THE INFLUENCE OF THE ENERGY SPOT MARKET ON ON-THE-MICROGRID-MARKETS COMPLETE RESEARCH



Similar documents
How To Integrate Renewable Energy With Smart Grids

ESRI Research Note. The Irish Electricity Market: New Regulation to Preserve Competition Valeria di Cosmo and Muireann Á. Lynch

Transactive Energy. A Sustainable Business and Regulatory Model for Electricity. Arizona Corporation Commission

Transactive Energy. A Sustainable Business and Regulatory Model for Electricity. Ed Cazalet SPRING 2014 MEMBERS MEETING MAY 5-8, 2014 DENVER, COLORADO

Demand Response Management System ABB Smart Grid solution for demand response programs, distributed energy management and commercial operations

ENERGY ADVISORY COMMITTEE. Electricity Market Review : Electricity Tariff

Renewable Electricity and Liberalised Markets REALM. JOULE-III Project JOR3-CT GREECE ACTION PLAN. By ICCS / NTUA K. Delkis

The business model of MICRO POWER ECONOMY DIRECTORY. INENSUS GmbH The business model

DESIGN FOR MONITORING AND OPTIMIZATION OF POWER DEMAND FOR WIRELESSLY COMMUNICATING ELECTRIC LOADS

D 6.4 and D7.4 Draft topics of EEGI Implementation Plan Revision: Definitive

SmartGrids SRA Summary of Priorities for SmartGrids Research Topics

While there has been a lot of discussion

Wind Turbine Manufacturers. Renewables Advocates. Retail Customers. Wind Project Generators. Gas, Nuclear and other Generators. Electric Utilities

METER DATA MANAGEMENT FOR THE SMARTER GRID AND FUTURE ELECTRONIC ENERGY MARKETPLACES

Unlocking Electricity Prices:

CERTS Microgrid Research and Lessons Learned

Integrating the customer experience through unifying software - The Microsoft Vision

Power Trading and Retail System. empowering. smarter trading. across the energy value chain. Smart energy. Powering progress

The UK Electricity Market Reform and the Capacity Market

Becoming an Electricity Retailer

THE STRUCTURE OF AN ELECTRICITY MARKET

Measurement and Mitigation of Market Power in Wholesale Electricity Markets

Preparatory Paper on Focal Areas to Support a Sustainable Energy System in the Electricity Sector

Study to Determine the Limit of Integrating Intermittent Renewable (wind and solar) Resources onto Pakistan's National Grid

Enabling 24/7 Automated Demand Response and the Smart Grid using Dynamic Forward Price Offers

A Method for Assessing Relative Value of Central Generation and Distributed Energy Resources (DERs) in Distribution Feeders

Finnish Energy Industries draft answer to CEER public consultation The future role of DSOs

Georgia Tech ARPA-E: Energy Internet

Value of Distributed Generation

Pricing in a Competitive Market with a Common Network Resource

How To Mitigate Market Power

Value of Distributed Generation

Tufts Consulting Group: Macedonian Energy

ESDER Implementation and TeMix Comments

Electric Utility Business Models

Distributed Energy Resource Options and The Importance of The Electric Power Grid

TAMPA ELECTRIC COMPANY UNDOCKETED: SOLAR ENERGY IN FLORIDA STAFF S REQUEST FOR COMMENTS INTRODUCTION PAGE 1 OF 1 FILED: JUNE 23, 2015.

Measuring Unilateral Market Power in Wholesale Electricity Markets: The California Market,

Wind Power and District Heating

Main variations of business models for Flexible Industrial Demand combined with Variable Renewable Energy

TARIFF AND GOVERNANCE ASSESSMENT

RENEWABLE SELF- CONSUMPTION. Cheap and clean power at your doorstep

Eco Bairros demonstration project:

DSM in competitive market. Seppo Kärkkäinen, VTT, Finland TAIEX Workshop on Demand Side Management in Energy Efficiency Ankara /11/2007

3 Price Discrimination

Anthony Price Swanbarton Limited, Dairy Farm, Pinkney, Malmesbury, Wiltshire, SN16 0NX Telephone

LADWP GREEN POWER PROGRAM

About us The Challenge Younicos Technology Our Services Business Segments & Projects. Page 3

