Crowdsourced Digital Goods and Firm Productivity



Similar documents
Crowdsourced Digital Goods and Firm Productivity: Evidence from Free and Open Source Software DRAFT

IT Knowledge Spillovers and Productivity: Evidence from Enterprise Software *

Network of Practice, IT Knowledge Spillovers, and Productivity: Evidence from Enterprise Software

A Brief Survey of the Economics of Open Source Software. Chaim Fershtman and Neil Gandal 1,2. June 2011

Do Supplemental Online Recorded Lectures Help Students Learn Microeconomics?*

Markups and Firm-Level Export Status: Appendix

JOB HOPPING, INFORMATION TECHNOLOGY SPILLOVERS, AND PRODUCTIVITY GROWTH

IT Productivity and Aggregation using Income Accounting

MEASURING INFORMATION TECHNOLOGY SPILLOVERS

Introduction. Current methodology

Open Source Software Development

Sources United States-NAICS based

FDI as a source of finance in imperfect capital markets Firm-Level Evidence from Argentina

Combining Information Technology and Decentralized Work Organization: SMEs versus Larger Firms

HAS THE PRODUCTIVITY BOOM FINALLY ARRIVED?

Introduction to Open Source. Marco Zennaro Carlo Fonda

What Leads to Innovation? An Analysis of Collaborative Problem-Solving

Microsoft & Open Source Software

April 2015 Revenue Forecast. Methodology and Technical Documentation

Combining Technology and Work Organization: An Analysis of Complementarity between IT and Decentralization across Firms of Different Size

Measuring Innovation s Role in GDP & Productivity Growth

Open Source Software: No Free Lunch?

2013 Energy Savings Results for the Commercial Real Estate Cohorts

On March 11, 2010, President Barack

Marketing Mix Modelling and Big Data P. M Cain

This study extends existing information technology (IT) productivity research by evaluating the contributions

An Analysis of Price Determination and Markups in the Air-Conditioning and Heating Equipment Industry

How To Calculate Export Earnings

Market Value of R&D, Patents, and Organizational Capital: Finnish Evidence

The Business Value of CRM Systems: Productivity, Profitability, and Time Lag

Why develop open-source software? The role of non-pecuniary benefits, monetary rewards, and open-source licence type

Understanding Linux Migrations: How easy is it to change distributions?

Prasanna Tambe Stern School of Business, New York University New York, NY

Private Sector Investment and Employment Impacts of Reassigning Spectrum to Mobile Broadband in the United States

The Relationship Between Computer Networks and Plants Labor Productivity

11th National Convention on Statistics (NCS) EDSA Shangri-La Hotel October 4-5, 2010

Technical Efficiency Accounting for Environmental Influence in the Japanese Gas Market

Why Do High-Tech Firms Offer Perks at Work?

Do R&D or Capital Expenditures Impact Wage Inequality? Evidence from the IT Industry in Taiwan ROC

CSPA. Common Statistical Production Architecture Descritption of the Business aspects of the architecture: business models for sharing software

The U.S. Software Industry: An Engine for Economic Growth and Employment

Outsourcing and Imported Services in BEA s Industry Accounts

An Economic Impact Analysis.

Traditional Commercial Software Development. Open Source Development. Traditional Assumptions. Intangible Goods. Dr. James A.

Economy-Wide and Industry-Level Impact of Information Technology

Converting Historical Industry Time Series Data from SIC to NAICS

Effective Federal Income Tax Rates Faced By Small Businesses in the United States

BIG DATA INVESTMENT, SKILLS, AND FIRM VALUE

The U.S. Software Industry As an Engine for Economic Growth and Employment. Robert J. Shapiro

There are 6 base years in China GDP estimation history. The base year of

Internet Appendix to Collateral Spread and Financial Development *

Executive Summary. Abstract. Heitman Analytics Conclusions:

The Elasticity of Taxable Income: A Non-Technical Summary

VIDEO GAMES. 21 the st CENTURY THE 2014 REPORT BY STEPHEN E. SIWEK.

Scope of Capital Measurement and Classifications

HW 2 Macroeconomics 102 Due on 06/12

The impact of exports on economic growth: It s the market. form

Incentive Structure on Open Source Software Community: Case Study of GitHub

The Effects of Unemployment on Crime Rates in the U.S.

An Econometric Assessment of Electricity Demand in the United States Using Panel Data and the Impact of Retail Competition on Prices

Export Pricing and Credit Constraints: Theory and Evidence from Greek Firms. Online Data Appendix (not intended for publication) Elias Dinopoulos

National Heavy Duty Truck Transportation Efficiency Macroeconomic Impact Analysis

August Industry Report: SolarBusinessServices. Solar Businesses in Australia. Prepared for: Rec Agents Association

The Economic Impact of the New Hospital on the Economy of Drumright, Creek County, Oklahoma

Inflation. Chapter Money Supply and Demand

ACCRUAL ACCOUNTING MEASURES FOR NIPA TIME SERIES. Why is Accrual Accounting Important? Definitions

Benchmark Revisions and the U.S. Personal Saving Rate. Leonard I. Nakamura and Tom Stark. Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia.

Asymmetric Effects of the Financial Crisis: Collateral-Based Investment-Cash Flow Sensitivity Analysis

Measuring GDP and Economic Growth

The Decline of the U.S. Labor Share. by Michael Elsby (University of Edinburgh), Bart Hobijn (FRB SF), and Aysegul Sahin (FRB NY)

Rose Business Technologies

Free software GNU/Linux TOR project

IHS Study on the Economic Impact of Proposed Restrictions on Tax Exempt Bonds for Nonprofit Organizations

The Economics of Open Source and Free Software* Gerald P. Dwyer, Jr. Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta

Small, Medium-sized, and Large Businesses in the Canadian Economy: Measuring Their Contribution to Gross Domestic Product from 2001 to 2008

How To Find Out How Effective Stimulus Is

PRODUCTIVITY AND COSTS First Quarter 2015, Revised

The Economic Impacts of Reducing. Natural Gas and Electricity Use in Ontario

On the Influence of Free Software on Code Reuse in Software Development

A PROTOTYPE INDUSTRY-LEVEL PRODUCTION ACCOUNT FOR THE UNITED STATES,

The Life-Cycle Motive and Money Demand: Further Evidence. Abstract

A Primer on Forecasting Business Performance

How Sensitive are Low Income Families to Health Plan Prices?

