Risk Appetite and Commodity Returns

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Risk Appetite and Commodity Returns"

Transcription

1 Risk Appetite and Commodity Returns Erkko Etula Harvard University February 2009 Abstract This paper shows that the risk appetite of leveraged nancial institutions such as security broker-dealers forecasts commodity returns at quarterly horizons. The result holds robustly both in-sample and out-of-sample and is particularly strong for energy commodities: the single variable is able to forecast up to 34% of the variation in quarterly crude oil returns. The pattern emerged shortly after the launch of commodity futures contracts and is consistent with a model in which the economic role of broker-dealers is to provide insurance to producers and end-users of commodities. I estimate cross-sectional prices of risk using an arbitrage-free asset pricing approach and show that broker-dealer risk appetite forecasts commodity returns through its association with market-wide risk premia. Additional predictions of the model for the market risk premium, market volatility, and speculative activity also receive support in the data. I am grateful to my advisers Jeremy Stein, John Campbell, Ken Rogo, and Andrei Shleifer, and to Tobias Adrian, Emmanuel Farhi, Robin Greenwood, Ravi Jagannathan, Hyun Song Shin and Erik Sta ord for their comments, support and advice. I also thank seminar participants at the Federal Reserve Bank of New York. All errors are my own.

2 1. Introduction The last three decades witnessed impressive growth of leveraged nancial institutions. This trend is displayed in Figure 1.1, which also shows the stark divergence of the growth of U.S. broker-dealer nancial assets from the growth of household nancial assets in the late 1970s. While the plot is intriguing in its own right, the economic signi cance of the growth pattern is further ampli ed by the procyclicality of broker-dealer nancial leverage: Adrian and Shin (2008a) demonstrate that broker-dealer risk appetite uctuates sharply with funding conditions. When liquidity is high, broker-dealer assets expand and leverage is adjusted upward. Conversely, when liquidity is tight, broker-dealer assets contract and leverage must be reduced. Combining the increased importance of the broker-dealer sector with the evidence of aggressive balance sheet management, it seems plausible to conjecture that uctuations in broker-dealer risk appetite are also re ected in asset prices. 10 Broker Dealer Total Financial Assets as a Fraction of Household Total Financial Assets (%, log scale) Figure 1.1: Broker-dealer total nancial assets as a share of household total nancial assets, Q1/1952-Q2/

3 This paper investigates the impact of broker-dealer risk appetite on commodity prices. The paper shows that broker-dealer risk appetite, as proxied by brokerdealer asset growth, has forecasting power for quarterly commodity returns across a cross-section of energy, metal, and agricultural commodities. The result holds robustly both in-sample and out-of-sample and is particularly strong for energy commodities: the single variable is able to forecast up to 34% of the variation in quarterly crude oil returns. The pattern emerged shortly after the launch of commodity futures contracts and is consistent with a model in which the economic role of broker-dealers is to provide insurance to producers and end-users of commodities. In equilibrium, expected commodity returns re ect broker-dealer risk appetite through their association with commodity risk premia. Figure 1.2 illustrates the emergence of return forecastability for crude oil by plotting the R 2 obtained from rolling regressions of crude oil returns on lagged broker-dealer asset growth. The power of the return forecasts jumps sharply approximately two years after the crude oil futures contract begins trading in the NYMEX and the CME in This change in the market structure (denoted by the red mark on the time axis) brought transparency into energy pricing and facilitated the matching of producers and end-users of commodities with speculators willing to supply insurance against uctuations in commodity prices. To show how the power of the uncovered predictive relationship relates to the size of the broker-dealer sector, Figure 1.2 also reproduces the graph of brokerdealer asset share from Figure 1.1. It may not be surprising that the predictive power of lagged broker-dealer risk appetite has increased over time along with the size of the broker-dealer sector but what is quite striking, the two variables have also grown at the same rate as indicated by the parallel trend lines. This nding lends support to the stability of the forecast relationship over time. The theoretical section of the paper builds on existing literature on commodity pricing to argue that the impact of broker-dealer risk appetite on expected 2

4 10 Broker Dealer Asset Share %, log scale (left) 1 R Squared, 18 Year Rolling Window Ending, log scale (right) Figure 1.2: Predictive power of lagged broker-dealer asset growth in rolling crude oil return regressions, Q1/1952-Q2/2008. Crude oil futures launched in March commodity returns stems from the importance of broker-dealers as insurance brokers (speculators) in commodity futures markets. Commodity futures are vital for producers and end-users of commodities (hedgers) because they are the principal means to unload spot commodity price risk. This risk is often termed "non-marketable" because the trading of many spot commodities involves signi - cant transaction costs or informational asymmetries, which discourage speculators from engaging in spot commodity transactions in the marketplace. These transaction costs and informational asymmetries are alleviated in the futures market where the hedgers demand for insurance is marketed through futures contracts that require no investment outlays. The insurance premia are determined by the risk appetite of speculators who o er to bear the price risk. To the extent that hedgers demand for insurance is independent of the uctuations in speculator risk appetite, changes in speculator risk appetite should in equilibrium be re ected in 3

5 expected commodity returns. 1 The link between broker-dealer risk appetite and expected commodity returns is rationalized in a simple pricing model where broker-dealers maximize expected return on equity subject to a value-at-risk constraint and have a role in providing insurance to producers and end-users of commodities. In equilibrium, expected commodity returns are determined by their loading on systematic marketable risk but also on systematic non-marketable risk whose price uctuates with brokerdealer risk appetite. The model predicts that broker-dealer risk appetite should be a signi cant determinant of expected returns for those commodities that load particularly heavily on systematic non-marketable (spot commodity) risk. The analysis shows that some energy commodities such as crude oil and its derivatives heating oil and unleaded gasoline have a large positive loading on systematic spot commodity risk, which makes them particularly sensitive to changes in broker-dealer risk appetite: high broker-dealer risk appetite forecasts low expected returns on energy commodities as speculators lower their required risk premia. The converse holds for some agricultural commodities such as wheat and cocoa, which have a signi - cant negative loading on systematic spot commodity risk. For these commodities, high broker-dealer risk appetite forecasts high expected returns as the risk premia required by speculators decrease. The model is also consistent with other quantitative and qualitative features of the data, including market risk premia, market volatility, and speculative activity in commodity futures markets. The paper concludes with cross-sectional asset pricing tests, which con rm the signi cance of broker-dealer asset growth for the pricing of systematic spot commodity risk. The results also suggest that the innovations to broker-dealer risk appetite constitute a signi cant source of systematic risk for the cross-section 1 Grossman and Miller (1988) emphasize that hedgers also have a strong preference for immediacy in hedging transactions. This further increases their vulnerability to shifts in speculator risk appetite. 4

6 of commodity returns. Overall, the cross-sectional evidence lends strong support to the view that the uncovered forecastability of commodity returns is a re ection of systematic changes in risk premia Related Literature The risk appetite channel analyzed in this paper originates in Adrian and Shin (2008a,b,c) who demonstrate that the active management of nancial intermediary balance sheets generates procyclical leverage, which has consequences for investor risk appetite. The authors exhibit evidence that the adjustment of balance sheets forecasts changes in aggregate market volatility, particularly the price of risk of volatility, at weekly horizons. The impact of procyclical leverage on asset prices is further explored in Adrian, Etula and Shin (2008) who show that the growth of U.S. nancial intermediary balance sheets has systematic implications for the cross-section of currency returns. The view that balance sheet constraints in uence risk premia is also supported by the nancial market turmoil, which shows how a sudden drying up of nancial intermediary liquidity may have signi cant systematic consequences. The literature on time-varying expected commodity returns can be divided roughly into two groups of theories. The rst group uses the CAPM to argue that the expected return on commodity holdings re ects their value as a hedge against market uctuations. Early studies include Black (1976) and Breeden (1980) who explain the variation in futures prices by systematic risk that stems from changes in economic state variables. Tests of these models nd scant evidence in the data, as show by Jagannathan (1985) and a number of other studies. More recently, Bessembinder and Chan (1992) nd that the same variables that forecast market returns e.g. dividend yield, interest rate, and credit spread also forecast commodity returns. This suggests that time-varying risk premia in commodities could be driven by macro-economic forces that determine asset allocation. Gorton 5

7 and Rouwenhorst (2006) attribute a lesser role to the hedging value of commodities and argue that commodity futures as an asset class provide a return pro le that is comparable to that of equities. The second group of theories argues that the expected return of holding commodities is driven largely by commodity-speci c factors. Most relevant for the present paper are the studies that nd additional forecastability of commodity futures risk premia and returns using the net positions of hedgers in the futures market, which is known as hedging pressure. The idea of hedging pressure dates back to Keynes (1930) and Hicks (1939) whose theory of normal backwardation argues that producers short futures to hedge their initially long positions in the underlying spot. Models that allow both hedging pressure and systematic risk to a ect futures prices include Stoll (1979) and Hirschleifer (1988, 1989). Empirical evidence for the combined role of commodity-speci c hedging pressure and systematic market risk include Carter, Rausser and Schmidt (1992), Bessembinder (1992), and de Roon, Nijman and Veld (2000). The current paper contributes to the rst group of theories by demonstrating that for a set of commodities a signi cant portion of the time-variation in expected returns can be attributed to time-variation in U.S. broker-dealer risk appetite. The paper s argument for why broker-dealer risk appetite matters for expected commodity returns builds on the second group of theories: broker-dealers have an important role in providing insurance to producers and end-users of commodities who wish to hedge their positions in spot commodities. This channel is also supported by the evidence of Erb and Harvey (2006) who show that such insurance provision earns positive expected excess returns. In sum, the current paper argues that expected commodity returns re ect changes in broker-dealer risk appetite through their systematic association with insurance risk premia. The theoretical framework builds on Danielsson, Shin and Zigrand (2008) where investor risk appetite shifts endogenously with balance sheet constraints 6

