US labor market: little sign of structural damage so far

Similar documents
Risk management: Building an effective process

How should policy respond to higher unemployment? Keywords: unemployment, mismatch, labor supply, unemployment insurance, monetary policy

Deutsche Bank Group Deutsche Insurance Asset Management. Advisory Focus Demystifying Life Insurance RBC Equity Charges

Absolute return: The search for positive returns in changing markets

US Labour Market Monitor July report set to attract much attention as both employment and growth have slowed in 2016

When Will the U.S. Job Market Recover?

CANADA AND U.S. AUTO SALES: ROOM FOR FUR- THER GROWTH? October Factors supporting the U.S. sales outlook: Employment Growth

FRBSF ECONOMIC LETTER

Direct real estate: Institutional grade investing for individuals portfolios

Capital preservation strategy update

The U.S. Economy after September pushing us from sluggish growth to an outright contraction. b and there s a lot of uncertainty.

Dice DFH Measure of National Mean Vacancy Duration, January 2001 to October 2014

Perspective. Economic and Market. Does a 2% 10-year U.S. Bond Yield Make Sense When...

Is the U.S. Economy Losing Its Dynamism? Dennis Lockhart President and Chief Executive Officer Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta

Table of Contents. A. Aggregate Jobs Effects...3. B. Jobs Effects of the Components of the Recovery Package...5. C. The Timing of Job Creation...

S&P 500 Composite (Adjusted for Inflation)

What Can We Learn by Disaggregating the Unemployment-Vacancy Relationship?

General Discussion: The United States Labor Market: Status Quo or A New Normal?

Underutilization in U.S. Labor Markets

Lars Osberg. Department of Economics Dalhousie University 6214 University Avenue Halifax, Nova Scotia B3H 3J5 CANADA

Does Unemployment Insurance Inhibit Job Search?

At the turn of the 21st century, labor force participation in the

Employment in the United States is recovering slowly from the

Global Client Group The Gateway to AWM

CIO Flash U.S. Fed tapering

High Yield Bonds in a Rising Rate Environment August 2014

Market Bulletin. November 7, U.S. High Yield: A bubble set to burst?

The Recent Evolution of the Natural Rate of Unemployment

Deficits as far as the eye can see

Research US Fed on hold: uncertainty set to keep Fed sidelined

Spain s Real Estate and Construction Markets. Think Tank of Deutsche Bank Group

FRBSF ECONOMIC LETTER

Why ECB QE is Negative for Commodities. Investment Research & Advisory. Deltec International Group

Jobs Online Background and Methodology

Adjusting to a Changing Economic World. Good afternoon, ladies and gentlemen. It s a pleasure to be with you here in Montréal today.

Which Industries are Shifting the Beveridge Curve?

Economic Update. Australian house prices unlikely to fall

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES HIRING, CHURN AND THE BUSINESS CYCLE. Edward P. Lazear James R. Spletzer

Household debt levels now higher than before the financial crisis 20 April 2016

The Credit Crisis: A Monetary Explanation

Perspective. Economic and Market. The U.S. Stock Market Resides at a Unique Global Zip Code. U.S. stock market diverges

WHAT AN INDICATOR OF LABOR DEMAND MEANS FOR U.S. LABOR MARKET ANALYSIS: INITIAL RESULTS FROM THE JOB OPENINGS AND LABOR TURNOVER SURVEY

CIO Flash Chinese equities: what happens next? July 8, 2015

MBA Forecast Commentary Joel Kan,

Preparing for 2015 Housing Market Opportunities

Alpha Preservation. Using Valuations to Identify Style Risk. Benjamin Graham

Analysis of the U.S. labor market is a difficult

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES LONG-TERM DAMAGE FROM THE GREAT RECESSION IN OECD COUNTRIES. Laurence M. Ball

Unemployment. AS Economics Presentation 2005

THE STATE OF THE ECONOMY

The worst is over for online brokerage

Gauging Current Conditions: The Economic Outlook and Its Impact on Workers Compensation

HOW BAD IS THE CURRENT RECESSION? LABOUR MARKET DOWNTURNS SINCE THE 1960s

Perspective. Economic and Market. A Productivity Problem?