Is Economics a Good Major for Future Lawyers? Evidence from Earnings Data

In contrast to the large and rapidly growing literature on information technology (IT) investments and firm

The Economic Impact of Health Services on the Economy of Sumter County, Alabama

Nonprofit pay and benefits: estimates from the National Compensation Survey

THE OTHER PRODUCTIVITY PUZZLE BUSINESS DYNAMISM AND PRODUCTIVITY GROWTH BEFORE THE CRISIS

Intermediate Macroeconomics: The Real Business Cycle Model

Assessing Three-Way Complementarities: Abstract

Strength in Numbers: How Does Data-Driven Decisionmaking Affect Firm Performance?

BIDM Project. Predicting the contract type for IT/ITES outsourcing contracts

Asset based finance in Scotland:

Imported Inputs and Industry Contributions to Economic Growth: An Assessment of Alternative Approaches

Policy on Device Drivers for Procurement of Hardware for e-governance

Integrated Resource Plan

The Returns to an MBA Degree: The Impact of Programme Attributes

Sources of US Economic Growth, the Role of Information Technology and Sectoral Dispersion*

SPECIALIZATION AND NEIGHBORHOOD EFFECTS

Linux, Open Source, and IBM: The Next Decade

Transcription:

Paper to be presented at the DRUID Society Conference 2014, CBS, Copenhagen, June 16-18 Crowdsourced Digital Goods and Firm Productivity Frank Nagle Harvard Busines School Technology and Operations Management fnagle@hbs.edu Abstract As crowdsourced digital goods become more freely available and more frequently used as key inputs by firms, understanding the impact they have on productivity becomes of critical importance. In this paper, I measure the impact of one such good, open source software (OSS), on firm productivity. I find a positive and significant return to the usage of OSS. I address the endogeneity issues inherent in productivity studies by using panel data with random effects combined with an instrumental variable approach. Further, I use a matching estimation to provide additional support for my primary finding. My findings fill an important gap in the existing literature on the returns to IT investment, which currently does not properly account for non-pecuniary digital inputs. Jelcodes:O30,O47

Crowdsourced Digital Goods and Firm Productivity February 24, 2014 Abstract As crowdsourced digital goods become more freely available and more frequently used as key inputs by firms, understanding the impact they have on productivity becomes of critical importance. In this paper, I measure the impact of one such good, open source software (OSS), on firm productivity. I find a positive and significant return to the usage of OSS. I address the endogeneity issues inherent in productivity studies by using panel data with random effects combined with an instrumental variable approach. Further, I use a matching estimation to provide additional support for my primary finding. My findings fill an important gap in the existing literature on the returns to IT investment, which currently does not properly account for non-pecuniary digital inputs. I. Introduction As the digital age progresses, information goods are easier and easier to reproduce at costs that are rapidly approaching zero. Coupled with decreases in communication costs, this has made it easier for groups of individuals, frequently referred to as the crowd, to produce digital goods that have no price. Wikipedia, the online crowdsourced encyclopedia is a frequent example of this phenomenon. However, there are many other examples including open source software (OSS), free closed source software available via app stores, and the digitization of consumers opinions for free via online review sites and social media. The same information cost decreases that have enabled the production of these goods also enable firms to use these public crowdsourced goods as inputs into production. However, the non-pecuniary nature of these goods can lead to large measurement problems when calculating productivity measures (Greenstein and Nagle, 2014). These observations lead to a question that has not been addressed in the existing

academic literature: does the consumption of non-pecuniary community developed digital goods have an impact on productivity? As both the production of such goods and the reliance on such goods as inputs into production increase, the answer to this question becomes more interesting and more important. A deeper understanding of this phenomenon may help shed light on important trends in national level productivity measures such as Gross Domestic Product (GDP). Whether measuring GDP via a country s production or its expenditures, non-pecuniary digital goods can cause such a measure to greatly underestimate the true productivity of a nation and its firms. When a digital good is produced for free and then sold for free, its value under such calculations is essentially zero since there is no direct pecuniary transaction involved in its creation or its use. Furthermore, it is quite possible that through the Schumpeterian process of creative destruction (1942), the creation of such goods may lead to the destruction of the pecuniary goods they replace, leading to such goods having a negative effect on productivity measures. For example, the creation and use of Wikipedia does not directly add to GDP since its contributors are not paid and no one pays to use it. Further, Wikipedia has greatly decreased demand for pecuniary encyclopedias (digital or otherwise), and thus the net effect on GDP is negative. However, almost everyone would agree that the value of a good such as Wikipedia is certainly greater than zero. Therefore, understanding the impact of such goods on firm productivity helps to contribute to the broad literature on the determinants of productivity. 1

To answer the question of how usage of such non-pecuniary digital inputs affects firm productivity, I utilize a dataset that combines data on usage of OSS with firm productivity measures. OSS is a frequently used example of a digital good that is produced by a community of users. OSS is a particularly interesting example due to the lack of price that is normally, although not always, associated with this model of production. This data set allows me to apply a classic Cobb-Douglas production function analysis to understand the role of non-pecuniary IT inputs in firm-level productivity. This is a standard methodology for estimating the value of IT (Brynjolfsson and Hitt, 1996; Dewan and Min, 1997; Tambe, Hitt, and Brynjolfsson, 2012; Huang, Ceccagnoli, Forman, and Wu, 2013), although non-pecuniary IT is normally not accounted for in such frameworks. Since firms endogenously decide whether or not to consume OSS, I utilize a number of strategies including panel random effects, instrumental variables, and matching methods to show the robustness of my results to a number of endogeneity and attenuation concerns. My results show that non-pecuniary OSS usage has a positive and significant impact on firm productivity. This makes intuitive sense since firms that use non-pecuniary IT are using more IT inputs than their pecuniary measures reveal. This may help explain why existing research has shown that firm returns to IT investment are heterogeneous (Aral and Weill, 2007). I find that the primary effect is robust to various endogeneity concerns and to various splits of the sample. I estimate that a 1% increase in usage of OSS leads to a.15% increase in productivity.