8 that uctuate with market outcomes, generating endogenous risk. The balance sheet constraints are imposed by a contracting setting of Adrian and Shin (2008c), which yields a value-at-risk rule. The model has similarities with the large behavioral nance literature on noise trader risk (e.g. DeLong, Shleifer, Summers and Waldmann, 1990; Barberis, Shleifer and Vishny, 1998; Hong and Stein, 1999), limited arbitrage (e.g. Shleifer and Vishny, 1997), and market making (e.g. Grossman and Miller, 1988; Kyle, 1985). However, the distinguishing feature of the present framework is its ability to generate stochastic volatility even though the underlying fundamental risks remain constant. It is also free of restrictive assumptions on the behavior of noise traders. The outline of the paper is as follows. To x ideas, Section 2 develops a simple framework, which introduces broker-dealer balance sheet constraints in an equilibrium pricing model for commodities. The model shows that if brokerdealers play an important role in providing insurance to producers and end-users of physical commodities, then uctuations in broker-dealer risk appetite should be re ected in expected commodity returns through their association with risk premia. Section 3 con rms the predictions of the model in the data by showing that broker-dealer risk appetite forecasts returns on commodities that have the heaviest loadings on systematic spot commodity risk. Section 4 tests additional predictions of the model and incorporates evidence from the commodity futures market. Section 5 implements a cross-sectional asset pricing model with timevarying prices of risk and nds that balance sheet constraints are signi cant to the pricing of the cross-section of commodity returns. Section 6 concludes. 7

9 2. Theoretical Framework As discussed above, there is an extensive literature 2 that relates futures risk premia to two components: systematic marketable risk and commodity-speci c hedging pressure. The latter arises from risks that agents cannot or do not want to trade because of market frictions such as transaction costs or informational asymmetries. Following this literature, consider an economy with marketable assets A, futures F, and non-marketable securities N. Denote by r i t+1 the excess return on security i. The non-marketable securities may serve as the underlying value of the futures contracts and can also coincide with some of the assets. While the returns on non-marketable securities r N t+1 do not enter the market portfolio, they do in uence portfolio choice. Suppose there are two types of agents in the economy: risk-neutral brokerdealers and risk averse investors. The portfolio of agent j consists of positions in assets! j A;t, futures!j F;t, and non-marketable securities qj t : r j t+1 =! j0 A ra t+1 +! j0 F rf t+1 + q j0 r F t+1: All positions are expressed as a fraction of the agent s nancial wealth Risk-Neutral Broker-Dealers Security brokers and dealers (bd) are leveraged nancial institutions that nance long positions in risky securities (dollar value S 1 ) with short positions in other risky securities (dollar value S 2 ). Their cash holdings (c) earn the safe rate of return. A stylized broker-dealer balance sheet can be depicted as: Assets S 1 c Liabilities e S 2 2 For example, Stoll (1979), Hirshleifer (1988, 1989), Carter et al. (1983), Bessembinder (1992), and de Roon, Nijman and Veld (2000). 8

10 where e is the market value of equity. Following Danielsson, Shin and Zigrand (2008), suppose broker-dealers maximize expected return on equity subject to a value-at-risk constraint: max E t rt+1 bd! A;t ;! F;t s:t: V ar t e t : That is, pro t-maximizing broker-dealers leverage up to the maximum level permitted by their balance sheet constraints. Thus, under pro t maximization, the value-at-risk q constraint binds with equality. If V ar is some multiple of portfolio volatility V ar t rt+1 bd, the constraint becomes V art rt+1 bd = e t 2. Suppose for simplicity that broker-dealers do not have non-marketable securities. It follows that the return on broker-dealer equity is given by: r bd t+1 =! bd0 A;tr A t+1 +! bd0 F;tr F t+1: The Lagrangian is: L t = E t rt+1 bd t V ar t rt+1 bd e 2 : (2.1) De ne r t+1 = r A t+1; r F t+1 0,! bd t =! bd A;t ;!bd F;t 0, and write the FOC:! bd t = 1 2 t [V ar t (r t+1 )] 1 E t (r t+1 ) ; (2.2) where! bd t is the broker-dealer s optimal portfolio choice. Note that equation (2:2) is identical to the standard mean-variance choice but with the risk-aversion parameter replaced by t, the Lagrange multiplier associated with the balance sheet constraint. In other words, broker-dealers are risk-neutral but behave as if they were risk-averse with the risk aversion uctuating with market conditions. As the balance sheet constraint binds harder, the shadow price t increases, and leverage must be reduced. The inverse of the Lagrange multiplier, 1 t, measures broker-dealer risk appetite. 3 3 The Lagrange multiplied can be solved for from the balance sheet constraint and is given 9

11 2.2. Risk-Averse Investors Suppose the rest of the investors are risk-averse (ra). They trade o mean against variance in the portfolio return, which depends on the returns on assets, futures, and non-marketable securities: rt+1 ra =! ra0 A;trt+1 A +! ra0 F;trt+1 F + qt ra0 r N t+1: Agent ra chooses positions in the marketable securities to solve: which yields the FOC:! ra t = 1 2 [V ar t (r t+1 )] max E t! ra t rt+1 ra V ar t 1 E t (r t+1 ) [V ar t (r t+1 )] r ra t+1 ; 1 Cov t r t+1 ; r N t+1 q ra t : (2.3) Note that the optimal porfolio choices of broker-dealers and risk-averse investors are linked by:! bd t = t! ra t + [V ar t (r t+1 )] 1 Cov t r t+1 ; r N t+1 q ra t : (2.4) 2.3. Market Portfolio Denote by s t the share of broker-dealer assets in the economy: s t = W ra t W bd t + W bd t Since futures contracts are in zero net supply, market clearing implies:!! M M t = A;t (1 st )! ra A;t = + s t! bd A;t : (2.5) 0 0 : by: t = 2e t q E t (r t+1 ) 0 [V ar t (r t+1 )] 1 E t (r t+1 ): 10

12 If the market portfolio is e cient in the sense that it satis es the FOCs (2:2) and (2:3) for t,, q t, and s t, one obtains: E t (r t+1 ) = M t Covt r t+1 ; rt+1 M + Covt r t+1 ; rt+1 N q M t ; (2.6) where 1 M t is the aggregate risk appetite and = 1 s t + s t t (2.7) q M t = (1 s t ) q ra t (2.8) is the vector of aggregate non-marketable positions on the economy. Note that the aggregates in (2:7) and (2:8) are linear combinations of the two investor groups respective variables Equilibrium Returns Let i t = Covt(ri t+1 ;rm t+1) V ar t(r M t+1) denote security i s beta with the portfolio of marketable assets and rewrite the expression (2:6) for equilibrium returns as: E t (r t+1 ) = t E t rt+1 M + Covt r t+1 ; rt+1 N q M t t Cov t rt+1; M rt+1 N q M t M t = t E t rt+1 M + Covt r t+1 ; rt+1 NM t Cov t rt+1; M rt+1 NM M t : (2.9) The second line de nes: r NM t+1 r N t+1q M t ; which is interpreted as the excess return on the aggregate production-weighted portfolio of non-marketable securities. If non-marketable securities consist primarly of physical commodities, then r NM t+1 is the excess return on the world productionweighted portfolio of spot commodities. 11

13 Further, denote the coe cient of M t t Cov t r t+1 ; rt+1 NM in (2:9) by: t Cov t r M t+1; r NM t+1 ; (2.10) which contains the loadings of individual assets on aggregate non-marketable risk in excess of their loadings on aggregate marketable risk. It follows that (2:9) can be expressed concisely as: E t (r t+1 ) {z } Security Risk Premium = t E t rt+1 M {z } Price of Marketable Risk + t M t {z} Price of Non-Marketable Risk : (2.11) The rst term in (2:11) captures the non-diversi able risk that stems from uctuations in the value of aggregate marketable securities. The price of marketable risk is E t r M t+1. The second term captures the non-diversi able risk that stems from uctuations in the value of aggregate non-marketable securities, which is not already captured by systematic marketable risk. The price of non-marketable risk is M t and it varies over time with the willingness of broker-dealers to provide insurance against non-marketable risks i.e. it varies with broker-dealers risk appetite as given by (2:7). Note that (2:11) prices both futures and assets. 3. Empirical Implementation The model outlined in Section 2 implies that risk premia for all futures contracts and spot commodities are determined by two systematic risk components: one that stems from aggregate marketable risk and another that stems from aggregate non-marketable risk. Replacing expectations by realizations in (2:11), assuming constant conditional variances and covariances, and adding a constant on the right hand side yields: r i t+1 = i + i r M t+1 + i M t + i t+1; i 2 fa; F g ; (3.1) 12