June Position Paper Contribution to the debate on electricity market design and capacity markets

To assist you with getting started with the SRECs program, find enclosed a copy of the following:

European Distribution System Operators for Smart Grids

Value of storage in providing balancing services for electricity generation systems with high wind penetration

A new electricity market for Northern Ireland and Ireland from Integrated Single Electricity Market (I-SEM)

Different types of electricity markets modelled using PLEXOS Integrated Energy Model The UK Balancing Market example

Full Scale Program for Renewable Energy in Egypt

November Background

Preparing for Distributed Energy Resources

Ubiquitous Computing in Business Processes Part V

BRIEFING NOTE POSITION OF DEMAND RESPONSE PROGRAMS IN THE

How To Develop A Smart Grid In Danesland

Perspectives for ESS in Germany and Europe legal situation and applications StoREgio energy storage system association

LP-based Mathematical Model for Optimal Microgrid Operation Considering Heat Trade with District Heat System

Power Generation Industry Economic Dispatch Optimization (EDO)

Droop Control Forhybrid Micro grids With Wind Energy Source

Anita Rønne. Análisis del marco normativo de las redes inteligentes en Europa The European legal framework for smart grids

THE GREEN ELECTRCITY MARKET IN DENMARK: QUOTAS, CERTIFICATES AND INTERNATIONAL TRADE. Ole Odgaard Denmark

Electricity settlement reform moving to halfhourly

Fuel cell microchp: Greener and cheaper energy for all

How To Price Bundle On Cable Television

Siemens Hybrid Power Solutions. Cost and emission reduction by integrating renewables into diesel plants

Hybrid Renewable Energy Systems for North-Eastern Poland

CALIFORNIA ISO. Pre-dispatch and Scheduling of RMR Energy in the Day Ahead Market

NERA Analysis of Energy Supplier Margins

Taking Advantage of Lower Electric Rates for your Government Agency

Demand Response Management System Smart systems for Consumer engagement By Vikram Gandotra Siemens Smart Grid

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

STEADYSUN THEnergy white paper. Energy Generation Forecasting in Solar-Diesel-Hybrid Applications

Annex B: Strike price methodology July 2013

ELECTRICITY SECTOR 1

Committee on the Northern Territory s Energy Future. Electricity Pricing Options. Submission from Power and Water Corporation

Proposals for the electricity market from competition policy (Summary)

Renewable Energy Management System (REMS): Using optimisation to plan renewable energy infrastructure investment in the Pacific

High Natural Gas Prices and the Updated Market For CHP

Enhancing the market potential of distributed energy systems

CAPACITY MECHANISMS IN EU POWER MARKETS

Chapter 5 Pricing Foundations and Implications on Web Service Pricing

Kevin Spears Electricity Regulation and Rate Structures ECO 300

4. Comparison with DECC (2014) Estimated impacts of energy and climate change policies on energy prices and bills

Development of a Conceptual Reference Model for Micro Energy Grid

2. Executive Summary. Emissions Trading Systems in Europe and Elsewhere

look A closer Have you ever wanted to look into what makes up electricity prices and find out how the electricity market works? at electricity prices

ESC Project: INMES Integrated model of the energy system

FORTNIGHTLY. Reliability Standards. PLUS A Role for Coal Falling Demand New York s Distributed Future

In Maryland, competitive energy suppliers are licensed by the Maryland Public Service Commission (MD-PSC) to market electricity to customers.

Energy Storage Systems. New solutions for a new energy environment

DANISH DISTRICT ENERGY PLANNING EXPERIENCE

Glossary of Terms Avoided Cost - Backfeed - Backup Generator - Backup Power - Base Rate or Fixed Charge Baseload Generation (Baseload Plant) -

Energy Management in the Greek Islands

Authors: Sophia Ruester, Xian He, Jorge Vasconcelos, and Jean-Michel Glachant Editor: Annika Zorn

Renewable and Alternative Energy Outlook

Transcription:

THE INFLUENCE OF THE ENERGY SPOT MARKET ON ON-THE-MICROGRID-MARKETS COMPLETE RESEARCH Verena Dorner Gilbert Fridgen Rebecca Trick Institute of Information Systems and Marketing (IISM) Karlsruhe Institute of Technology (KIT)) Research Center Finance & Information Management (FIM) University of Bayreuth Research Center Finance & Information Management (FIM) University of Bayreuth verena.dorner@kit.edu gilbert.fridgen@fim-rc.de rebecca.trick@fim-rc.de Abstract With the transition towards distributed energy resources (DER) for electricity generation, new applications for information systems arise in enabling the development of innovative business models for grid control and operation. IS enables the merging of DERs and energy consumers into microgrids. Microgrids increase efficiency, e.g. through shorter transmission distances. Cost-savings due to these efficiency gains can be distributed among microgrid-participants via an on-the-microgrid-market platform. However, due to differences in the power plant parks and fluctuations in renewable energy generation, energy prices on the on-the-microgrid-market (OMM) are likely to differ from energy prices on the spot market. Based on the varying prices in both markets, the supply- or the demand-side of the OMM may from time-to-time, prefer to trade on the spot market, which could cause the OMM to stop functioning. We develop an economic model to analyse the conditions, under which OMMs are a viable concept for energy trading. Our results indicate that OMMs can indeed function in competitive energy markets. 1 Motivation The increasing deployment of intermittent resources, such as sun and wind is burdened with high costs and poses considerable challenges for power system reliability (Annual Energy Outlook, 2013). Applying intelligent information systems (IS) to these challenges appears promising (Depuru, Wang, Devabhaktuni, & Gudi, 2011). Especially since IS enable the merging of loads and distributed energy resources (DER) into local microgrids (Piagi & Lasseter, 2006). A microgrid is a single controllable entity of the main grid that can also disconnect and work in stand-alone mode. Its compact scale allows for various benefits such as better grid management and fewer costs for energy transmission (Bertolini, Giacomini, Grillo, Massucco, & Silvestro, 2010). Large utility consumers already deploy microgrids in practice, e.g. ports (Burns & McDonnell Engineering Company, Inc., 2014) or local energy cooperatives (Ohio University Compass, 2013). In most microgrids, suppliers only provide energy to consumers. Yet, with adequate IS, generators and loads could also trade automatically with each other on an on-themicrogrid-market platform. Considering fewer maintenance costs within microgrids, 1

an on-the-microgrid-market (OMM) could allow suppliers to sell at prices higher than the prices at wholesale level and end consumers could buy at prices lower than the retail level (Schwaegerl & Tao, 2014, p. 276). As such, the concept of OMM would be economically attractive for both market sides. Yet, one aspect has been largely neglected so far. The power plant park of a microgrid is typically less diverse and has a higher share of intermittent resources than the power plant park of the energy spot market. Trade on an OMM will only thrive if participants are not trading at a disadvantage. In other words, an OMM s long-term success depends on whether participants are able to trade at least at the same prices and quantities as on the spot market. The rationale behind this assumption is simply that suppliers will stop trading on the OMM if they are able to realize greater profits on the spot market and that consumers will stop trading if they incur lower costs. This would lead to a failure of the OMM. In our definition, a closed OMM prohibits trade with the spot market and balances residual energy and loads with storage devices. In contrast, an open OMM exchanges residual loads and energy on the spot market and suppliers and consumers are free to choose between trading on the spot market or on the OMM 1. Given an open OMM, spot market prices are likely to affect OMM prices. The objective of this paper is analyzing whether attractive prices, for both suppliers and consumers, can form on an open OMM under these conditions. Hence, our research question is: Under which conditions, if any, are open OMMs a viable concept for energy trading? To answer our question, we develop an economic model and evaluate the influence of energy exchange between the OMM and the energy spot market on OMM prices. We analyze the full range of scenarios that can occur, i.e. in a closed OMM, prices can be lower than, higher than or equal to spot market prices at any point in time. 1 Current regulations in many countries ban consumers and small suppliers from trading directly on the spot market. Instead, they contract with utilities via the retail market. Our work is based on the view that regulatory frameworks are subject to change; indeed, current debates about the utility status of microgrids in many countries make it appear probable that fundamental changes are imminent (Costa, Matos, & Lopes, 2008). We therefore abstracted from current regulatory frameworks. This arguably reduces the direct applicability of our model to specific real-world energy markets, but we feel that this is outweighed by its generalizability and flexibility in modelling. 2