This paper seeks to add insights to two important bodies of literature: the user innovation literature and the returns to IT literature. The user innovation literature, in particular that which is centered on OSS, focuses primarily on supply side questions, e.g. why do individuals and firms contribute time and resources to the development of OSS, with almost no literature focusing on the demand and usage side of the OSS market. At the same time, the literature on the returns to IT investment focuses almost exclusively on IT investments that are of a pecuniary nature, completely missing investments in nonpecuniary IT, such as OSS. This paper contributes to both of these bodies of work by filling these important gaps in the literature. My findings offer important insights for researchers, practitioners, and policy makers. For researchers, the results have important implications for those studying both productivity and user innovation. On the productivity side, my results bring attention to important issues of mismeasurement in the contribution of IT to firm-level and national production. On the user innovation side, I add support to arguments that the firm s interaction with external communities is an important driver of success. For practitioners, I offer insights that can be utilized to increase the profitability of the firm s operations. Finally, for policy makers, my results encourage policies that incentivize production of public digital goods as a method for increasing firm and, in turn, national productivity. This paper is laid out as follows. In Section II, I present a brief overview of OSS and then discuss the existing gap in the OSS and productivity of IT literature. In Section III, I

construct the models I will use in my estimation and discuss my strategies for dealing with the inherent endogeneity in my study. Section IV details my dataset on OSS usage and firm production. In Section V, I present my results, and in Section VI I discuss the implications of these results and conclude. II. Free and Open Source Software and the Returns to Information Technology II.A Institutional Context: The Free and Open Source Software Movement Although the concept of free and open source software developed as part of the early computer culture, it was not formalized until 1983 when Richard Stallman founded the GNU Project 2 to create a computer operating system that gave users the freedom to share and modify the software, unlike the predominant operating system at the time, UNIX, which was proprietary and closed-source software. Two years later, Stallman founded the Free Software Foundation (FSF), a non-profit organization designed to encourage the creation and dissemination of software with unrestrictive licenses, including the GNU General Public License (GPL), which continues to be the most widely used software license for free software. The FSF emphasizes that it uses the word free to mean liberty, not price, encapsulated in the pithy slogan free as in free speech, not as in free beer. 3 However, the software released under this license is frequently also offered at a price of zero. This ambiguity later led to Eric Raymond s call for the use of the term open source instead of free (Raymond, 1998). As the GNU Project progressed, it was successful in creating most of the middle layers

and upper layers (user interface) of the operating system. However, very little work had been finished for the lowest layers, known as the kernel, of the operating system. In 1991, Linus Torvalds released the Linux kernel to take the place of the incomplete GNU kernel. GNU developers rapidly latched on to the Linux kernel and the combination of the Linux kernel and GNU software on top of it became the basis for most free and open source operating systems in use today. The other main free and open source operating system is the Berkeley Software Distribution (BSD) operating system, which was initially proprietary until a variant of version 4.3 was released as open source in 1989 under the terms of the BSD License, which allowed for redistribution provided the BSD License was included. Both GNU/Linux and BSD rely on a community of mostly unpaid contributors to maintain and upgrade the code base. Since these early operating systems were released, there has been a flood of free and open source software projects that are either a variant of these operating systems or are applications that run on top of them, such as the vast array of projects maintained by the Apache Software Foundation. Although unrestricted non-pecuniary software is at the core of the free and open source software movement, many companies have structured profitable business models on top of this software. Common examples of this include Red Hat, which offers its own Linux distribution and charges for customer support, the IBM HTTP Server, which is built on the open source Apache HTTP Server and is included with the IBM WebSphere Application Server, and Apple s Mac OS X, which is based on the FreeBSD operating system.

II.B Free and Open Source Software as an Input into Productivity The importance of OSS as an input into productivity is difficult to measure due to both meanings of free discussed above. The fact that many of the unrestrictive licenses ( free as in free speech ) allow for code to be freely used in other products makes it difficult to measure the true extent of the usage of such code. Further, the fact that much of the software that comes out of this ecosystem is non-pecuniary ( free as in free beer ) means that the production and usage of such software is mismeasured as an input into productivity since productivity measures are based on priced inputs and outputs. In this section, I discuss the research into both OSS and the productivity of IT to highlight the gap that exists at the intersection of these two bodies of literature. As early as the 1980 s, production by users has been a topic of interest in the management field (von Hippel, 1986). While such production is by no means limited to the digital world, it is here that user innovation is frequently studied, primarily in the realm of OSS. However, most of the academic work on OSS has been focused on the supply side of the equation why do users contribute to OSS (Lerner and Tirole, 2002; West and Lakhani, 2008), how do users join OSS projects (von Krogh, Spaeth, and Lakhani, 2003), how do users help each other contribute to OSS (Lakhani and von Hippel, 2003), and how do OSS communities protect their intellectual property (O Mahony, 2003). Research on the supply side has also been extended to better understand why firms release some of their proprietary code as OSS (Harhoff, Henkel, and von Hippel, 2003; von Hippel and von Krogh, 2003; Henkel, 2006; Lerner and Schankerman, 2010; Casadesus-Masanell and Llanes, 2011). Despite the abundance of

literature on the supply side of OSS, there is almost no literature on the demand side of OSS 4 who uses it, why do they use it, and are there productivity benefits to using it remain unanswered questions. This is despite the fact that OSS, and - more broadly non-pecuniary, community-based user-production, has been identified as an increasingly important input into the business models of firms in both academic literature (Krishnamurthy, 2005; Baldwin and von Hippel, 2011; Lakhani, Lifshitz-Assaf, and Tushman, 2012; Altman, Nagle, and Tushman, 2014; Greenstein and Nagle, 2014) and popular literature (Howe, 2008; Shirky, 2008). Although the productivity related value of OSS usage has not been directly investigated, there is a significant body of literature examining the impact of IT usage on productivity at both the firm and country levels. This literature has shown that the rate of return for firm investments in IT is different than that of other investments (Brynjolfsson and Hitt, 1996) and productivity boosts from investments in IT are frequently mistaken for intangible firm-specific benefits (Brynjolfsson, Hitt, and Yang, 2002; Syverson, 2011; Tambe, Hitt, and Brynjolfsson, 2011). Studies have also shown that IT-producing and using industries contributed a disproportionately large amount to the economic growth experienced in the US, particularly from 1995-2004 (Jorgenson, 2001; Jorgenson, Ho, and Stiroh, 2005). In addition to spending on IT capital, spending on IT labor has also been found to boost firm productivity (Tambe and Hitt, 2012). Further, participation in networks of practice adds IT related knowledge spillovers that increase productivity (Huang, Ceccagnoli, Forman, and Wu, 2013). However, it has been found that not all 4 The one notable exception is Lerner and Schankerman (2010), which explores the cross-country differences in demand for OSS usage. However, their analysis does not examine the returns to OSS usage and does not include the US.