14 with E t+1 i = 0 and E i t+1 rt+1 M = E i t+1 M t = 0 for all i. i 1 Equation (2:7) tells one that the risk premium M t is proportional to hs t 1 t and has the following three properties: First, the risk premium increases as the broker-dealer balance sheet constraints tighten, which increases t and forces a decrease in leverage. Second, if broker-dealer leverage is procyclical as suggested by the above theoretical model and the empirical evidence of Adrian and Shin (2008a), then broker-dealer assets uctuate in near lock-step with their leverage, which implies that broker-dealer asset growth is a good proxy for broker-dealer risk 1 appetite,. The empirical tests that follow normalize broker-dealer asset growth t by household asset growth to obtain a proxy for. This captures the idea t 1 that it is the deviations of broker-dealer implied risk appetite from household risk tolerance that drive time-varying risk premia. Third, uctuations in broker-dealer risk appetite matter economically only if the share s t of broker-dealer assets in the economy is high enough. Based on the above properties of M t, one may conclude that a good proxy might be the negative of broker-dealer asset growth in excess of household asset growth. The model also suggests that one may bene t from interacting this proxy with the share of broker-dealer assets, s t, to account for any time variation in the power of the forecasting relationship (recall Fig. 1.2). The interaction is likely to be of particular importance in longer samples Data The empirical exercises that follow investigate the impact of lagged broker-dealer asset growth on the excess returns of spot commodities and commodity futures. The data on aggregate balance sheets is obtained from the Federal Reserve, which publishes the gures quarterly as part of the Flow of Funds Accounts. The analysis includes 14 individual commodities and two investable commodity indexes. The individual commodities are selected based on their respective world production 13

15 quantities and liquidity of futures contracts. The price data on spot commodities, commodity futures and commodity indexes are obtained from Compustat. The excess returns are generated by subtracting the 3-Month Treasury Bill rate from the quarterly gross returns. The data on equity returns, bond returns, and technical indicators used as controls in the regressions are provided by Global Financial Data. The data on the S&P 500 implied volatility index (VIX) and the credit default swap index (CDX) are from Bloomberg. The paper also employs quantity data on the positions of market participants in futures exchanges. These variables are obtained from the Commitment of Traders reports, which are published weekly by the Commodity Futures Trading Commission. The CFTC requires that large traders in futures exchanges report whether they take a position for hedging ( commercial ) or for speculative ( noncommercial ) purposes. To register as a hedger, one must hold a cash position in the underlying. Thus, the hedgers in commodity futures markets consist primarily of producers and end-users of physical commodities: producers (such as farmers) have long positions in the underlying commodity and wish to short the futures contract in order to hedge against spot price uctuations; conversely, end-users (such as our mills) have a future need for the physical commodity and want to long the futures contract in order to lock in the purchase price today. Speculators consist of broker-dealers, hedge funds, and other market participants who hold the futures for other purposes. See Bessembinder (1992) for further discussion of the distinction between commercial and non-commercial traders. The baseline regressions cover the time period Q3/1990-Q4/2008, which was selected based on the availability of data. Year 2008 is excluded because the key assumption of the model fails to hold in most quarters of the year: the use of broker-dealer asset growth as a proxy for broker-dealer risk appetite 1 relies on t the nding of Adrian and Shin (2008a) that broker-dealer leverage is procyclical; 14

16 that is, increases in broker-dealer assets are matched by increases in leverage to keep V ar=equity constant. As the nancial crisis expanded in 2008, a signi cant part of broker-dealer asset growth was nanced by equity 4. For instance, the rst quarter of 2008 witnessed substantial growth in broker-dealer assets while leverage decreased signi cantly, suggesting that broker-dealer asset growth was not a good proxy for broker-dealer risk appetite. A decrease in risk appetite in Q1/2008 would correctly predict the run-up in oil prices in Q2/2008, which the asset growth proxy fails to capture. Unfortunately, it is hard to nd reliable aggregate data on broker-dealer leverage. This is a topic for future work In-Sample Regressions The panels of Table 1 implement the baseline OLS speci cation of equation (3:1) for the futures and spot returns of 14 individual energy, metal, and agricultural commodities. Table 1A regresses the quarterly futures excess returns on the S&P 500 excess return and lagged broker-dealer asset growth in excess of household asset growth (henceforth, broker-dealer asset growth). Since the futures contracts are pure bets in the sense that they require no investment outlays, their excess returns are given by the percentage price change, p t+1 =p t 1. The regressions consider the returns on the front-month contracts, which are usually the most liquid ones. The results show that broker-dealer asset growth is a signi cant predictor of expected returns for crude oil, its derivatives heating oil and unleaded gasoline as well as for silver, copper, wheat and cocoa. Note, however, that the sign of the coe cient for most agricultural commodities is positive rather than negative this feature is consistent with the predictions of the model and will be discussed below. The economic power of the regressions is the strongest for the three energy commodities crude oil, heating oil and unleaded gasoline, for which 4 As the crisis escalated, it is possible that the usual stigma associated with equity decreased, making it a more desirable form of nancing for broker-dealers. Thus, the nancing decisions in 2008 nd some support in the pecking order theory of Myers and Majluf (1984). 15

17 the adjusted R 2 is over 20%. Table 1B conducts the same regressions for excess spot returns. Consistent with the predictions of the model, the results are nearly identical. An additional set of regressions for the futures basis (price of future minus price of spot) as the dependent variable con rms that broker-dealer risk appetite has no predictive power for the front-month slope of the futures curve at this frequency. Finally, Table 1C runs the baseline regression for the excess returns on the S&P Goldman Sachs Commodity Index (spot and futures) and the Dow Jones Commodity Index (futures), which are readily accessible to investors. The results show that broker-dealer asset growth is a highly signi cant predictor of excess returns on all indexes. The table also includes the regression for the Dow Jones Corporate Bond index to show that broker-dealer asset growth has no predictive power for excess bond returns. While the regressions of Table 1 include the contemporaneous market excess return as an additional predictor variable, one should note that this control has no material impact on the signi cance of lagged broker-dealer asset growth or the power of the regressions. It is included merely to adhere to the theoretical speci cation in equation (3:1). The qualitative results also remain una ected if broker-dealer asset growth is interacted with the share of broker-dealer assets s t Estimated vs. Model-Predicted Loadings To see how the coe cient estimates of Tables 1A-1C compare with the predictions of the pricing model (2:11), compute the theoretical loadings on M t of individual commodity futures, spot returns, and indexes using: i = Cov rt+1; i rt+1 NM i Cov rt+1; M rt+1 NM ; (3.2) which is just a stationary version of (2:10). Recall that the weights of the nonmarketable portfolio are given by the vector of aggregate non-marketable positions q M t in the economy. Thus, it seems natural to proxy the excess return r NM t+1 on 16

18 y = 1.02x R 2 = 73.3% Estimated Theoretical Figure 3.1: Commodity futures and futures indexes: Estimated vs. modelpredicted coe cients of broker-dealer asset growth for energy (squares), metal (circles) and agricultural (triangles) commodities, plus three indexes (diamonds). the non-marketable portfolio by the excess return on the GSCI Spot index, which weights commodities by their respective world production quantities. Since M t is inversely proportional to broker-dealer asset growth, one must compare the estimated coe cients of broker-dealer asset growth from Tables 1A- 1C with i s computed by (3:2). Figure 3.1 displays the results for the futures contracts and Figure 3.2 draws the same comparison for the spot commodities. The scatter plots lend substantial support to the model: for both futures and spot commodities, the empirical coe cient estimates line up cleanly with the modelpredicted coe cients. For futures, the slope of the relationship is remarkable 1.02 and for the spot commodities the slope is also nearly unity at The R 2 s of both regressions are well above 70%. The only outlier is natural gas whose estimated coe cient is somewhat less negative than the model-predicted value (see the bottom-left corner of the plots). The above results for the cross-section of commodities shed light to under- 17

19 Estimated y = 0.81x R 2 = 78.1% Theoretical Figure 3.2: Spot commodities and indexes: Estimated vs. model-predicted coe cients of broker-dealer asset growth for energy (squares), metal (circles) and agricultural (triangles) commodities, plus three indexes (diamonds). standing why one observes such vast di erences in the signi cance and the forecast power of broker-dealer asset growth across commodities. They con rm the prediction of the model that uctuations in broker-dealer risk appetite should have the greatest impact on the risk premia of those commodities that covary the most with the aggregate non-marketable portfolio; that is, on the commodities that load heavily on the price of systematic non-marketable risk, which uctuates strongly with broker-dealer risk appetite In-Sample Robustness Checks The remainder of the section will investigate the robustness of the forecasting relationships uncovered in the panels of Table 1. In the interest of space, the analysis will be limited to crude oil and the GSCI index. The panels of Table 2 display the quarterly in-sample regressions of crude oil excess return (panel A) and GSCI excess return (panel B) on lagged broker-dealer 18

20 asset growth and a set of controls. Column (i) shows that the lagged growth of broker-dealer nancial assets is an important predictor of commodity returns on both statistical and economic grounds: the variable is signicant at 1% level and can alone forecasts nearly 34% of the in-sample variation in the excess crude oil returns and 13% of the GSCI futures returns over the next quarter. Column (ii) demonstrates that the results are not a ected by the inclusion of an autoregressive term. Columns (iii)-(viii) add a number of control variables from the literature, which include lags of the VIX volatility index, interest rate, yield spread, dividend yield, in ation, and hedging pressure. 5 Notably, none of the controls are signi cant in the regressions with broker-dealer asset growth at this frequency. 6 While part of the observed insigni cance may be due to collinearity of the controls, the stability of adjusted R 2 across the di erent speci cations suggests that none of the controls contribute signi cantly to the power of the model. The coe cient of brokerdealer asset growth, on the other hand, remains signi cant at 1% level across all speci cations. The magnitude of the broker-dealer coe cient is also preserved for both crude oil and GSCI. One can furthermore test the robustness of the above predictive relationships at di erent forecast horizons. Regressions with Newey-West standard errors for returns 2 8 quarters ahead show that both the statistical signi cance as well as the economic magnitude of the relationships remain stable over longer horizons. 7 These results lend additional support to the strength and robustness of the dynamic connection between broker-dealer asset growth and commodity returns. 5 Hedging pressure measures commercial hedgers net exposure to a particular futures market. It is de ned as the net short open interest of hedgers divided by the total open interest of hedgers. 6 If broker-dealer asset growth is excluded from column (viii) of Table 1, lagged VIX and lagged dividend yield become signi cant at 10% level in Panel A; only lagged VIX becomes signi cant in Panel B. Note that the results are also robust to the inclusion of inventory gures or any additional proxies for the phase of the business cycle. 7 These robustness checks can be obtained from the author. 19