THE POTENTIAL MACROECONOMIC EFFECT OF DEBT CEILING BRINKMANSHIP

PROTECTING YOUR PORTFOLIO WITH BONDS

Chapter 12. Unemployment and Inflation Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved

FOMC review Less confident Fed likely to stay on hold in March as well

Through the Snow, Job Market Plows Ahead

INFLATION REPORT PRESS CONFERENCE. Thursday 4 th February Opening remarks by the Governor

Inflation Target Of The Lunda Krona

The Problem with Structural Unemployment in the U.S.

Over the past several years, Americans have

How should we assess the implications of a rise in bond yields for UK pension schemes?

Plumbing, Heating, and Air-Conditioning Contractors: NAICS b - Plumbing: NAICS 1997

CIO Flash Chinese equities: what happens next? July 8, 2015

Renminbi Depreciation and the Hong Kong Economy

ANZ NZ JOB ADS FINALLY

Perspective. Economic and Market. Has Stock Market Stability Increased Vulnerability?

LIST OF MAJOR LEADING & LAGGING ECONOMIC INDICATORS

What do rising rates mean for equities?

Case Study of Unemployment Insurance Reform in North Carolina

On March 11, 2010, President Barack

The workforce in the United States is

Investment insight. Fixed income the what, when, where, why and how TABLE 1: DIFFERENT TYPES OF FIXED INCOME SECURITIES. What is fixed income?

New Issue: MOODY'S: CITY OF SAN DIEGO'S SUBORDINATED WATER REVENUE REFUNDING BONDS RATED Aa3

If Some Dare Call It Treason, Was Milton Friedman a Traitor?

DO WE NEED MORE STORAGE IN EUROPE?

Executive Summary The Macroeconomic Effects of an Add-on Value Added Tax

Employment and Unemployment

The Fix Fixed income flashback: is history going to repeat?

Bond markets vote for global recovery

UNEMPLOYMENT AMONG YOUNG WORKERS

Outlook for Australian Property Markets Perth

BOND ALERT. What Investors Should Know. July MILL ROAD, SUITE 105

A Case for Dividend Investing

FX Strategies. In the Low Yield Environment. Eddie Wang Head of FX Structuring, Asia. Hong Kong October 2010

Economic Research: Spain's Housing Market May Need Four More Years To Rebalance. Table Of Contents

Project LINK Meeting New York, October Country Report: Australia

CIO Flash Revisions to our 2016 global outlook Jan 25, 2016

Why Has Japan Been Hit So Hard by the Global Recession?

Impact of the recession

Trade Confidence Survey Australia:1H 2015

AUSTRALIAN DOLLAR OUTLOOK

EXPLORING SEPARATE ACCOUNTS

Accessing the U.S. market through ETFs


FRBSF ECONOMIC LETTER

EXECUTIVE BRIEF Settlements in Full: Debt Collection and the U.S. Economic Recovery

The following text represents the notes on which Mr. Parry based his remarks. 1998: Issues in Monetary Policymaking

Transcription:

Deutsche Bank Group DB Advisors A Closer Look US labor market: little sign of structural damage so far November 2012 Joshua N. Feinman Chief Global Economist DB Advisors Tel: 212-454-7964 Email: josh.feinman@db.com