firms receive the same return on IT investment (Aral and Weill, 2007) and that the returns to IT investment are not as strong as they once were (Byrne, Oliner, Sichel, 2013). An important aspect of all such studies is that they measure IT investment via dollars spent on software, hardware, labor, or a combination of the three. Since most OSS does not have a price directly associated with it, it is not properly factored in to such calculations. This mismeasurement has been shown to be on the order of billions of dollars for one piece of OSS in the US alone (Greenstein and Nagle, 2014) and such nonpecuniary production has been shown to significantly alter GDP calculations (Bridgman, 2013). In this paper, I consider how this mismeasurement may help account for the heterogeneity in firm returns to IT investment. Despite the vast literatures that exist in these two areas, there is a noticeable dearth of literature that addresses the intersection. Although some literature exists analyzing the total-cost of ownership when comparing open and closed source software (e.g., MacCormack, 2003; Russo et al, 2005; Wheeler, 2005; Fitzgerald, 2006), a consensus has not been reached and this literature does not explore the productivity implications of the two types of software, just the costs of employing it. Therefore, in this paper, I attempt to answer the open question at the intersection of these two literatures: does the consumption of OSS have an impact on the productivity of the firm? Since non-pecuniary OSS does not have a measurable price, it is likely that firms using it are underreporting the actual level of IT being employed at the firm. For example, if two firms spend $1 million on pecuniary IT, but only one also uses non-pecuniary OSS, it will appear as if they are both using the same amount of IT when in actuality they are not. Therefore, if

this additional non-pecuniary IT investment can be measured, a more accurate breakdown of the inputs into productivity can be obtained, allowing for a better understanding of the productivity implications of non-pecuniary community developed digital goods. III. Methods III.A Estimation Models I utilize a standard Cobb-Douglas production function, modified to account for the importance of IT in productivity calculations, as is common in the productivity of IT literature (Brynjolfsson and Hitt, 1996; Dewan and Min, 1997; Tambe and Hitt 2012; Tambe, Hitt, and Brynjolfsson, 2012; Huang, Ceccagnoli, Forman, and Wu, 2013): is the production of firm in time, is the amount of non-it capital stock, and is the amount of non-it labor. is the amount of IT capital stock. I substitute value-added ( for productivity to remove concerns about trends in the economy or demand shocks (Brynjolfsson and Hitt 2003) and then take the log of each side to obtain: Taking the natural log of each side results in coefficients that are equivalent to a firm s elasticity to a given input. This allows us to interpret the coefficients as the percentage change in for a one percent change in the value of the given input. This baseline model is consistent with the most current three-factor models of productivity measurement that account for IT usage (e.g., Tambe and Hitt 2012; Tambe, Hitt, and

Brynjolfsson, 2012; Huang, Ceccagnoli, Forman, and Wu, 2013). However, notably absent is the stock of free and open source software utilized by the firm. As discussed above, because this software does not have a price, it is not accounted for in standard productivity calculations. To account for this properly, I enhance this model with a measure of a firm s utilization of non-pecuniary open source software,, in a given period. Non-pecuniary OSS must be separated from pecuniary OSS because the latter is already measured by current productivity methods since it has a price. 5 I again take the natural log of this measure to allow for consistent interpretation. This results in the following equation: To control for the firm s investment in other operating system software, I also include a measure of the total number of pecuniary OSS operating systems ( as well as closed source operating systems ( at the firm in a given period. These two variables are also transformed by taking the natural log, yielding the following equation: 5 As mentioned above, an important aspect of the OSS movement is the ability to build pecuniary software on top of non-pecuniary OSS. For example, Red Hat Enterprise Linux is built on the open source Linux kernel, but is not free due to the additional functionality and support Red Hat provides. Similarly, Apple charges a pecuniary price for Mac OS X although it is built on the open source FreeBSD kernel. Conversely, a product like Mandrake Linux is both open source and non-pecuniary. Therefore, we must consider this pecuniary OSS differently than non-pecuniary OSS.

Using equation 4 as my preferred estimation equation, I will also estimate the impact of OSS usage in a binary manner. III.B Identification Strategy Like all studies of the impact of IT on productivity, my analysis is subject to both errors in the measurement of the variables, and endogeneity. The former could result in attenuation bias, underestimating the size of the effect, while the latter could lead to an overestimation of the effect if firms that use OSS tend to have higher levels of productivity but the relationship is not causal. Therefore, I employ a number of methods that help to address both of these concerns. First, since I am using panel data, I will use firm random effect models to estimate the effect at individual firms. Further, to control for unobserved time and industry trends, I add a year fixed effect and industry fixed effect at the 1-digit Standard Industrial Classification (SIC) level. The combination of these approaches helps eliminate unobserved firm, time, or industry effects that may bias the results. Second, I will employ an instrumental variable to help address both endogeneity and errors-in-variables bias. My instrument is a measure of the mean non-pecuniary OSS usage within a firm s 2-digit SIC industry within the same year. These firms face supply conditions similar to the focal firm. The amount of non-pecuniary OSS usage by the firms in a firm s same industry may affect that firm s propensity for using non-pecuniary OSS, but does not directly affect the firm s productivity level. I will use this instrument

within a framework that also employs random effects. Finally, I will utilize a matching procedure to estimate the average treatment effect of using non-pecuniary OSS using the methodology of Abadie and Imbens (2006). Although the decision to use OSS is endogenous, using a nearest-neighbor match based on all available observables allows for a quasi-experimental analysis. IV. Data My data breaks into two primary areas: OSS usage and financial statements, both of which are at the firm level. Data on which firms are using OSS comes from the Harte Hanks IT Survey a survey of IT usage by multiple sites at over 10,000 firms from 1999-2009. This database is used frequently in studies of the impact of IT on firm-level productivity (Brynjolfsson and Hitt, 2003; Forman, 2005; Forman, Goldfarb, and Greenstein, 2005; Forman, Goldfarb, and Greenstein, 2008; Tambe, Hitt, and Brynjolfsson, 2012; Huang, Ceccagnoli, Forman, and Wu, 2013, McElheran, 2013). The Harte Hanks survey asks site-level IT personnel questions about the types of IT (both hardware and software) used at the site as well as the number of IT employees at the site. In cases where Harte Hanks does not interview all sites within a firm, I take the average values for sites that are interviewed and assign this average value to sites that are not interviewed. This allows me to construct firm level values that account for all sites within the firm. I augment the Harte Hanks data with detailed firm financial data. In particular, firm

expenditures on labor (IT and non-it) and capital (IT and non-it) as well as firm revenues and costs of materials. For public firms, this information is available via Standard and Poor s Compustat database. To match the Harte Hanks data to the Compustat data, I used the firm s stock ticker symbol which is present in both datasets. In this manner, sites within the Harte Hanks database that are owned by different firms in different years (e.g., through mergers or acquisitions) will be associated with the correct parent firm and therefore the correct financial data. The sections below detail how these two datasets are used to construct the variables discussed in the previous section. For all monetary values, I convert the value to 2009 dollars using an appropriate deflation index and report the value in millions of dollars. Value-Added To construct my dependent variable, I use a method consistent with prior literature (e.g., Dewan and Min, 1997; Brynjolfsson and Hitt, 2003; Huang, Ceccagnoli, Forman, and Wu, 2013). First I take yearly operating costs (XOPR in Compustat), deflated by the BLS Producer Price Index by stage of processing for intermediate materials, supplies, and components, and subtract both deflated IT labor and non-it labor (defined below). Then I subtract this from yearly sales (SALE in Compustat), deflated by the BEA Gross Domestic Product Price Index for gross output for private industries. IT Capital Consistent with prior literature in this field (Brynjofsson and Hitt, 1996; Hitt and Brynjofsson, 1996; Dewan and Min, 1997; Huang, Ceccagnoli, Forman, and Wu 2013), I