21 3.5. Out-of-Sample Regressions As is well known, the high in-sample forecasting power of a regressor does not guarantee robust out-of sample performance, which is more sensitive to misspeci cation problems. To show the extent to which the above in-sample results survive this tougher test, the following investigates the forecastability of excess commodity returns out-of-sample. Again, the analysis will be limited to crude oil and the GSCI index. The results are produced using recursive regressions with the out-of-sample portion running from the second quarter of 1995 until the end of Table 3 compares the predictive power of the proposed broker-dealer model to three benchmarks (restricted models) that are standard in the literature of out-of-sample forecasting: (1) random walk, (2) random walk with drift, and (3) rst-order autoregression. These benchmarks are nested in the unrestricted speci cations, which allows one to evaluate their performance using the Clark and West (2006) adjusted di erence in mean squared errors: MSE-adj: = MSE r (MSE u adj:). The Clark-West test accounts for the small-sample forecast bias (adj:), which works in favor of the simpler restricted models and is present in the (unadjusted) Diebold-Mariano/West (DMW) tests. As Rogo and Stavrakeva (2008) show, a signi cant Clark-West adjusted statistic implies that there exists an optimal combination between the unrestricted model and the restricted model, which will produce a combined forecast that outperforms the restricted model in terms of mean squared forecast error; i.e. the forecast will have a DMW statistic that is signi cantly greater than zero. The results in Table 3 indicate that the models with broker-dealer asset growth (x t ) outperform all three benchmarks at 1% signi cance level for Crude Oil (panel A) and at 5% signi cance level for S&P GSCI (panel B). The p-values are based on bootstrapped standard errors with 1000 iterations. 20

22 4. Additional Predictions In addition to the relationships investigated above, the theoretical framework of Section 2 also yields a number of other predictions. extent to which these additional predictions hold in the data Market Risk Premia This section explores the Consider rst the association of broker-dealer risk appetite with other measures of market risk premia. Rearranging the de nition of market risk appetite (2:7), one obtains: M t = 1 + s t 1 ; (4.1) t which implies that the aggregate risk appetite increases in broker-dealer risk appetite. It seems natural to test if this prediction holds for a common measure of market risk appetite such as the VIX risk premium, which is de ned as the option-implied S&P 500 volatility over the realized S&P 500 volatility. The prediction is also tested for the Investment Grade CDX index even though the data is available only since Q4/2003. The results are displayed in Table 4. Column (i) demonstrates that broker-dealer asset growth is associated with low VIX risk premia and the relationship is signi cant at 1% level; that is, times of high market risk appetite tend to coincide with high broker-dealer risk appetite. Column (ii) shows that both the statistical signi cance and economic magnitude of the relationship increase if one interacts broker-dealer asset growth with the share of broker-dealer assets, as predicted by (4:1). In the latter speci cation, the t-statistic increases to 4:7 and the single variable explains over 24% of the variation in the VIX risk premium, based on adjusted R 2. Columns (iii) and (iv) run the same regressions for changes in the VIX risk premium and nd a similar pattern: Broker-dealer asset growth is again highly signi cant in both speci cations and the single variable is capable of explaining as much as 25:5% of 21

23 the variation in quarterly changes in the VIX risk premium. Finally, column (v) considers the e ect of broker-dealer asset growth on the CDX. While the sample size is very small, bootstrapped standard errors suggest that broker-dealer risk appetite is negatively associated with the CDX index and the relationship is signi cant at 5% level. Thus, high broker-dealer risk appetite seems to coincide with periods of low risk premia also in the market for corporate default risk. Note the consistence of the results with Adrian and Shin (2008a) who demonstrate that high growth of primary-dealer repurchase agreements forecasts low VIX risk premia at weekly horizons Market Volatility Consider next the e ect of broker-dealer risk appetite on market volatility. Using equation (2:5) and the FOCs, one obtains: V ar t r M t+1 2 = V art r M; t+1 +2s t 1 Cov t r M;0 t+1 ; r M; t+1 +s 2 t 1 V ar t t t (4.2) where r M;0 t+1 denotes the market return in a world without broker-dealers and nonmarketable assets, and r M; t+1 is the market return in a world where t = for all t. Mathematically: r M;0 t+1 ; r M;0 t+1 = r M; t+1 = r M;0 t [V ar (r t+1)] [V ar (rt+1 )] 0 1 E t (r t+1 ) r t+1; (4.3) 1 Cov r t+1 ; rt+1 NM 0 rt+1 : (4.4) That is, high volatility of broker-dealer risk appetite should forecast high market variance. This prediction is investigated in Table 5. Column (i) implements a contemporaneous version of (4:2) by running the realized S&P 500 variance on broker-dealer asset growth interacted with s t and the 22

24 square of this variable The squared regressor is signi cant at 1% level, suggesting that high volatility of broker-dealer risk appetite is indeed associated with high market volatility. The regressors explain 21:7% of the variation in market variance on an adjusted R 2 basis. Running the regression with lagged right-hand-side variables yields no signi cance at this horizon. Columns (ii) and (iii) assess the e ect of broker-dealer asset growth on changes in S&P 500 volatility. The results show that broker-dealer asset growth is positively associated with changes in market volatility; that is, market volatility increases at times of high broker-dealer risk appetite. The regressor is signi cant at 1% level and explains over 10% of the variation in volatility growth. Both the statistical signi cance of the regressor and the economic power of the speci cation increase further when broker-dealer asset growth is interacted with their asset share Speculative Demand in the Futures Market Finally, consider the impact of broker-dealer risk appetite on speculative activity in commodity futures. If changes in broker-dealer risk appetite drive expected commodity returns via the proposed mechanism, one should expect to see changes in speculators open interest as broker-dealer risk appetite uctuates. In particular, an increase (decrease) in broker-dealer risk appetite that lowers insurance premia should be associated with an increase (decrease) in speculators share of futures demand. In other words, when broker-dealer risk appetite increases, speculators take more aggressive futures positions, which should be re ected in higher speculative open interest. Column (i) of Table 6 demonstrates this e ect for crude oil: broker-dealer asset growth that bids up current crude oil prices (compresses risk premia) is associated with an increase in the speculator share of open interest. The result is signi cant at 1% level. 23

25 One can also demonstrate the direct e ect on contemporaneous crude oil returns. That is, an increase in broker-dealer risk appetite that increases the share of speculative demand in the futures market should be associated with a contemporaneous increase in crude oil prices (compression of risk premia). This result is shown in column (ii). 8 Similar results also obtain for other commodities with strong return predictability. But note that commodities that have a negative loading on lagged broker-dealer risk appetite in Table 1 also have a di erent sign on the interaction terms of Table 6. This lends additional support to the prediction of the model that broker-dealer risk appetite determines expected commodity returns through its association with risk premia, where that risk premium may be positive or negative depending on the covariance properties of the individual commodity (recall Figs ). 5. Cross-Sectional Prices of Risk In order to investigate the signi cance of broker-dealer risk appetite for the pricing of the cross-section of commodity returns, this section constructs and implements a cross-sectional asset pricing model with time-varying prices of risk. 8 Note the similarity of these results to Campbell, Grossman and Wang (1993) where riskaverse market makers accommodate selling pressure from liquidity traders. Their model predicts that an asset price decline on a high-volume day is more likely to be associated with an increase in the expected asset return than an asset price decline on a low-volume day. In the present framework, liquidity traders (hedgers) have to accommodate changes in broker-dealer (speculator) risk appetite by accepting a higher/lower futures price. A futures price increase is more likely to be associate with an increase in broker-dealer risk appetite when speculative activity is increasing than when speculative activity is decreasing. 24

26 5.1. Cross-Sectional Asset Pricing Approach Let r i t+1 be the excess return on a position in commodity i. Denoting the pricing kernel by M t+1 =M t, the expected excess return is: Mt+1 E t rt+1 i = 0: M t De ne the commodity risk premium, M t+1 =M t t = Cov t E t (M t+1 =M t ) ; ri t+1 ; (5.1) and express the excess return in terms of two components: r i t+1 {z} Excess Return = t {z} Commodity Risk Premium + u i t+1 {z} Commodity Risk ; (5.2) where E t u i t+1 = 0. In order to estimate the prices of risk t, assume the pricing kernel is exponentially a ne in a set of state variables X t : M t+1 = exp ln (r t ) M t where t t = X t ; t t 0 tv t+1 ; X t+1 = + X t + t v t+1 ; vec ( t 0 t) = S 0 + S 1 X t ; and v t+1 N (0; I k ). Using Stein s lemma for the commodity risk premium (5:1) and de ning i0 t = Cov t rt+1; i X t+1 1 t, the pricing equation (5:2) becomes: r i t+1 = i0 t ( X t ) + u i t+1: 25