A Closer Look US labor market: little sign of structural damage so far Overview After being pummeled by the Great Recession, the US labor market has had only a patchy and incomplete recovery. True, the unemployment rate has been trending down for nearly three years, but it is still well above pre-recession readings, while the share of the working-age population employed and the share participating in the labor force (i.e., employed or actively seeking employment) have both barely even begun to recover (charts 1 and 2). What s behind this enduring weakness? Some contend it s the result of structural damage to the supply of labor that will be hard to repair, even by a vigorous recovery in aggregate demand and additional monetary and fiscal stimulus. On this reckoning, changes Chart 1: Unemployment Rate wrought by the Great Recession have reduced the ability and willingness of potential workers to be matched to available jobs at economically viable wages because some have been left without the requisite skills, or ability to relocate, or incentives to find employment. As a result, the natural rate of unemployment has risen, and the fraction of the population able and willing to participate in the labor force has declined, implying there is less slack in the labor market than would be suggested by pre-recession relationships. According to this view, it will take improvements in education, the honing of appropriate skills, and changes in micro labor policies (like scaling back the expanded unemployment insurance program, and increasing job training and mobility assistance), rather than a Chart 2: Shares of the Working-age Population 11 In the Labor Force Employed 10 9 68 67 66 Percent 8 7 6 Percent 65 64 63 62 61 5 4 60 59 58 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 Source: BLS Source: BLS 1

pickup in aggregate demand and more macro stimulus, to solve the underemployment problem. Others push back against these arguments, countering that most of the damage to the labor market is cyclical, owing to a sharp fall-off in the demand for labor that can be turned around by a stronger economic recovery and macro-policy easing. On this logic, there remain vast pools of labor willing and able to be re-employed at profitable, non-inflationary wages. Of course, these different views are not mutually exclusive. It s really a question of degree: how much of the problem is cyclical, demand-driven, and hence potentially correctable by a conventional demandside recovery, and how much is structural, supplydriven, and thus more apt to endure absent changes to labor supply. This note briefly surveys the arguments and evidence in this debate. On balance, the cyclical case seems stronger. That is, the damage appears to be more the result of the terrible shock to aggregate demand initiated by the bursting of the housing and credit bubble, and at least in principle it ought to be reversible by a more vibrant recovery in labor demand that taps into the substantial pool of idle employable capacity. This is not to deny the structural argument entirely. There is some evidence to suggest that the effective supply of labor may have been damaged, partly by an increase in skills mismatch and partly by things like the extension of unemployment benefits (though the former seems to have already reversed, and the latter will likely dissipate as the extension program is eventually phased out). As for the argument that the supply of labor would improve if people sharpened their education and skills, that s undoubtedly true, but it was true before the Great Recession too. The question is whether the labor supply problem has gotten worse since the crisis. And the answer seems to be only a little. There are some caveats, though. First, even if most of the damage has in fact been caused by a temporary, cyclical shortfall in demand, the longer it takes to correct, the greater the chances it could morph into something more permanent. One reason is that the longer people remain unemployed or detached from the labor force, the higher the risk they will eventually lose their skills and/or attachment to work in ways that are not easily reversible. In other words, if a transitory demand shock lasts long enough, it could become a more permanent supply shock (this actually strengthens the case, though, for a more aggressive macropolicy response to try to boost demand now before it s too late). The other caution is that even if demand shocks have been the prime culprit, and someday they fully heal so that whatever cyclical forces that have pushed up unemployment and lowered labor force participation completely lift the shares of the population that will be employed and/or seeking employment will not come all the way back to pre-recession readings. That s not because of some lingering structural damage caused by the crisis. It s because of longer-term labor market trends, especially demographics, which have little to do with the Great Recession. The aging of the baby boomers, for example, has already started to shift the population toward age groups that normally have lower participation and employment rates. So even if the Great Recession had never happened, and the unemployment rate were still 5% or less, the rates of employment and labor force participation would be below 2007 rates simply because the population is older. And it is slated to get older still, making it unlikely that even a fully recovered labor market, with no lingering scars from the Great Recession, will ever again see as large a share of the population employed and in the labor force as in the pre-2008 world. The structural case There are several strands to the structural, supplyside argument. One focuses on increased mismatch between the types of labor supplied by workers (or potential workers) and the types of skills demanded by employers. This mismatch 2