construct a measure that includes both the value of IT hardware at the firm and three times the value of IT labor at the firm. This is a commonly used estimation of the full value of IT capital due to the importance of IT labor being used for internal software development efforts, the result of which is a capital good. To do this, I first estimate the market value of the IT stock by multiplying the number of PCs and Servers at the firm (from Harte Hanks 6 ) by the average value of a PC or Server that year from The Economist Intelligence Unit Telecommunications Database. I then deflate this by the BEA Price Index for computers and peripherals. I then calculate the value of IT labor by taking the number of IT workers at each firm (from Harte Hanks 7 ) multiplied by the mean annual wage for all Computer and Mathematical Science Occupations 8. I deflate the result by the BLS Employment Cost Index for wages and salaries for private industry workers. I multiply the result by three and add the PC and Server value above to obtain the aggregate measure. Non-IT Capital To construct the variable, I take the yearly Gross Total Property, Plant and Equipment 6 For most firms, Harte Hanks only surveys a sample of the sites within the firm. In such cases, I calculate the average number of PCs and Servers at the sites that are in the survey, and then multiply by the total number of sites in the firm to obtain the total number of PCs and Servers in the firm. I use the same procedure for calculating the number of IT employees and the number of each type of operating system at the firm. 7 Harte Hanks reports the number of IT employees at each site as a range so I take the average value of the range. The ranges are 1-4, 5-9, 10-24, 25-49, 50-99, 100-249, 250-499, and 500 or More. 8 Obtained from the Bureau of Labor and Statistics: http://www.bls.gov/oes/2009/may/oes_nat.htm#15-0000.

(PPEGT in Compustat), deflated by the BLS price index for Detailed Capital Measures for All Assets for the Private Non-Farm Business Sector, and subtract the deflated value of IT Capital (defined above). Non-IT Labor I take the total number of employees at the firm (EMP in Compustat) and subtract the number of IT employees (from Harte Hanks) to obtain the total number of non-it employees. I then multiply this by the mean annual wage of all occupations 9 that year. I deflate the result by the BLS Employment Cost Index for wages and salaries for private industry workers. This method of calculation is consistent with prior studies on IT productivity (Bloom and Van Reenen, 2007; Bresnahan, Brynjolfsson, and Hitt, 2002; Brynjolfsson and Hitt 2003). Operating Systems Measures I construct these three measures ( and ) by calculating the total number of each type of operating system at the firm (from Harte Hanks). The Harte Hanks data does not report the precise number of operating systems in use at a given firm. It does, however, report the different types of operating systems used at each site. I classify these operating systems into three categories, non-pecuniary OSS, pecuniary OSS, or closed source. Further, Harte Hanks reports whether each operating system is for a PC or a server as well as the total number of PCs and servers at each site. Therefore, for each site, I assume an even split of the 9 Obtained from the Bureau of Labor and Statistics, for example the data for 2009 can be found here: http://www.bls.gov/oes/2009/may/oes_nat.htm#00-0000.

number of PC operating systems over the total number of PCs at the site. I do the same for servers. This yields an estimate of how many instances of a given type of operating system exist at the site. I then aggregate this to the firm level and divide by the number of sites at the firm in the Harte Hanks database to obtain an average per site. Finally, I multiply this by the total number of sites in the firm to obtain a firm-wide estimate of the number of each type of operating system. As the resulting numbers are estimates, I will begin my analysis by only using a binary indicator of the presence of each type of operating system. The estimated number of operating systems will then allow for a more granular interpretation of the primary effect. Because the number of operating systems in any of the three categories can potentially be zero (e.g., that category of operating system is not in use at the firm), I add one to the number of operating systems in each category before taking the natural log as the natural log of zero is undefined. Although there are many firms that have zero non-pecuniary and pecuniary OSS operating systems, there is a high degree of skewness in these numbers (as shown in the descriptive statistics below). Therefore, adding a one before taking the natural log should not significantly bias the results. Table 1 shows the descriptive statistics of the firms in my dataset. There are 13,828 firm/year observations in the dataset. The ranges vary greatly for all variables and demonstrate the breadth of the firms in the sample. This breadth allows for results that are more generalizable than many other studies of this kind, which only focus on Fortune 1000 companies. The firms in the dataset also have a wide range of the type and intensity

of IT use. The mean number of closed source operating systems at a firm is 4714.99 while the mean number of non-pecuniary OSS and pecuniary OSS operating systems are much lower at 164.16 and 160.50, respectively. Table 2 shows the correlation matrix and Table 3 shows the breakdown by industry. ------------------- Insert Tables 1, 2, & 3 Here ------------------- V. Results Three-Factor Productivity Analysis Before delving into the results on open source usage, I first present the results of the baseline regression, equation 2, to compare the elasticities of the three main productivity inputs with other existing studies. Table 4 shows the results of my basic three-factor productivity analysis. Models 1-3 use Ordinary Least Squares (OLS) regression with increasingly restrictive fixed effects, while Model 4 uses panel regression with firm fixed effects and Model 5 uses panel regression with random effects. For all models, the standard errors are robust and clustered by firm. The high R 2 values are characteristic of such productivity studies. The confidence intervals of the coefficients in models 4 and 5 overlap with those of Huang, Ceccagnoli, Forman, and Wu (2013), whose methodology this study most closely resembles. However, my coefficients on non-it capital are slightly higher than theirs, likely because their sample size is only companies in the Fortune 1000, while I cast a wider net. However, as a robustness check I will later split the sample and analyze Fortune 1000 firms separately to confirm this is not skewing my results. Further, the model 4 coefficient on IT capital is very similar to that of