27 Following Adrian and Moench (2008), one can further decompose the commodityspeci c risk into a systematic and idiosyncratic component to obtain: r i t+1 {z} Excess Return = i0 t ( X t ) {z } Commodity Risk Premia + i0 t v t+1 {z } Systematic Commodity Risk + i t+1 {z} Idiosyncratic Commodity Risk ; (5.3) where e i t+1 N (0; 1) for all i Estimating Prices of Risk The cross-sectional model in (5:3) is estimated by way of three-stage OLS regressions applied to the cross-section of 14 commodities discussed above. simplicity, it is assumed that the commodity-speci c betas i are constant over time. The steps of the estimation procedure are outlined in Adrian and Moench (2008). Following the reduced-form factor model (2:11) from Section 2, let the vector of state variables be given by: 0 1 S&P 500 Excess Return GSCI Spot Excess Return X t = B [B-D Share] [B-D Asset Growth] PC 1 A ; PC 2 where the S&P 500 is a proxy for the returns on marketable assets (rt M ), the GSCI Spot is a proxy for the returns on non-marketable securities (rt NM ), and the negative of broker-dealer asset growth is a proxy for the tightness of broker-dealer balance sheet constraint ( M t t ). PC 1 and PC 2 are the rst two principal components extracted from the cross-section of commodity prices: PC 1 is interpreted as an equally-weighted commodity price index. PC 2 captures systematic variation between di erent classes of commodities. Before proceeding to the results, note what to expect based on Section 2 s theoretical formulation. The main prediction of (2:11) concerns the tightness of 26 For

28 broker-dealer balance sheet constraint M t, which in the time-series regressions of Section 3 was proxied by the negative of broker-dealer asset growth. Since the dynamics of prices of risk t are linked to the state variables X t, the cross-sectional model gives one an opportunity to investigate the prediction of the model that the price of non-marketable risk GSCI t is linked to broker-dealer asset growth. In particular, the model predicts that GSCI t has a signi cant positive load on lagged [B-D Share][B-D Asset Growth]. Note also that the model in its current static form remains silent about whether the innovations to [B-D Share] [B-D Asset Growth], i.e. balance sheet risk, should be priced. For an intertemporal asset pricing model with broker-dealer balance sheet constraints, see Adrian, Etula and Shin (2009). The estimates for the cross-sectional prices of risk are displayed in Table 7. Columns (i)-(v) give the loadings of the four prices of risk k t on a constant 0 and on the lags of the state variables l 1. The associated t-statistics are based on a bootstrap with 1000 iterations. There are two things to note: First, the price of non-marketable risk (on the second row) has a signi cant positive loading on the tightness of broker-dealer balance sheet constraints, [B-D Share] [B- D Asset Growth]. This con rms the prediction of the model that the price of non-marketable risk is inversely linked to broker-dealer risk appetite. Second, the price of balance sheet risk (on the third row) has a signi cant negative loading on the aggregate market return, suggesting that the price of balance sheet risk is high in economic downturns. The signi cance of the prices of risk of each state variable is tested in Column (v). The p-values in brackets show that all risk premia except for the price of marketable risk are signi cant at 1% level. This is consistent with the ndings of numerous previous studies, which suggest that systematic market risk is not signi cant for the pricing of commodity returns. The prices of risk are plotted in Figures 5.1 and 5.2 for the two signi cant risk 27

29 15 Price of Non Marketable Risk Figure 5.1: Price of GSCI spot commodity risk (Q3/1990-Q4/2007) Price of Balance Sheet Risk Figure 5.2: Price of broker-dealer balance sheet risk (Q3/1990-Q4/2007) 28

30 factors of interest, non-marketable risk and balance sheet risk. Both series are highly volatile, which re ects the same time-variation in commodity risk premia that was found to generate forecastability of commodity returns in Section 2. Note the increase in the price of non-marketable risk at the end of 2007 as a result of decreasing broker-dealer risk appetite. The sharp increase in the price of balance sheet risk over the same period stemmed from a simultaneous decline in equity prices and a run-up in non-energy commodity prices. In order to assess the signi cance of individual commodities loadings on the risk premia, column (i) of Table 8 tests the joint signi cance of betas for each commodity. The bootstrapped p-values in brackets indicate that all commodities except for silver have statistically signi cant loadings on the innovations of state variables. Column (ii) conducts similar tests for the commodity risk premia, which correspond to the currency-speci c betas multiplied by the prices of risk. The risk premium is signi cant at the 5% level for 7 out of 14 commodities, which apart from corn and soybeans coincide with the forecastable commodities in Tables 1A and 1B. The di erences stem from the cross-sectional restrictions imposed by the model. Finally, column (iii) investigates the quality of the pricing model by testing the predictability of forecast residuals by lagged state variables. The tests of excess forecastability are signi cant only for unleaded gasoline and cocoa, which suggests that the model does a good job in pricing the rest of the cross-section. That is, the observed predictability of commodity returns is largely explained by market-wide risks, which cannot be diversi ed away in the cross-section of commodities. This result is regarded as further con rmation of the paper s rationalization of the channel through which balance sheet constraints operate. As suggested in the theoretical model, the balance sheet constraint and the associated Lagrange multiplier t have the e ect of varying the apparent risk preferences of market participants. Times of ample liquidity correspond to times when balance 29

Broker-Dealer Risk Appetite and Commodity Returns

Broker-Dealer Risk Appetite and Commodity Returns Broker-Dealer Risk Appetite and Commodity Returns Erkko Etula Federal Reserve Bank of New York erkko.etula@ny.frb.org First Draft: November 2008 This Draft: November 2009 Abstract This paper shows that

More information

CAPM, Arbitrage, and Linear Factor Models

CAPM, Arbitrage, and Linear Factor Models CAPM, Arbitrage, and Linear Factor Models CAPM, Arbitrage, Linear Factor Models 1/ 41 Introduction We now assume all investors actually choose mean-variance e cient portfolios. By equating these investors

More information

Broker-Dealer Leverage and the Cross-Section of Stock Returns 1

Broker-Dealer Leverage and the Cross-Section of Stock Returns 1 Broker-Dealer Leverage and the Cross-Section of Stock Returns 1 Tobias Adrian, Erkko Etula and Tyler Muir Federal Reserve Bank of New York and Northwestern University Bank of England, January -5, 11 1

More information

Financial Intermediaries and the Cross-Section of Asset Returns

Financial Intermediaries and the Cross-Section of Asset Returns Financial Intermediaries and the Cross-Section of Asset Returns Tobias Adrian - Federal Reserve Bank of New York 1 Erkko Etula - Goldman Sachs Tyler Muir - Kellogg School of Management May, 2012 1 The

More information

Default Risk, Hedging Demand and Commodity Prices

Default Risk, Hedging Demand and Commodity Prices Default Risk, Hedging Demand and Commodity Prices Viral V. Acharya, Lars Lochstoer and Tarun Ramadorai November 15, 2007 Abstract Recent literature has argued that commodity producers manage their inventories

More information

Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Reports

Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Reports Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Reports Financial Intermediaries and the Cross-Section of Asset Returns Tobias Adrian Erkko Etula Tyler Muir Staff Report no. 464 July 2010 Revised April 2011 This

More information

Chap 3 CAPM, Arbitrage, and Linear Factor Models

Chap 3 CAPM, Arbitrage, and Linear Factor Models Chap 3 CAPM, Arbitrage, and Linear Factor Models 1 Asset Pricing Model a logical extension of portfolio selection theory is to consider the equilibrium asset pricing consequences of investors individually

More information

Lecture Notes: Basic Concepts in Option Pricing - The Black and Scholes Model

Lecture Notes: Basic Concepts in Option Pricing - The Black and Scholes Model Brunel University Msc., EC5504, Financial Engineering Prof Menelaos Karanasos Lecture Notes: Basic Concepts in Option Pricing - The Black and Scholes Model Recall that the price of an option is equal to

More information

A note on the impact of options on stock return volatility 1

A note on the impact of options on stock return volatility 1 Journal of Banking & Finance 22 (1998) 1181±1191 A note on the impact of options on stock return volatility 1 Nicolas P.B. Bollen 2 University of Utah, David Eccles School of Business, Salt Lake City,

More information

SAMPLE MID-TERM QUESTIONS

SAMPLE MID-TERM QUESTIONS SAMPLE MID-TERM QUESTIONS William L. Silber HOW TO PREPARE FOR THE MID- TERM: 1. Study in a group 2. Review the concept questions in the Before and After book 3. When you review the questions listed below,

More information

Internet Appendix for Institutional Trade Persistence and Long-term Equity Returns

Internet Appendix for Institutional Trade Persistence and Long-term Equity Returns Internet Appendix for Institutional Trade Persistence and Long-term Equity Returns AMIL DASGUPTA, ANDREA PRAT, and MICHELA VERARDO Abstract In this document we provide supplementary material and robustness

More information

Fundamentals of Futures and Options (a summary)

Fundamentals of Futures and Options (a summary) Fundamentals of Futures and Options (a summary) Roger G. Clarke, Harindra de Silva, CFA, and Steven Thorley, CFA Published 2013 by the Research Foundation of CFA Institute Summary prepared by Roger G.

More information

Commodities: an asset class in their own right?