could be geographic: people may be having a tougher time moving to places where jobs are available than they did in the past because the collapse of house prices has left them unable or unwilling to sell their homes. This is often referred to as house lock, and could be one cause of greater frictions in the labor market. Another is that the demand for labor may have shifted toward occupations or industries requiring skills that a lot of unemployed people just don t have. It will take time, for example, for unemployed construction workers or idled financial-sector employees to acquire the skills needed to fill openings in, say, technology, or health care management. Another arrow in the quiver of those who push the structural case is that incentives have become less favorable to employment. In particular, some argue that work has become less valuable because the subsidies available to remaining without work have increased relative to labor compensation. The main culprit often cited here is the extension of unemployment insurance benefits, but other potential factors include increased food stamps and income supports, including health and mortgage assistance that require low income. 1 Indeed, some estimate that the extension of Chart 3: Lots of Long-term Unemployed unemployment insurance benefits alone has raised the unemployment rate ½% to 1%, and a few suggest the impact has been even greater. 2 There s no doubt that long-term unemployment remains elevated, near all-time highs (chart 3), and some contend this is at least partly due to the extension of unemployment insurance benefits and other government-induced distortions that have reduced the rewards to work. Similarly, the Social Security disability rolls have swelled (chart 4), and some argue this is because it s easier to qualify and more remunerative to be on disability than it was in the past, which has encouraged more people to drop out of the labor force entirely. 3 The bottom line, according to these lines of reasoning, is that much of the rise in unemployment and decline in labor force participation is structural, due to a decline in labor supply (or inappropriate supply for the skills that are in demand in the locations in which they are demanded). Simply put, some people have become less able and others less willing to be matched to available employment. Buttressing this argument is the apparent shift in the Beveridge curve, which relates job openings to the unemployment rate (chart 5). In general, unemployment and job vacancies tend to be inversely related: when the labor market is Chart 4: Disability Recipients Unemployed Six Months or Longer (lhs) 5.4 % of Unemployed 50 45 40 35 30 25 20 15 10 5 0 Median Duration of Unemployment (rhs) 1968 1970 1972 1974 1976 1978 1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 25 20 15 10 5 0 Weeks % of Population Aged 25 to 64 5.0 4.6 4.2 3.8 3.4 3.0 2.6 2.2 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 1968 1969 2000 1970 1971 1972 2001 1973 1974 2002 1975 1976 2003 1977 1978 2004 1979 1980 2005 1981 1982 2006 1983 1984 2007 1985 1986 2008 1987 1988 2009 1989 1990 2010 1991 1992 2011 1993 1994 1995 2012 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 Source: BLS Source: SSA, BLS 3 1 See Mulligan, Casey (2011), The Expanding Social Safety Net, NBER Working Paper no. 17654. 2 See, for example, Aaronson, Daniel, and B. Mazumder, and S. Schechter (2010). What is Behind the Rise in Long-Term Unemployment? Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago Economic Perspectives. Farber, Henry S. and R. Valletta (2011), Extended Unemployment Insurance and Unemployment Duration in the Great Recession: The US Experience, Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco. Rothstein, Jesse (2012), Unemployment Insurance and Job Search in the Great Recession, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Fall. Grubb, David (2011), Assessing the Impact of Recent Unemployment Insurance Extensions in the US, OECD Working Paper (June). 3 See Autor, David H. and Mark G. Duggan (2006), The Growth in Social Security Disability Rolls: A Fiscal Crisis Unfolding, Journal of Economic Perspectives, Volume 20, Number 3, Summer.

