking Sector by Wensheng Peng, Kitty Lai, Frank Leung and Chang Shu of the Research Department A rise in the Hong Kong dollar risk premium,

More information

Financial Development and Macroeconomic Stability

Financial Development and Macroeconomic Stability Financial Development and Macroeconomic Stability Vincenzo Quadrini University of Southern California Urban Jermann Wharton School of the University of Pennsylvania January 31, 2005 VERY PRELIMINARY AND

More information

Asian Economic and Financial Review THE CAPITAL INVESTMENT INCREASES AND STOCK RETURNS

Asian Economic and Financial Review THE CAPITAL INVESTMENT INCREASES AND STOCK RETURNS Asian Economic and Financial Review journal homepage: http://www.aessweb.com/journals/5002 THE CAPITAL INVESTMENT INCREASES AND STOCK RETURNS Jung Fang Liu 1 --- Nicholas Rueilin Lee 2 * --- Yih-Bey Lin

More information

Lesson 5. Risky assets

Lesson 5. Risky assets Lesson 5. Risky assets Prof. Beatriz de Blas May 2006 5. Risky assets 2 Introduction How stock markets serve to allocate risk. Plan of the lesson: 8 >< >: 1. Risk and risk aversion 2. Portfolio risk 3.

More information

Discussion of "The Cross Section and Time Series of Stock and Bond Returns" by Koijen, Lustig & Van Nieuwerburgh

Discussion of The Cross Section and Time Series of Stock and Bond Returns by Koijen, Lustig & Van Nieuwerburgh Discussion of "The Cross Section and Time Series of Stock and Bond Returns" by Koijen, Lustig & Van Nieuwerburgh Monika Piazzesi Stanford University & NBER AFA Atlanta 2010 Summary A ne model in which:

More information

Variance Risk Premium and Cross Section of Stock Returns

Variance Risk Premium and Cross Section of Stock Returns Variance Risk Premium and Cross Section of Stock Returns Bing Han and Yi Zhou This Version: December 2011 Abstract We use equity option prices and high frequency stock prices to estimate stock s variance

More information