Commodities: an asset class in their own right? PHILIPPE MONGARS, CHRISTOPHE MARCHAL-DOMBRAT Market Operations Directorate Market Making and Monitoring Division Investor interest in commodities has risen in recent years in line with the spectacular

More information

Chapter 3: Commodity Forwards and Futures

Chapter 3: Commodity Forwards and Futures Chapter 3: Commodity Forwards and Futures In the previous chapter we study financial forward and futures contracts and we concluded that are all alike. Each commodity forward, however, has some unique

More information

Incorporating Commodities into a Multi-Asset Class Risk Model

Incorporating Commodities into a Multi-Asset Class Risk Model Incorporating Commodities into a Multi-Asset Class Risk Model Dan dibartolomeo, Presenting Research by TJ Blackburn 2013 London Investment Seminar November, 2013 Outline of Today s Presentation Institutional

More information

The Changing Relationship Between Commodity Prices and Prices of Other Assets with Global Market Integration

The Changing Relationship Between Commodity Prices and Prices of Other Assets with Global Market Integration The Changing Relationship Between Commodity Prices and Prices of Other Assets with Global Market Integration Barbara Rossi ICREA, CREI, Duke, UPF, BGSE January 31, 1 Abstract We explore the linkage between

More information

Corporate Income Taxation

Corporate Income Taxation Corporate Income Taxation We have stressed that tax incidence must be traced to people, since corporations cannot bear the burden of a tax. Why then tax corporations at all? There are several possible

More information

A General Approach to Recovering Market Expectations from Futures Prices (with an Application to Crude Oil)

A General Approach to Recovering Market Expectations from Futures Prices (with an Application to Crude Oil) A General Approach to Recovering Market Expectations from Futures Prices (with an Application to Crude Oil) Christiane Baumeister Lutz Kilian University of Notre Dame University of Michigan CEPR Motivation

More information

Black Box Trend Following Lifting the Veil

Black Box Trend Following Lifting the Veil AlphaQuest CTA Research Series #1 The goal of this research series is to demystify specific black box CTA trend following strategies and to analyze their characteristics both as a stand-alone product as

More information

Introduction to Futures Contracts

Introduction to Futures Contracts Introduction to Futures Contracts September 2010 PREPARED BY Eric Przybylinski Research Analyst Gregory J. Leonberger, FSA Director of Research Abstract Futures contracts are widely utilized throughout

More information

Discussion of Momentum and Autocorrelation in Stock Returns

Discussion of Momentum and Autocorrelation in Stock Returns Discussion of Momentum and Autocorrelation in Stock Returns Joseph Chen University of Southern California Harrison Hong Stanford University Jegadeesh and Titman (1993) document individual stock momentum:

More information

How to Time the Commodity Market

How to Time the Commodity Market How to Time the Commodity Market Devraj Basu, Roel C.A. Oomen and Alexander Stremme June 2006 Abstract Over the past few years, commodity prices have experienced the biggest boom in half a century. In

More information

Asymmetry and the Cost of Capital

Asymmetry and the Cost of Capital Asymmetry and the Cost of Capital Javier García Sánchez, IAE Business School Lorenzo Preve, IAE Business School Virginia Sarria Allende, IAE Business School Abstract The expected cost of capital is a crucial

More information

Commodity Variance Risk Premia and Expected Futures Returns: Evidence from the Crude Oil Market

Commodity Variance Risk Premia and Expected Futures Returns: Evidence from the Crude Oil Market Commodity Variance Risk Premia and Expected Futures Returns: Evidence from the Crude Oil Market Sang Baum Kang Xuhui Pan y March 1 014 Abstract We develop an extended mean-variance model to investigate

More information

9 Hedging the Risk of an Energy Futures Portfolio UNCORRECTED PROOFS. Carol Alexander 9.1 MAPPING PORTFOLIOS TO CONSTANT MATURITY FUTURES 12 T 1)

9 Hedging the Risk of an Energy Futures Portfolio UNCORRECTED PROOFS. Carol Alexander 9.1 MAPPING PORTFOLIOS TO CONSTANT MATURITY FUTURES 12 T 1) Helyette Geman c0.tex V - 0//0 :00 P.M. Page Hedging the Risk of an Energy Futures Portfolio Carol Alexander This chapter considers a hedging problem for a trader in futures on crude oil, heating oil and

More information

Mechanics of the Futures Market. Andrew Wilkinson

Mechanics of the Futures Market. Andrew Wilkinson Mechanics of the Futures Market Andrew Wilkinson Risk Disclosure Options and Futures are not suitable for all investors. The amount you may lose may be greater than your initial investment. Before trading

More information

Optimal portfolio selection in a Value-at-Risk framework

Optimal portfolio selection in a Value-at-Risk framework Journal of Banking & Finance 25 2001) 1789±1804 www.elsevier.com/locate/econbase Optimal portfolio selection in a Value-at-Risk framework Rachel Campbell, Ronald Huisman, Kees Koedijk * Department of Business

More information

Introduction, Forwards and Futures

Introduction, Forwards and Futures Introduction, Forwards and Futures Liuren Wu Zicklin School of Business, Baruch College Fall, 2007 (Hull chapters: 1,2,3,5) Liuren Wu Introduction, Forwards & Futures Option Pricing, Fall, 2007 1 / 35

More information

Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Reports

Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Reports Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Reports Financial Intermediation, Asset Prices, and Macroeconomic Dynamics Tobias Adrian Emanuel Moench Hyun Song Shin Staff Report no. 422 January 2010 Revised September

More information

Sensex Realized Volatility Index

Sensex Realized Volatility Index Sensex Realized Volatility Index Introduction: Volatility modelling has traditionally relied on complex econometric procedures in order to accommodate the inherent latent character of volatility. Realized

More information

Normalization and Mixed Degrees of Integration in Cointegrated Time Series Systems

Normalization and Mixed Degrees of Integration in Cointegrated Time Series Systems Normalization and Mixed Degrees of Integration in Cointegrated Time Series Systems Robert J. Rossana Department of Economics, 04 F/AB, Wayne State University, Detroit MI 480 E-Mail: r.j.rossana@wayne.edu

More information

Online appendix to paper Downside Market Risk of Carry Trades

Online appendix to paper Downside Market Risk of Carry Trades Online appendix to paper Downside Market Risk of Carry Trades A1. SUB-SAMPLE OF DEVELOPED COUNTRIES I study a sub-sample of developed countries separately for two reasons. First, some of the emerging countries

More information

Index Volatility Futures in Asset Allocation: A Hedging Framework

Index Volatility Futures in Asset Allocation: A Hedging Framework Investment Research Index Volatility Futures in Asset Allocation: A Hedging Framework Jai Jacob, Portfolio Manager/Analyst, Lazard Asset Management Emma Rasiel, PhD, Assistant Professor of the Practice

More information

Dynamic Leverage Asset Pricing

Dynamic Leverage Asset Pricing Dynamic Leverage Asset Pricing Tobias Adrian Emanuel Moench Hyun Song Shin This version: February 28, 2015 Abstract We empirically investigate predictions from alternative intermediary asset pricing theories.

More information

Assumptions: No transaction cost, same rate for borrowing/lending, no default/counterparty risk

Assumptions: No transaction cost, same rate for borrowing/lending, no default/counterparty risk Derivatives Why? Allow easier methods to short sell a stock without a broker lending it. Facilitates hedging easily Allows the ability to take long/short position on less available commodities (Rice, Cotton,

More information

Invest in Direct Energy

Invest in Direct Energy Invest in Direct Energy (Forthcoming Journal of Investing) Peng Chen Joseph Pinsky February 2002 225 North Michigan Avenue, Suite 700, Chicago, IL 6060-7676! (32) 66-620 Peng Chen is Vice President, Direct

More information

1 Volatility Trading Strategies

1 Volatility Trading Strategies Brunel University Msc., EC5504, Financial Engineering Prof Menelaos Karanasos Lecture Notes: Volatility Trading Strategies 1 Volatility Trading Strategies As previously explained, volatility is essentially

More information

Hedging Using Forward Contracts

Hedging Using Forward Contracts 10 CHAPTER 1 Business Snapshot1.1 Hedge Funds Hedge funds have become major users of derivatives for hedging, speculation, and arbitrage. A hedge fund is similar to a mutual fund in that it invests funds

More information

Liquidity Supply and Volatility: Futures Market Evidence *

Liquidity Supply and Volatility: Futures Market Evidence * Liquidity Supply and Volatility: Futures Market Evidence * Peter R. Locke Commodity Futures Trading Commission George Washington University Asani Sarkar Federal Reserve Bank of New York 33 Liberty Street

More information

CFA Examination PORTFOLIO MANAGEMENT Page 1 of 6

CFA Examination PORTFOLIO MANAGEMENT Page 1 of 6 PORTFOLIO MANAGEMENT A. INTRODUCTION RETURN AS A RANDOM VARIABLE E(R) = the return around which the probability distribution is centered: the expected value or mean of the probability distribution of possible

More information

Predicting the US Real GDP Growth Using Yield Spread of Corporate Bonds

Predicting the US Real GDP Growth Using Yield Spread of Corporate Bonds International Department Working Paper Series 00-E-3 Predicting the US Real GDP Growth Using Yield Spread of Corporate Bonds Yoshihito SAITO yoshihito.saitou@boj.or.jp Yoko TAKEDA youko.takeda@boj.or.jp

More information

Chapter 1. Vector autoregressions. 1.1 VARs and the identi cation problem

Chapter 1. Vector autoregressions. 1.1 VARs and the identi cation problem Chapter Vector autoregressions We begin by taking a look at the data of macroeconomics. A way to summarize the dynamics of macroeconomic data is to make use of vector autoregressions. VAR models have become

More information

Market Efficiency and Stock Market Predictability

Market Efficiency and Stock Market Predictability Mphil Subject 301 Market Efficiency and Stock Market Predictability M. Hashem Pesaran March 2003 1 1 Stock Return Regressions R t+1 r t = a+b 1 x 1t +b 2 x 2t +...+b k x kt +ε t+1, (1) R t+1 is the one-period