2 Model For a start, we developed a base model of the OMM, consisting of the following six assumptions: A1 A2 A3 A4 A5 A6 The supply-function of the OMM is continuous, twice differentiable, strictly increasing and convex Aggregate demand in the OMM is given We assume perfect competition between suppliers in the OMM, so that the aggregate- supply-function is determined by the generators marginal production costs (merit-order function) We assume that suppliers are generally capable of generating at least enough energy to supply aggregate demand in the OMM. For simplicity, we abstract from grid bottlenecks and other physical constraints, which influence market prices and trade between the microgrid and the spot market For simplicity, we assume that there are only two alternatives for trade, either the spot market or the OMM. Trading on the spot market causes transaction costs to the customer c > 0 We define the following prices and costs (prices and costs are per unit, e.g. /kwh): P OMM P P S (P S + c ) Market price in a fictively closed OMM Market price, which forms on an open OMM through interaction between the OMM and the spot market Spot market price / price OMM-suppliers get, if they sell on the spot market Spot market purchasing price / price OMM-consumer have to pay, if they purchase energy on the spot market 3

Figure 1 shows our base model. Figure 1: The base model of the OMM In line with common practice in modelling energy markets, we model suppliers in the OMM to be uniformly paid, according to the price-setting unit in the OMM (1). Our analysis adopts a cost-based perspective, abstracting the model from current regulatory frameworks and market distortions such as negative prices. 4

3 Model Application In our analysis, we assess which market price P would form, given P OMM and P S. Scenario I: P OMM P S < ( P S + c) Figure 2: The market price in the closed OMM is below the spot market price for energy Figure 2 illustrates scenario I. If OMM-suppliers (1) can serve demand at a lower price than the spot market (2), trading on the spot market would be more profitable for them. Hence, in open OMMs, suppliers willingness to trade on the OMM starts at P P S. In turn, if there was no OMM, consumers (3) would have to purchase energy at price (P S + c). Considering this as their maximal willingness to pay, P (P S + c). Consequently, P S P (P S + c). The perfect competition among suppliers prevents them from exploiting consumers maximum willingness to pay. P = P S will form in the open OMM. When trading on the OMM, consumers benefit by more attractive prices, compared to the spot market. Suppliers have no disadvantage when trading on the OMM as they can sell as much energy at the same price as before. Excess supply (4), which can be produced by suppliers at P, is traded on the spot market. 5

Scenario II: P S < P OMM ( P S + c) Figure 3: The market price in the closed OMM is in between of the spot market prices for energy Figure 3 illustrates scenario II: the spot market (1) provides demand at a lower price than the OMM (2). Yet, based on the transaction costs, purchasing supply on the spot market would be more expensive (3) than purchasing it on the OMM (2). Consequently, neither consumers nor suppliers have an incentive to trade on the spot market, which is why P = P OMM. When trading on the OMM, consumers benefit by more attractive prices, compared to the spot market. Suppliers (4) also benefit from trading on the OMM instead of trading on the spot market since they can sell more energy at a higher price on the OMM. 6

Scenario III: P S < ( P S + c) < P OMM Figure 4: The market price in the closed OMM is above the spot market price for energy Figure 4 illustrates scenario III. If the spot market (1) can serve demand at a lower price than the OMM (2), trading on the spot market would be more beneficial for consumers. Considering this as their maximal willingness to pay, consumers stop trading on the OMM if P (P S + c). Suppliers (3) would get P S, if there would be no OMM. Hence, suppliers prefer trading on the OMM as soon as P P S. Consequently, neither consumer nor suppliers have an incentive to trade on the spot market, if P = (P S + c). Compared to the spot market, consumers have no disadvantage since residual demand (4) can be bought on the spot market at the price as before. Suppliers benefit from trading on the OMM due to a higher price and a larger capacity utilization (5). 4 Conclusion, state of research and future outlook Our results indicate that open OMMs are a viable concept for energy trading. We find that consumers and suppliers do not necessarily trade at a disadvantage in open OMMs. Depending on the respective scenario, they can even benefit from attractive prices and higher capacity utilization. Since prices vary on both markets, the distribution of benefits among the participants is likely to fluctuate too, so that everyone profits from time to time. A quantitative assessment of the probability of occurrence is of further interest for our research. 7