Brynjolfsson and Hitt (2003) in their 1-year difference model with year and industry controls. The coefficients for model 4 are also very similar to the fixed effect estimate of Tambe and Hitt (2012), although the IT capital coefficient is slightly lower, likely because they are calculating their coefficient based solely on IT labor. These similarities help to add support to the validity of my dataset. ------------------- Insert Table 4 Here ------------------- Binary Usage of Non-Pecuniary OSS Table 5 presents my estimation results using a binary measure of OSS usage. Columns 1, 2, and 5 show the results of estimating equation 3, which does not include the controls for other types of operating systems. Columns 3, 4, and 6 show the result of estimating equation 4, which includes these controls. Although columns 1-4 show a slight positive coefficient for, the coefficients are not significant. As the rest of my analysis shows, in all models using instrumental variables, this coefficient is significant, implying there may be an attenuation bias resulting in an underestimate of these coefficients in the basic panel models. Columns 5 and 6 show the results from the random effect estimation with the same industry non-pecuniary OSS instrument. Both models show a positive and significant coefficient for. Additionally, both models have a first stage F-statistic much greater than 10, adding validity to the relevance of my instrument. The coefficients in these two models are nearly identical, indicating that the variable is not just identifying firms who invest in more IT (operating systems), but that the effect is due to

the adoption of non-pecuniary OSS. Since the dependent variable is a natural log, we can interpret the coefficient on to indicate that firms who use non-pecuniary OSS have a 1.03% increase in productivity (as measured by value-added). ------------------- Insert Table 5 Here ------------------- Continuous Usage of Non-Pecuniary OSS Table 6 presents my estimation results using a continuous measure of OSS usage. As in Table 5, columns 1, 2, and 5 show the results of estimating equation 3, which does not include the controls for other types of operating systems and columns 3, 4, and 6 show the result of estimating equation 4, which includes these controls. Again, columns 1-4 show a slight positive coefficient for the continuous measure of, but the coefficients are not significant. However, columns 5 and 6 show the results from the random effect estimation with the same industry non-pecuniary OSS instrument, which shows a positive and significant coefficient for. Again, both models have a first stage F-statistic much greater than 10, adding validity to the relevance of my instrument. As with the binary analysis, the coefficients in these two models are nearly identical, indicating that the variable is not just identifying firms who invest in more IT (operating systems), but that the effect is due to the usage of non-pecuniary OSS. Since the estimation is a log-log specification, we can interpret the coefficient on to mean that a 1% increase in the amount of non-pecuniary OSS a firm uses leads to a.15% increase in productivity (as measured by value-added). By comparison, this represents a little more than half the

elasticity for non-it capital. The reduction of the coefficient on IT Capital to the point where it is either not significant or negative is symptomatic of such studies (Huang, Ceccagnoli, Forman, and Wu, 2013). ------------------- Insert Table 6 Here ------------------- Split-Sample Analysis To further explore the results, I use my preferred specification (model 6 from Table 6) to calculate various split-sample results. Table 7 shows the results of this analysis. In column 1, I examine the continuous effect on only firms who are users of either nonpecuniary or pecuniary OSS. In column 2, I look at only firms that use non-pecuniary OSS. In both cases, the coefficient on is higher than in the full sample, however the confidence intervals all overlap. Column 3 only uses firms that were in the Fortune 1000 at least one year from 1999-2009. The coefficient on is slightly larger, but statistically not different than that when using the full sample. This allows me to further confirm that my results are consistent with prior literature (Brynjolfsson and Hitt, 2003; Tambe and Hitt, 2012; Huang, Ceccagnoli, Forman, and Wu, 2013), and are not driven by differences in the makeup of my sample. However, the results in column 4 show a slightly different story for firms that are not in the Fortune 1000. These firms are generally smaller than the Fortune 1000 firms, and we see that these smaller firms obtain a benefit to using non-

pecuniary OSS that is statistically lower. Finally, in column 5, I exclude finance companies from my sample because they frequently report capital expenditures in a fundamentally different way than other firms. The resulting coefficient for is nearly identical to that in the full sample, indicating that this irregularity does not affect my results. ------------------- Insert Table 7 Here ------------------- Average Treatment Effect of Non-Pecuniary OSS Usage Finally, I also utilized a matching procedure to estimate the average treatment effect of using OSS by employing the methodology of Abadie and Imbens (2006). While the decision to use OSS is not exogenous, matching allows for quasi-experimental analysis. Using a nearest-neighbor match based on all observables used in the prior regressions, I construct a matched sample based on the binary use of non-pecuniary OSS. I then use this matched sample to estimate the sample average treatment effect (SATE) at.181 with a standard error of.031. This positive and statistically significant coefficient again offers support for the validity of my primary results. VI. Discussion and Conclusion My results show that the consumption of non-pecuniary OSS does indeed have an impact on the productivity of the firm, and that this impact is positive. Although this result did not appear significant in the basic panel regression, it is consistently significant in all specifications that account for endogeneity and errors-in-variables via instrumental

variable analysis and a quasi-experimental approach via the Abadie and Imbens nearestneighbor match. The effect stays consistent in sub-sample analyses of OSS adopters, Fortune 1000 firms, and non-finance firms. I also show that this effect exists when considering the use of non-pecuniary OSS at a binary level. Interestingly, a slight negative return to the usage of closed source software appeared in several of the estimation models. However, this effect was not consistent throughout the more rigorous models. Likewise, the effect of pecuniary OSS was not stable throughout the various analyses. As these two variables were only used as controls, it is difficult to make a general statement about their specific effect on productivity. Although endogeneity is always a concern in productivity studies, I take many steps to help rule out this bias and allow for a causal statement. All of the primary regression results (Tables 5 and 6) use panel regression techniques with random effects as well as fixed effects for year. This helps to rule out alternative explanations due to trends over time so that I am comparing a firm with itself over time. The use of an instrumental variable allows for a proper identification of the effect within this panel framework. Further, the results of the various estimations of equation 4, which includes the number of pecuniary OSS and closed source operating systems, allow us to rule out the concern that a firm s level of technology usage causes them to adopt non-pecuniary OSS and to have a higher value-add, rather than the use of the non-pecuniary OSS itself causing the increase in value-add. Finally, I use Abadie and Imbens nearest-neighbor match, to further reduce concerns about endogeneity. With this statistically rigorous matching method, the

primary finding of a positive causal effect of non-pecuniary OSS usage on productivity holds. My findings have important implications for researchers, practitioners, and policy makers. For researchers, my results draw additional attention to the mismeasurement that occurs when firms use OSS (and, more generally, non-pecuniary crowdsourced digital goods) as inputs into production. Future studies of productivity, especially the productivity of IT, should account for these non-pecuniary inputs, rather than lumping them into firm intangible effects. This is especially important as information costs are approaching zero and the amount of non-pecuniary digital inputs firms use is likely to rise in the coming years. For practitioners, my results indicate that firms of all sizes may enhance their productivity by increasing the amount of OSS they employ in their production process. For policy makers, my results indicate that federal funding of OSS and other publicly available digital goods could enhance the productivity of firms. While other studies have shown that federal investment in such goods can have a high rate of return based on the value of the goods themselves, my results indicate that such goods can also boost the productivity of the firms that use them.