More information

Working Papers. Cointegration Based Trading Strategy For Soft Commodities Market. Piotr Arendarski Łukasz Postek. No. 2/2012 (68)

Working Papers. Cointegration Based Trading Strategy For Soft Commodities Market. Piotr Arendarski Łukasz Postek. No. 2/2012 (68) Working Papers No. 2/2012 (68) Piotr Arendarski Łukasz Postek Cointegration Based Trading Strategy For Soft Commodities Market Warsaw 2012 Cointegration Based Trading Strategy For Soft Commodities Market

More information

B.3. Robustness: alternative betas estimation

B.3. Robustness: alternative betas estimation Appendix B. Additional empirical results and robustness tests This Appendix contains additional empirical results and robustness tests. B.1. Sharpe ratios of beta-sorted portfolios Fig. B1 plots the Sharpe

More information

Interest Rates and Real Business Cycles in Emerging Markets

Interest Rates and Real Business Cycles in Emerging Markets CENTRAL BANK OF THE REPUBLIC OF TURKEY WORKING PAPER NO: 0/08 Interest Rates and Real Business Cycles in Emerging Markets May 200 S. Tolga TİRYAKİ Central Bank of the Republic of Turkey 200 Address: Central

More information

Liquidity of Corporate Bonds

Liquidity of Corporate Bonds Liquidity of Corporate Bonds Jack Bao, Jun Pan and Jiang Wang MIT October 21, 2008 The Q-Group Autumn Meeting Liquidity and Corporate Bonds In comparison, low levels of trading in corporate bond market

More information

The relationship between exchange rates, interest rates. In this lecture we will learn how exchange rates accommodate equilibrium in

The relationship between exchange rates, interest rates. In this lecture we will learn how exchange rates accommodate equilibrium in The relationship between exchange rates, interest rates In this lecture we will learn how exchange rates accommodate equilibrium in financial markets. For this purpose we examine the relationship between

More information

VaR-x: Fat tails in nancial risk management

VaR-x: Fat tails in nancial risk management VaR-x: Fat tails in nancial risk management Ronald Huisman, Kees G. Koedijk, and Rachel A. J. Pownall To ensure a competent regulatory framework with respect to value-at-risk (VaR) for establishing a bank's

More information

Research Division Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Working Paper Series

Research Division Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Working Paper Series Research Division Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Working Paper Series Comment on "Taylor Rule Exchange Rate Forecasting During the Financial Crisis" Michael W. McCracken Working Paper 2012-030A http://research.stlouisfed.org/wp/2012/2012-030.pdf

More information

Carry Trades and Currency Crashes: A Comment

Carry Trades and Currency Crashes: A Comment Carry Trades and Currency Crashes: A Comment Craig Burnside y July 2008 Abstract The failure of uncovered interest parity and the pro tability of the carry trade in currencies are intimately related, and

More information

Chapter 1 - Introduction

Chapter 1 - Introduction Chapter 1 - Introduction Derivative securities Futures contracts Forward contracts Futures and forward markets Comparison of futures and forward contracts Options contracts Options markets Comparison of

More information

Review for Exam 2. Instructions: Please read carefully

Review for Exam 2. Instructions: Please read carefully Review for Exam 2 Instructions: Please read carefully The exam will have 25 multiple choice questions and 5 work problems You are not responsible for any topics that are not covered in the lecture note

More information

The Abnormal Performance of Bond Returns

The Abnormal Performance of Bond Returns The University of Reading THE BUSINESS SCHOOL FOR FINANCIAL MARKETS The Abnormal Performance of Bond Returns Joëlle Miffre ISMA Centre, The University of Reading, Reading, Berks., RG6 6BA, UK Copyright

More information

René Garcia Professor of finance

René Garcia Professor of finance Liquidity Risk: What is it? How to Measure it? René Garcia Professor of finance EDHEC Business School, CIRANO Cirano, Montreal, January 7, 2009 The financial and economic environment We are living through

More information

Exchange-traded Funds

Exchange-traded Funds Mitch Kosev and Thomas Williams* The exchange-traded fund (ETF) industry has grown strongly in a relatively short period of time, with the industry attracting greater attention as it grows in size. The

More information

FINANCIAL ECONOMICS OPTION PRICING

FINANCIAL ECONOMICS OPTION PRICING OPTION PRICING Options are contingency contracts that specify payoffs if stock prices reach specified levels. A call option is the right to buy a stock at a specified price, X, called the strike price.

More information

The Long-Term Cost of the Financial Crisis* 1

The Long-Term Cost of the Financial Crisis* 1 The Long-Term Cost of the Financial Crisis* 1 Murillo Campello John R. Graham Campbell R. Harvey University of Illinois Duke University Duke University & NBER & NBER & NBER campello@illinois.edu john.graham@duke.edu

More information

Online Appendix to Impatient Trading, Liquidity. Provision, and Stock Selection by Mutual Funds

Online Appendix to Impatient Trading, Liquidity. Provision, and Stock Selection by Mutual Funds Online Appendix to Impatient Trading, Liquidity Provision, and Stock Selection by Mutual Funds Zhi Da, Pengjie Gao, and Ravi Jagannathan This Draft: April 10, 2010 Correspondence: Zhi Da, Finance Department,

More information

Volatility: A Brief Overview

Volatility: A Brief Overview The Benefits of Systematically Selling Volatility July 2014 By Jeremy Berman Justin Frankel Co-Portfolio Managers of the RiverPark Structural Alpha Fund Abstract: A strategy of systematically selling volatility

More information

Journal Of Financial And Strategic Decisions Volume 9 Number 2 Summer 1996

Journal Of Financial And Strategic Decisions Volume 9 Number 2 Summer 1996 Journal Of Financial And Strategic Decisions Volume 9 Number 2 Summer 1996 THE USE OF FINANCIAL RATIOS AS MEASURES OF RISK IN THE DETERMINATION OF THE BID-ASK SPREAD Huldah A. Ryan * Abstract The effect

More information

Potential research topics for joint research: Forecasting oil prices with forecast combination methods. Dean Fantazzini.

Potential research topics for joint research: Forecasting oil prices with forecast combination methods. Dean Fantazzini. Potential research topics for joint research: Forecasting oil prices with forecast combination methods Dean Fantazzini Koper, 26/11/2014 Overview of the Presentation Introduction Dean Fantazzini 2 Overview

More information

Commodity Speculation and Commodity Investment

Commodity Speculation and Commodity Investment Global Commodities Forum Palais des Nations, Geneva 22-23 March 2010 Commodity Speculation and Commodity Investment by Mr. Christopher L. Gilbert, Academic Director, Doctoral Programme in Economics and

More information

Speculation in Commodity Futures Markets, Inventories and the Price of Crude Oil

Speculation in Commodity Futures Markets, Inventories and the Price of Crude Oil Speculation in Commodity Futures Markets, Inventories and the Price of Crude Oil Sungje Byun January, 203 Abstract Refiners have a motive to hold inventories even if they anticipate falling crude oil prices.

More information

Investment in United States Futures and

Investment in United States Futures and Investment in United States Futures and Options Markets: A Discussion of the Possible Impact on Commodity Prices 1 Frank S. Rose COLLEGE OF BUSINESS, LEWIS UNIVERSITY, UNITED STATES JOINT MEETING INTERGOVERNMENTAL

More information

Conditional Investment-Cash Flow Sensitivities and Financing Constraints

Conditional Investment-Cash Flow Sensitivities and Financing Constraints WORING PAPERS IN ECONOMICS No 448 Conditional Investment-Cash Flow Sensitivities and Financing Constraints Stephen R. Bond and Måns Söderbom May 2010 ISSN 1403-2473 (print) ISSN 1403-2465 (online) Department

More information

Topic 5: Stochastic Growth and Real Business Cycles

Topic 5: Stochastic Growth and Real Business Cycles Topic 5: Stochastic Growth and Real Business Cycles Yulei Luo SEF of HKU October 1, 2015 Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) Macro Theory October 1, 2015 1 / 45 Lag Operators The lag operator (L) is de ned as Similar

More information

In ation Tax and In ation Subsidies: Working Capital in a Cash-in-advance model

In ation Tax and In ation Subsidies: Working Capital in a Cash-in-advance model In ation Tax and In ation Subsidies: Working Capital in a Cash-in-advance model George T. McCandless March 3, 006 Abstract This paper studies the nature of monetary policy with nancial intermediaries that

More information

Internet Appendix to Stock Market Liquidity and the Business Cycle

Internet Appendix to Stock Market Liquidity and the Business Cycle Internet Appendix to Stock Market Liquidity and the Business Cycle Randi Næs, Johannes A. Skjeltorp and Bernt Arne Ødegaard This Internet appendix contains additional material to the paper Stock Market

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES CARRY TRADES AND RISK. Craig Burnside. Working Paper 17278 http://www.nber.org/papers/w17278

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES CARRY TRADES AND RISK. Craig Burnside. Working Paper 17278 http://www.nber.org/papers/w17278 NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES CARRY TRADES AND RISK Craig Burnside Working Paper 17278 http://www.nber.org/papers/w17278 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge, MA 02138 August

More information

The Credit Spread Cycle with Matching Friction

The Credit Spread Cycle with Matching Friction The Credit Spread Cycle with Matching Friction Kevin E. Beaubrun-Diant and Fabien Tripier y June 8, 00 Abstract We herein advance a contribution to the theoretical literature on nancial frictions and show

More information

Financial Development and Macroeconomic Stability

Financial Development and Macroeconomic Stability Financial Development and Macroeconomic Stability Vincenzo Quadrini University of Southern California Urban Jermann Wharton School of the University of Pennsylvania January 31, 2005 VERY PRELIMINARY AND

More information

In recent years, Federal Reserve (Fed) policymakers have come to rely

In recent years, Federal Reserve (Fed) policymakers have come to rely Long-Term Interest Rates and Inflation: A Fisherian Approach Peter N. Ireland In recent years, Federal Reserve (Fed) policymakers have come to rely on long-term bond yields to measure the public s long-term

More information

Investing In Volatility

Investing In Volatility Investing In Volatility By: Anish Parvataneni, CFA Portfolio Manager LJM Partners Ltd. LJM Partners, Ltd. is issuing a series a white papers on the subject of investing in volatility as an asset class.