strong, there are usually a lot of openings and not much unemployment; when it s weak, there are many people searching for work and not many open positions. This negative correlation held pretty tightly between late 2000, when the current series on job openings from the Job Openings and Labor Turnover (JOLTS) survey began, and early 2008. Since the Great Recession, however, the relationship appears to have shifted; unemployment has been higher for any given rate of job openings than it was in the previous cycle. For example, the rate of job openings so far this year is similar to readings seen in early 2004, yet the unemployment rate then was only about 5 1 2%, not 8%. To some, this is indicative of an increase in structural unemployment due to deterioration in the matching efficiency of the labor market. Whatever the cause greater skills mismatch, less geographic mobility, reduced incentives to work, or all of the above the implications of the structural case are clear: since the problems are on the supply side, they cannot be remedied by stronger demand and macro policy easing. What s needed is structural reform: phasing out extended unemployment benefits, tightening the rules for the disability program, providing mobility assistance, and improving education and skills. Problems with the structural case Closer inspection reveals several weaknesses in the structural case. For starters, it just doesn t pass the smell test, at least not as the prime Chart 5: Beveridge Curve Quarterly Data Job Vacancy Rate (%) 4.0 3.5 3.0 2.5 2.0 2000 2008 1.5 3.5 4.5 5.5 6.5 7.5 8.5 9.5 10.5 Unemployment Rate (%) 2009 2012 Source: BLS cause of the labor market s collapse during the Great Recession. That collapse was just too stunning and abrupt; in less than two years, the unemployment rate soared more than five percentage points, and nearly nine million nonfarm payroll jobs were lost. Most structural changes in the types and locations of employment opportunities, or matching efficiency, or how people respond to changing work incentives are unlikely to occur so rapidly. Still, even if structural problems were not initially to blame, they may have grown gradually more important over time, and could explain at least some of the labor market s stunted recovery over the past few years. But if increasing skills mismatch or the changing composition of labor demand across industries, occupations, or regions were the prime culprits, we d expect to see asymmetrical signs of labor market weakness disproportionate hits in specific sectors, and among certain kinds of workers. Yet that is not what we ve seen, at least not persistently, or in ways that differ sharply from past cycles. While it s true that certain sectors were especially hard hit during the Great Recession construction, for example, accounted for nearly 20% of the rise in the unemployment rate, despite employing only about 8% of the workforce, even at the peak these are the kinds of sectors that are often the most cyclical, and they ve come back symmetrically since the recovery began, with unemployment among construction workers accounting for about 20% of the drop in the aggregate unemployment rate since late 2009. 4 To be sure, many of those formerly-unemployed construction workers have found jobs in other industries (they must have, because construction employment continued to fall for awhile even as unemployment among former construction workers was receding). But that just further undercuts the structural argument because it suggests that there has been some inter-industry job mobility. A more systematic way to look for signs of increasing mismatch is to compare job vacancy 4 See Edward P. Lazear, and J. Spletzer (2012), The United States Labor Market: Status Quo or a New Normal? 4

rates with unemployment rates across many industries, occupations, and regions. An index of mismatch can be constructed that varies from zero to one: it s zero if there is no mismatch, meaning that all industries (or occupations, or regions) are in perfect alignment, with each having a vacancy/unemployment ratio equal to the aggregate ratio; it s one if there is complete mismatch, meaning that half the industries (or occupations, or regions) have no vacancies and positive unemployment, while the other half have all the vacancies and no unemployment; and it s somewhere between zero and one if there is some mismatch. 5 The index measures the share of workers that would have to be moved across industries (or occupations, or regions) to remove the mismatch and restore perfect alignment. Using data on job vacancies and unemployment across 12 major industries to construct such an index reveals that mismatch did increase sharply during the Great Recession, but has since receded back to pre-crisis levels (chart 6). Other studies have found a similar story with mismatch across occupations. 6 What about regional mismatch, due perhaps to house lock? Here, the case against is even Chart 6: Index of Job Mismatch by Industry 0.26 0.22 0.18 0.14 0.10 Dec 01 Jun 02 Dec 02 Jun 03 Dec 03 Jun 04 Dec 04 Based on 12-month mov average of NSA data on job openings and unemployment across 12 major industries Jun 05 Dec 05 Jun 06 Dec 06 Jun 07 Dec 07 Jun 08 Dec 08 Jun 09 Dec 09 Jun 10 Dec 10 Jun 11 Dec 11 Jun 12 Source: BLS, DeAM estimates stronger, as mismatch between job openings and the unemployed in different parts of the country seems not to have increased at all, even in 2008 2009, and has come down a bit since then. 7 While people do appear to be moving less than they used to, this trend predates the Great Recession, and the continued decline in geographic mobility that has occurred in recent years has actually been greater for renters than for home owners the opposite of what we d expect if the house lock story were correct. 8 All told, there seems little evidence to suggest any permanent, structural increase in mismatch between available jobs and the unemployed across industries, occupations, or regions. As for the apparent shift in the Beveridge curve, this may not necessarily be the telltale sign of structural damage to the labor market and a higher natural rate of unemployment that some contend. Evidence from past business cycles not using JOLTS data, which were not available then, but using the help wanted index from the Conference Board as a proxy for job openings suggests that the recent counter-clockwise shift in the Beveridge curve is not unusual in recessions and early-stage recoveries, perhaps because job openings never fall below a certain threshold level, even when unemployment is high, and usually begin to pick up before firms start to hire more intensely. 9 In the past, the Beveridge curve has tended to shift back toward its original position once the recovery got stronger and unemployment retreated toward pre-recession levels. So we probably won t know for sure whether the curve has really shifted for good this time until the unemployment rate moves closer to pre-crisis levels and we see how the job vacancy rate behaves as that happens. For now, it s premature 5 5 Lazear and Spletzer, ibid. 6 Lazear and Spletzer, ibid. 7 Dickens, William T. (2011), Has the Recession Increased the NAIRU? Brookings Papers on Economic Activity (June). 8 See Farber, Henry (2012), Unemployment in the Great Recession: Did the Housing Market Crisis Prevent the Unemployed From Moving to Take Jobs? American Economic Review, 102(3), and Valetta, Robert G. (2012), House Lock and Structural Unemployment, Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco Staff paper, for more house lock evidence, and Kaplan, Greg and S. Schulhofer- Wohl (2011) Interstate Migration Has Fallen Less than You Think, Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Staff report, for more on long-term trends in geographic mobility. 9 Daly, Mary C., and B. Hobijn, A. Sahin, R. Valletta (2012). A Search and Matching Approach to Labor Markets: Is the Natural Rate of Unemployment Rising? Forthcoming, Journal of Economic Perspectives.