In order to increase the applicability of our base model to real-world energy markets, we will relax its inherent assumptions step by step. Specifically, we have already developed models that relax assumptions 2-4. First, we relaxed the assumption of inelastic demand functions. In case of direct trade like in the OMM, where consumer are exposed to price fluctuations, elastic demand is a more realistic assumption (Kirschen, Strbac, Cumperayot, & de Paiva Mendes, 2000). We therefore analyzed this effect on P and found our results of the base model confirmed. Nevertheless, consumers generally prefer payment schemes like flat tariffs or usage-dependent tariffs (Dütschke & Paetz, 2013) that shield them from fluctuations on the spot market. Since tariffs usually are a reflection of average costs, our analysis is informative for the development of tariff structures for microgrid operators. In addition, this may be promising for behavioral research, to inform the development of automated bidding routines, which act in accordance with the preferences of individuals and might increase the acceptability of OMMs. Second, we lifted the assumption of perfect competition. Depending on the size of a microgrid, different market types may emerge. In larger microgrids, for instance villages with many PV modules, wind turbines, or biogas plants, it may be realistic to assume perfect competition on the supply side. In smaller microgrids, for instance ports with but a few PV modules and a diesel generator, monopolistic market structures may be more realistic. The results of our analysis indicate that consumer do not trade at a disadvantage even in case of monopolistic market structures, given an open OMM. Finally, we adapted our base model to cases in which the closed OMM is not self-sufficient and needs purchasing energy on the spot market. This restriction is unrealistic for cases like microgrids with a large share of RES where generation capacity fluctuates along with the availability of natural fuels. We find that even in such cases neither suppliers nor consumer face a disadvantage while trading on an open OMM. Subsequently, we will lift the remaining assumptions to further improve the real-world applicability of our model. Moreover, we plan to adapt the model to different realworld applications, e.g. energy cooperatives, where participants might follow a different code of conduct than purely rational agents do. 8

5 References U.S. Energy Information Administration, U. E. (2013). Annual Energy Outlook 2013- With projections to 2040. Retrieved from http://goo.gl/rbkhc Bertolini, S., Giacomini, M., Grillo, S., Massucco, S., & Silvestro, F. (2010). Coordinated micro-generation and load management for energy saving policies. 2010 IEEE PES, (pp. 1-7). doi:10.1109/isgteurope.2010.5638953 Burns & McDonnell Engineering Company, Inc. (2014, 06). Energy Management Action Plan. Retrieved 02 15, 2015, from Port of Los Angeles: http://goo.gl/vvi8oq Costa, P. M., Matos, M. A., & Lopes, J. P. (2008, 10). Regulation of microgeneration and microgrids. Energy Policy, pp. 3893 3904. doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2008.07.013 Depuru, S. S., Wang, L., Devabhaktuni, V., & Gudi, N. (2011, Mai 05). Smart Meters for Power Grid Challenges,Issues, Advantages and Status. Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews(6), pp. 2736 2742. doi:doi:10.1016/j.rser.2011.02.039 Dütschke, E., & Paetz, A.-G. (2013). Dynamic electricity pricing - Which programs do consumers prefer? Energy Policy, pp. 226-234. doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2013.03.025 Kirschen, D., Strbac, G., Cumperayot, P., & de Paiva Mendes, D. (2000, 05). Factoring the elasticity of demand in electricity prices. Power Systems, IEEE Transactions on(15 (2)), pp. 612-617. doi:10.1109/59.867149 Ohio University Compass. (2013). Retrieved 02 17, 2015, from http://www.ohio.edu/compass/stories/13-14/12/microgrid-dec-2013.cfm Piagi, P., & Lasseter, R. H. (2006). Autonomous Control of Microgrids. Power Engineering Society General Meeting. Montreal: IEEE. doi:10.1109/pes.2006.1708993 Schwaegerl, C., & Tao, L. (2014). The Microgrids Concept. In N. Hatziargyriou, Microgrids Architectures and Control (pp. 1-24). United Kingdom: John Wiley and Sons Ltd. doi:10.1002/9781118720677 9