More information

10. Fixed-Income Securities. Basic Concepts

10. Fixed-Income Securities. Basic Concepts 0. Fixed-Income Securities Fixed-income securities (FIS) are bonds that have no default risk and their payments are fully determined in advance. Sometimes corporate bonds that do not necessarily have certain

More information

How To Calculate Futures Risk Premium

How To Calculate Futures Risk Premium Yale ICF Working Paper No. 07-08 The Fundamentals of Commodity Futures Returns* Gary B. Gorton School of Management, Yale University and National Bureau of Economic Research Fumio Hayashi University of

More information

The Effect of Housing on Portfolio Choice. July 2009

The Effect of Housing on Portfolio Choice. July 2009 The Effect of Housing on Portfolio Choice Raj Chetty Harvard Univ. Adam Szeidl UC-Berkeley July 2009 Introduction How does homeownership affect financial portfolios? Linkages between housing and financial

More information

Lecture 1: Asset pricing and the equity premium puzzle

Lecture 1: Asset pricing and the equity premium puzzle Lecture 1: Asset pricing and the equity premium puzzle Simon Gilchrist Boston Univerity and NBER EC 745 Fall, 2013 Overview Some basic facts. Study the asset pricing implications of household portfolio

More information

Four Derivations of the Black Scholes PDE by Fabrice Douglas Rouah www.frouah.com www.volopta.com

Four Derivations of the Black Scholes PDE by Fabrice Douglas Rouah www.frouah.com www.volopta.com Four Derivations of the Black Scholes PDE by Fabrice Douglas Rouah www.frouah.com www.volopta.com In this Note we derive the Black Scholes PDE for an option V, given by @t + 1 + rs @S2 @S We derive the

More information

AFM 472. Midterm Examination. Monday Oct. 24, 2011. A. Huang

AFM 472. Midterm Examination. Monday Oct. 24, 2011. A. Huang AFM 472 Midterm Examination Monday Oct. 24, 2011 A. Huang Name: Answer Key Student Number: Section (circle one): 10:00am 1:00pm 2:30pm Instructions: 1. Answer all questions in the space provided. If space

More information

Decision-Based Forecast Evaluation of UK Interest Rate Predictability*

Decision-Based Forecast Evaluation of UK Interest Rate Predictability* DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS Decision-Based Forecast Evaluation of UK Interest Rate Predictability* Stephen Hall, University of Leicester, UK Kevin Lee, University of Leicester, UK Kavita Sirichand, University

More information

Capital Constraints, Lending over the Cycle and the Precautionary Motive: A Quantitative Exploration (Working Paper)

Capital Constraints, Lending over the Cycle and the Precautionary Motive: A Quantitative Exploration (Working Paper) Capital Constraints, Lending over the Cycle and the Precautionary Motive: A Quantitative Exploration (Working Paper) Angus Armstrong and Monique Ebell National Institute of Economic and Social Research

More information

CHAPTER 10 RISK AND RETURN: THE CAPITAL ASSET PRICING MODEL (CAPM)

CHAPTER 10 RISK AND RETURN: THE CAPITAL ASSET PRICING MODEL (CAPM) CHAPTER 10 RISK AND RETURN: THE CAPITAL ASSET PRICING MODEL (CAPM) Answers to Concepts Review and Critical Thinking Questions 1. Some of the risk in holding any asset is unique to the asset in question.

More information

BEAR: A person who believes that the price of a particular security or the market as a whole will go lower.

BEAR: A person who believes that the price of a particular security or the market as a whole will go lower. Trading Terms ARBITRAGE: The simultaneous purchase and sale of identical or equivalent financial instruments in order to benefit from a discrepancy in their price relationship. More generally, it refers

More information

The recent turmoil in nancial markets has highlighted the need

The recent turmoil in nancial markets has highlighted the need Economic Quarterly Volume 100, Number 1 First Quarter 2014 Pages 51 85 A Business Cycle Analysis of Debt and Equity Financing Marios Karabarbounis, Patrick Macnamara, and Roisin McCord The recent turmoil

More information

Eurodollar Futures, and Forwards

Eurodollar Futures, and Forwards 5 Eurodollar Futures, and Forwards In this chapter we will learn about Eurodollar Deposits Eurodollar Futures Contracts, Hedging strategies using ED Futures, Forward Rate Agreements, Pricing FRAs. Hedging

More information

Optimal Investment. Government policy is typically targeted heavily on investment; most tax codes favor it.

Optimal Investment. Government policy is typically targeted heavily on investment; most tax codes favor it. Douglas Hibbs L, L3: AAU Macro Theory 0-0-9/4 Optimal Investment Why Care About Investment? Investment drives capital formation, and the stock of capital is a key determinant of output and consequently

More information

The Microstructure of Currency Markets

The Microstructure of Currency Markets The Microstructure of Currency Markets Martin D. D. Evans Department of Economics Georgetown University and NBER July 2010 Abstract This article summarizes exchange-rate research using microstructure models.

More information

Implied Volatility Skews in the Foreign Exchange Market. Empirical Evidence from JPY and GBP: 1997-2002

Implied Volatility Skews in the Foreign Exchange Market. Empirical Evidence from JPY and GBP: 1997-2002 Implied Volatility Skews in the Foreign Exchange Market Empirical Evidence from JPY and GBP: 1997-2002 The Leonard N. Stern School of Business Glucksman Institute for Research in Securities Markets Faculty

More information

Intraday Trading Invariance. E-Mini S&P 500 Futures Market

Intraday Trading Invariance. E-Mini S&P 500 Futures Market in the E-Mini S&P 500 Futures Market University of Illinois at Chicago Joint with Torben G. Andersen, Pete Kyle, and Anna Obizhaeva R/Finance 2015 Conference University of Illinois at Chicago May 29-30,

More information

I.e., the return per dollar from investing in the shares from time 0 to time 1,

I.e., the return per dollar from investing in the shares from time 0 to time 1, XVII. SECURITY PRICING AND SECURITY ANALYSIS IN AN EFFICIENT MARKET Consider the following somewhat simplified description of a typical analyst-investor's actions in making an investment decision. First,

More information

Broker-Dealer Leverage and the Cross-Section of Stock Returns

Broker-Dealer Leverage and the Cross-Section of Stock Returns Broker-Dealer Leverage and the Cross-Section of Stock Returns Tobias Adrian tobias.adrian@ny.frb.org Erkko Etula etula@post.harvard.edu Tyler Muir t-muir@kellogg.northwestern.edu January 2011 Abstract

More information

CHAPTER 22: FUTURES MARKETS

CHAPTER 22: FUTURES MARKETS CHAPTER 22: FUTURES MARKETS PROBLEM SETS 1. There is little hedging or speculative demand for cement futures, since cement prices are fairly stable and predictable. The trading activity necessary to support

More information

A Review of Cross Sectional Regression for Financial Data You should already know this material from previous study

A Review of Cross Sectional Regression for Financial Data You should already know this material from previous study A Review of Cross Sectional Regression for Financial Data You should already know this material from previous study But I will offer a review, with a focus on issues which arise in finance 1 TYPES OF FINANCIAL

More information

This paper is not to be removed from the Examination Halls

This paper is not to be removed from the Examination Halls ~~FN3023 ZB d0 This paper is not to be removed from the Examination Halls UNIVERSITY OF LONDON FN3023 ZB BSc degrees and Diplomas for Graduates in Economics, Management, Finance and the Social Sciences,

More information

Financial Markets. Itay Goldstein. Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania

Financial Markets. Itay Goldstein. Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania Financial Markets Itay Goldstein Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania 1 Trading and Price Formation This line of the literature analyzes the formation of prices in financial markets in a setting

More information

The Fundamentals of Commodity Futures Returns*

The Fundamentals of Commodity Futures Returns* The Fundamentals of Commodity Futures Returns* Gary B. Gorton School of Management, Yale University and National Bureau of Economic Research Fumio Hayashi Graduate School of International Corporate Strategy,

More information

Changing income shocks or changed insurance - what determines consumption inequality?

Changing income shocks or changed insurance - what determines consumption inequality? Changing income shocks or changed insurance - what determines consumption inequality? Johannes Ludwig Ruhr Graduate School in Economics & Ruhr-Universität Bochum Abstract Contrary to the implications of

More information

Asymmetric Information (2)

Asymmetric Information (2) Asymmetric nformation (2) John Y. Campbell Ec2723 November 2013 John Y. Campbell (Ec2723) Asymmetric nformation (2) November 2013 1 / 24 Outline Market microstructure The study of trading costs Bid-ask

More information

Rethinking Fixed Income

Rethinking Fixed Income Rethinking Fixed Income Challenging Conventional Wisdom May 2013 Risk. Reinsurance. Human Resources. Rethinking Fixed Income: Challenging Conventional Wisdom With US Treasury interest rates at, or near,

More information