1.4 1.2 1.0 0.8 0.6 0.4 0.2 0.0 to conclude that the curve has shifted permanently, not only because apparent shifts in the past often proved temporary, but also because recently firms seem to be recruiting less intensively to fill job openings, offering lower initial wages, and requiring more qualifications so a job opening today may not be quite as solid as a job opening before the Great Recession. 10 Moreover, movements in the vacancy/unemployment ratio that have occurred in recent years have been pretty widespread across industries (chart 7); there are no industries with unusually high or low vacancy/unemployment ratios, reinforcing our earlier conclusion that structural mismatch across industries has not become a persistently greater problem than it was in the past. Even so, the labor market s ongoing struggles could still be due to supply issues, just not idiosyncratic, job-matching ones, but broad-based deteriorations in work incentives. In principle, if enhanced non-work benefits from the government have made some people less willing to accept available jobs at prevailing wages, this could shift out the Beveridge curve, drive up the natural rate of unemployment, and depress labor force participation. As already noted, the most often-cited potential problem here is the extension of unemployment benefits, and there are a wide range of estimates of the impact of this extension on the Chart 7: Vacancy/Unemployment by Industry 12-month mov Average Education and Health Services Government Transportation and Utilities Other Services Dec 01 Jun 02 Dec 02 Jun 03 Dec 03 Jun 04 Dec 04 Jun 05 Professional and Business Services Information Leisure and Hospitality Wholesale and Retail Trade Dec 05 Jun 06 Dec 06 Jun 07 Dec 07 Jun 08 Dec 08 Jun 09 Dec 09 Finance Manufacturing Construction Jun 10 Dec 10 Jun 11 Dec 11 Jun 12 Source: BLS unemployment rate. Some of the upper-end estimates, though, are based on extrapolations of past episodes in which unemployment was not as high and the labor market not as weak, so they may overstate the impact that today s extension of benefits may be having in boosting unemployment. Also, the duration of unemployment has increased even for those who are not eligible for benefits at all those who quit their jobs and those who are new to the labor force suggesting that the extension of benefits is far from the whole story. 11 Still, almost all studies find at least some modest impact a boost of 1 4% to perhaps as much as 3 4% to the unemployment rate due to the extended benefits program (though this program may also have slightly mitigated some of the downward pressure on labor force participation because to qualify for benefits one must be in the labor force). 12 But whatever the impact, it will likely be temporary, as the extended benefits program has already begun to be scaled back in some states, and will likely be phased out entirely before too long, as it always has been in past cycles. The unprecedented rise in the number of longterm unemployed is a worry not because it s a definitive sign of structural problems cyclical weakness in labor demand would also tend to create more long-term unemployed but because it could become more of a permanent condition if it takes too long to reverse. That s because the likelihood of returning to work declines as the duration of unemployment increases, perhaps because longer bouts of idleness erode skills and employment contacts, 13 so having so many people unemployed for so long raises the risk that even a vigorous rebound in labor demand might not be able to bring back all of them not to mention those who ve already become disillusioned and left the labor force entirely. Again, this is not necessarily a problem now, but it could become one in the future. How big of a problem? A recent 10 Davis, Stephen J., and R. Faberman, and J. Haltiwanger (2012). Recruiting Intensity During and After the Great Recession: National and Industry Evidence. American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings, 102 (3). 11 Kuang K. and Valletta R. (2010). Extended Unemployment and UI Benefits. Economic Letters. 12 Dickens (2011), ibid. 13 See, for example, Shimer, Robert (2008), The Probability of Finding a Job, American Economic Review, 98 (2), 268 73. 6