Tables Table 1: Descriptive Statistics Variable Obs Mean Std. Dev. Min Max 13828 1743.38 5249.90.006 154608 13828 61.67 158.40.001 4585.59 13828 4006.40 14244.94.101 305797.1 13828 820.01 2738.48.028 91149.09 13828 164.16 1192.55 0 65690 13828 160.50 2807.66 0 207646 13828 4714.99 17365.42 0 1176977 Table 2: Correlation Matrix Table 3: Industry Breakdown Description Agriculture, Forestry, and Fishing Mining and Construction Manufacturing Manufacturing Transportation, Communications, Electric, Gas, and Sanitary Services Wholesale and Retail Trade Finance, Insurance, and Real Estate Services Services 9 Public Administration 0 0 Total 13,828 100

Table 4: Baseline Regression Results DV: Value-Added 1 2 3 4 5 Model OLS OLS OLS FE RE IT Capital.072*** (.006).040*** (.006).032*** (.006).015*** (.005).019*** (.005) Non-IT Capital.320*** (.012).317*** (.012).304*** (.012).108*** (.034).269*** (.013) Non-IT Labor.646***.665***.684***.758***.716*** (.014) (.014) (.015) (.032) (.016) Constant.278*** (.040).091** (.045).127 (.160).980*** (.162).219** (.086) Year fixed effect? N Y Y Y Y Industry fixed effect (SIC2) N N Y Y Y Number of firm/year observations 13828 13828 13828 13828 13828 Number of firms (groups) 1964 1964 1964 1964 1964 R^2 (between for panel) 0.897 0.911 0.915 0.912 0.930 ***p<.01, **p<.05, *p<.1. All standard errors are clustered at the firm level. All variables are the natural log of the underlying variable. Table 5: Binary OSS Regression Results DV: Value-Added 1 2 3 4 5 6 Model RE RE RE RE RE RE IT Capital.019*** (.005).018*** (.005).025*** (.005).024*** (.005) -.028** (.011) -.026** (.011) Non-IT Capital.276*** (.013).269*** (.013).278*** (.013).270*** (.013).288*** (.008).291*** (.007) Non-IT Labor.707*** (.016).716*** (.016).710*** (.016).718*** (.016).677*** (.008).678*** (.009).006 (.013).008 (.013).005 (.013) -.003 (.003) -.012* (.007) Constant.167***.220***.220*** (.051) (.086) (.057).007 (.013) -.003 (.003) -.012* (.008).273*** (.088) 1.036*** (.201).618*** (.065) 1.034*** (.197) -.002 (.003) -.006 (.008).638*** (.074) Year fixed effect? Y Y Y Y Y Y Industry fixed effect? N Y N Y N N Instrument (for N/A N/A N/A N/A Y Y ) Number of firm/year 13828 13828 13828 13828 13828 13828 observations Number of firms (groups) 1964 1964 1964 1964 1964 1964 First Stage F-test - - - - 70.91 74.62 R^2 (between) 0.926 0.930 0.926 0.930 0.908 0.908 ***p<.01, **p<.05, *p<.1. Standard errors are clustered at the firm level for models 1-4, and conventional GLS for models 5-6. All variables are the natural log of the underlying variable.

Table 6: Continuous OSS Regression Results DV: Value-Added 1 2 3 4 5 6 Model RE RE RE RE RE RE IT Capital.020*** (.005).018*** (.005).025*** (.005).024*** (.006) -.016* (.008) -.015 (.009) Non-IT Capital.276*** (.013).269*** (.013).277*** (.013).270*** (.013).276*** (.008).279*** (.008) Non-IT Labor.707*** (.016).716*** (.016).710*** (.016).718*** (.016).687*** (.009).686*** (.009).001 (.003).001 (.003).0003 (.003) -.003 (.003) -.012* (.007) Constant.167***.221*** 1.220*** (.051) (.086) (.057).001 (.003) -.003 (.003) -.012* (.007).274*** (.088).150*** (.029).618*** (.061).155*** (.030).008* (.004) -.006 (.007).641*** (.067) Year fixed effect? Y Y Y Y Y Y Industry fixed effect? N Y N Y N N Instrument (for N/A N/A N/A N/A Y Y ) Number of firm/year 13828 13828 13828 13828 13828 13828 observations Number of firms (groups) 1964 1964 1964 1964 1964 1964 First Stage F-test - - - - 112.00 107.58 R^2 (between) 0.926 0.930 0.926 0.930 0.918 0.917 ***p<.01, **p<.05, *p<.1. Standard errors are clustered at the firm level for models 1-4, and conventional GLS for models 5-6. All variables are the natural log of the underlying variable.

Table 7: Split-Sample Regression Results DV: Value-Added 1 2 3 4 5 Model RE RE RE RE RE IT Capital.008 (.014) -.002 (.015) -.053*** (.014).029*** (.008) -.018* (.009) Non-IT Capital.317*** (.007).318*** (.009).279*** (.012).231*** (.011).274*** (.009) Non-IT Labor.627*** (.010).644*** (.012).595*** (.013).739*** (.012).701*** (.010).171*** (.031).039*** (008) -.037** (.015) Constant.623*** (.083) Instrument (for ) Sample restriction (e.g. OSS adopters only, large companies, etc.).194*** (.037) -.011* (.007) -.042** (.018).126 (.109).194*** (.040) -.001 (.004) -.002 (.013) 1.461*** (.183).057** (.027).006 (.005) -.031*** (.009).588*** (.061) Y Y Y Y Y Either OSS adopters Nonpecuniary OSS Adopter Fortune 1000 Not Fortune 1000.158*** (.030).010*** (.004) -.013* (.007).606*** (.069) Exclude Finance Year fixed effect? Y Y Y Y Y Number of firm/year 5120 3739 6930 6896 12282 observations Number of firms (groups) 1094 969 821 1143 1809 First Stage F-Test 104.76 94.04 59.19 145.53 104.66 R^2 (between) 0.908 0.894 0.818 0.884 0.924 ***p<.01, **p<.05, *p<.1. Standard errors are conventional GLS for all models. All variables are the natural log of the underlying variable.