simulation found that if the labor market strengthens enough so that those who ve been unemployed for less than six months are able to find jobs again as quickly as they did before the Great Recession, but the long-term unemployed see no improvement in their job-finding rates, the aggregate unemployment rate would fall to 6% or a bit less. 14 That s not all the way back to the sub-5% rate prevailing before 2008, but the difference is probably an upper bound on any long-term increase in structural unemployment because it assumes no improvement at all in the rate at which the long-term unemployed find jobs even if the labor market gets much stronger. This seems an overly pessimistic assumption. Still, it is a caution about the kind of structural damage that could ensue down the road if the labor market continues to struggle, and is another reason to try to kick it into higher gear soon before permanent sclerosis sets in. As for the decline in labor force participation, that s not necessarily a sign of structural, supplyside problems either; it too could be a normal, cyclical response to weaker labor demand. Yes, the disability program may have enticed some people to drop out of the labor force, but this trend began long before the Great Recession (chart 4). And some of the decline in the labor force participation rate (LFPR) reflects the Chart 8: Labor Force Participation Rate continuation of other longer-term labor market trends, especially demographics, which would have happened anyway. The aggregate LFPR declined from a peak of 66.3% in 2007 to 63.6% in Q3 2012, but about half of this decline would have occurred even if within-age-group LFPRs had remained steady simply because the population was shifting into older age groups, who normally have lower participation rates (chart 8). A similar result would have obtained if the pre-recession trends in within-age-group LFPRs (particularly, the declines among the young, due to increased schooling, roughly offset by increases among the old) had continued. The bottom line is that you can t just look at the decline in the aggregate LFPR and say it is all due to the Great Recession. Some of it would likely have occurred anyway. It s a similar story for the employmentpopulation ratio, or E/Pop (chart 9). And the demographic trends depressing these ratios are slated to continue. Indeed, the changing age distribution of the population will shave another one-half percentage point or so off the aggregate LFPR by 2015. So even if the labor market fully heals, and the unemployment rate falls back to pre-recession readings, the LFPR and E/Pop will not come all the way back not because of lingering structural damage from the Great Recession, but largely because of demographics. Chart 9: Employment/Population Ratio Actual Due to Demographics (holding within-age-group LFPRs constant) Due to Demographics and Pre-Recession Trends in Within-Age-Group LFPRs Actual Due to Demographics (holding within-age-group LFPRs constant) Due to Demographics and Pre-Recession Trends in Within-Age-Group LFPRs 66.5 64 Percent 66.0 65.5 65.0 64.5 63 62 61 60 59 64.0 58 63.5 57 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 Source: BLS, UN, DeAM estimates Source: BLS, UN, DeAM estimates 7 14 Elsby, Michael, and B. Hobijn, and A. Sahin, and R. Valletta (2011). The Labor Market in the Great Recession: An Update. Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco Working Paper Series (October).