References Abadie, A., & Imbens, G. W. (2006). Large sample properties of matching estimators for average treatment effects. Econometrica, 74(1), 235-267. Altman, E., Nagle, F., & Tushman, M. (2014). Innovating without Information Constraints: Organizations, Communities, and Innovation When Information Costs Approach Zero. Harvard Business School Working Paper. Aral, S., & Weill, P. (2007). IT assets, organizational capabilities, and firm performance: How resource allocations and organizational differences explain performance variation. Organization Science, 18(5), 763-780. Baldwin, C., & Von Hippel, E. (2011). Modeling a Paradigm Shift: From Producer Innovation to User and Open Collaborative Innovation. Organization Science, 22(6), 1399 1417. Bloom, N. & J. Van Reenen. (2007). Measuring and explaining management practices across firms and countries. Quarterly Journal of Economics. 122(4) 1351-1408. Bresnahan, T.F., E. Brynjolfsson, & L.M. Hitt. (2002). Information technology, workplace organization, and the demand for skilled labor: Firm-level evidence. Quarterly Journal of Economics. 117(1) 339-376. Bridgman, B. (2013). Home Productivity. Bureau of Economic Analysis Working Paper 2013-03. Brynjolfsson, E., & Hitt, L. (1996). Paradox lost? Firm-level evidence on the returns to information systems spending. Management science, 42(4), 541-558. Brynjolfsson, E., & Hitt, L. M. (2003). Computing productivity: Firm-level evidence. Review of economics and statistics, 85(4), 793-808. Brynjolfsson, E., Hitt, L. M., & Yang, S. (2002). Intangible assets: Computers and organizational capital. Brookings papers on economic activity, 2002(1), 137-198. Byrne, D., Oliner, S., & Sichel, D. (2013). Is the information technology revolution over? Available at SSRN 2240961. Casadesus-Masanell, R., & Llanes, G. (2011). Mixed Source. Management Science, 57(7), 1212 1230. Dewan, S., & Min, C. K. (1997). The substitution of information technology for other factors of production: A firm level analysis. Management Science, 43(12), 1660-1675. Forman, C. (2005). The corporate digital divide: Determinants of Internet adoption. Management Science, 51(4), 641-654. Forman, C., Goldfarb, A., & Greenstein, S. (2005). How did location affect adoption of the commercial Internet? Global village vs. urban leadership. Journal of Urban Economics, 58(3), 389-420. Forman, C., Goldfarb, A., & Greenstein, S. (2008). Understanding the inputs into innovation: Do cities substitute for internal firm resources?. Journal of Economics & Management Strategy, 17(2), 295-316. Fitzgerald, B. (2006). The transformation of open source software. Mis Quarterly, 587-598. Greenstein, S., & Nagle, F. (2014). Digital Dark Matter and the Economic Contribution of Apache. National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper 19507. Forthcoming in Research Policy. Harhoff, D., Henkel, J., & Von Hippel, E. (2003). Profiting from voluntary information spillovers: how users benefit by freely revealing their innovations. Research Policy, 32(10), 1753-1769. Hitt, L. M., & Brynjolfsson, E. (1996). Productivity, business profitability, and consumer surplus: three different measures of information technology value. MIS Quarterly, 121-142. Howe, J. 2008. Crowdsourcing: Why the Power of the Crowd is Driving the Future of Business. Crown Business, New York. Henkel, J. (2006). Selective revealing in open innovation processes: The case of embedded Linux. Research policy, 35(7), 953-969.

Huang, P., Ceccagnoli, M., Forman, C., & Wu, D. J. (2013). IT Knowledge Spillovers and Productivity: Evidence from Enterprise Software. Available at SSRN 2243886. Jorgenson, D. W. (2001). Information technology and the US economy. The American Economic Review, 91(1), 1-32. Jorgenson, D. W., Ho, M. S., & Stiroh, K. J. (2005). Productivity, Volume 3: Information Technology and the American Growth Resurgence. MIT Press Books, 3. Krishnamurthy, S. (2005). "An Analysis of Open Source Business Models," in Perspectives on Free and Open Source Software, J. Feller, B. Fitzgerald, S. Hissam, and K. Lakhani (eds.), MIT Press, Cambridge, MA, 2005, pp. 279-296. Lakhani, K., & Von Hippel, E. (2003). How open source software works: free user-to-user assistance. Research Policy, 32(6), 923 943. Lakhani, K., Lifshitz-Assaf, H., & Tushman, M. (2012). Open innovation and organizational boundaries: the impact of task decomposition and knowledge distribution on the locus of innovation in Handbook of Economic Organization: Integrating Economic and Organization Theory, A. Grandori (ed.), Edward Elgar Publishing, Northampton, MA, pp. 355-382. Lerner, J., & Schaknerman, M. (2010). The comingled code: Open source and economic development. MIT Press Books, 1. Lerner, J., & Tirole, J. (2002). Some Simple Economics of Open Source. The Journal of Industrial Economics, 50(2), 197 234. MacCormack, A. (2003). Evaluating Total Cost of Ownership for Software Platforms: Comparing Apples, Oranges, and Cucumbers. AEI-Brookings Joint Center for Regulatory Studies Related Publication, April 2003. McElheran, K. S. (2013). Delegation in Multi-Establishment Firms: Adaptation vs. Coordination in I.T. Purchasing Authority. Journal of Economics & Management Strategy, forthcoming. O Mahony, S. (2003). Guarding the commons: how community managed software projects protect their work. Research Policy, 32(7), 1179 1198. Raymond, Eric. (1998). Goodbye, free software ; hello, open source. Retrieved from http://www.catb.org/~esr/open-source.html on February 23, 2014. Russo, B., Braghin, B., Gasperi, P., Sillitti, A., and Succi, G. (2005). Defining TCO for the Transition to Open Source Systems. Proceedings of the First International Conference on Open Source (OSS2005), pp. 108-112. Schumpeter, Joseph. 1942. The Process of Creative Destruction. Chapter VII, pp. 81-86 in Capitalism, Socialism, and Democracy. New York, NY: Harper & Row. Shirky, C. Here Comes Everybody: The Power of Organizing Without Organizations. Penguin Press, New York. Syverson, C. (2011). What Determines Productivity? Journal of Economic Literature, 49(2), pp. 326-365. Tambe, P., & Hitt, L. M. (2012). The Productivity of Information Technology Investments : New Evidence from IT Labor Data. Information Systems Research, 23(3), 599 617. Tambe, P., Hitt, L., & Brynjolfsson, E. (2011). The Price and Quantity of IT-Related Intangible Capital. Working paper. Tambe, P., Hitt, L. M., & Brynjolfsson, E. (2012). The Extroverted Firm: How External Information Practices Affect Innovation and Productivity. Management Science, 58(5), 843 859. Von Hippel, E. (1986). Lead Users: A Source of Novel Product Concepts. Management Science, 32(7), 791 805. Von Hippel, E., & Von Krogh, G. (2003). Open source software and the private-collective innovation model: Issues for organization science. Organization science, 14(2), 209-223. Von Krogh, G., Spaeth, S., & Lakhani, K. R. (2003). Community, joining, and specialization in open source software innovation: a case study. Research Policy, 32(7), 1217 1241.