So far, the evidence we ve reviewed suggests that cyclical, demand factors have been the predominant cause of the labor market s enduring weakness persistently higher unemployment than before the Great Recession and lower participation and employment rates than can be attributed soley to demographics and pre-recession trends. But what really seals the case for the cyclical, demand-side arguments is the behavior of labor compensation. If damage to labor supply were the main problem, and labor demand were more or less intact, we d expect to see wage pressures as firms competed to attract suitable, interested workers. But we re not seeing that at all not in aggregate, not adjusted for compositional changes in the workforce, not among new hires, not even in certain regions or industries, with very few modest exceptions. 15 On the contrary, most metrics suggest real labor costs have decelerated. And anecdotes of labor shortages remain limited, scattered, and confined to a few very specific skills. Of course, this doesn t mean there s been no damage at all to labor supply, only that the hit to labor demand has been much greater. Again, we won t know for sure whether there are any permanent supply effects until after labor demand has recovered more fully. Then, we can look at wages, the unemployment rate, the vacancy rate, and LFPR and E/Pop (adjusted for demographics and pre-recession trends) to see if there is lingering, structural damage to labor supply. But so far, cyclical demand factors seem to have been dominant. Conclusion Most of the damage to the labor market has been due to the awful demand shocks precipitated by the economic and financial crisis. There is not much sign of permanent structural damage, at least not yet, though there is some risk it could emerge if demand doesn t come back soon. And we won t know for sure until it does. 15 Rothstein (2012), ibid. 8

Notes DB Advisors is the brand name for the institutional asset management division of Deutsche Asset Management, the asset management arm of Deutsche Bank AG. In the US, Deutsche Asset Management relates to the asset management activities of Deutsche Bank Trust Company Americas, Deutsche Investment Management Americas Inc. and DWS Trust Company; in Canada, Deutsche Investment Management Americas Inc., and Deutsche Asset Management Canada Limited (Deutsche Asset Management Canada Limited is a wholly owned subsidiary of Deutsche Investment Management Americas Inc); in Germany and Luxembourg: DWS Investment GmbH, DWS Investment S.A., DWS Finanz-Service GmbH, Deutsche Asset Management Investmentgesellschaft GmbH, and Deutsche Asset Management International GmbH; in Denmark, Finland, Iceland, Norway and Sweden, Deutsche Asset Management International GmbH; in Australia, Deutsche Asset Management (Australia) Limited (ABN 63 116 232 154) Australian financial services license holder; in Hong Kong, Deutsche Asset Management (Hong Kong) Limited; in Japan, Deutsche Asset Management Limited (Japan); in Singapore, Deutsche Asset Management (Asia) Limited (Company Reg. No. 198701485N); in the United Kingdom, Deutsche Alternative Asset Management (UK) Limited, Deutsche Alternative Asset Management (Global) Limited, and Deutsche Asset Management (UK) Limited; in addition to other regional entities in the Deutsche Bank Group. This material is intended for informational purposes only and it is not intended that it be relied on to make any investment decision. It does not constitute investment advice or a recommendation or an offer or solicitation and is not the basis for any contract to purchase or sell any security or other instrument, or for Deutsche Bank AG and its affiliates to enter into or arrange any type of transaction as a consequence of any information contained herein. Neither Deutsche Bank AG nor any of its affiliates, gives any warranty as to the accuracy, reliability or completeness of information which is contained in this document. Except insofar as liability under any statute cannot be excluded, no member of the Deutsche Bank Group, the Issuer or any officer, employee or associate of them accepts any liability (whether arising in contract, in tort or negligence or otherwise) for any error or omission in this document or for any resulting loss or damage whether direct, indirect, consequential or otherwise suffered by the recipient of this document or any other person. The views expressed in this document constitute Deutsche Bank AG or its affiliates judgment at the time of issue and are subject to change. This document is only for professional investors. This document was prepared without regard to the specific objectives, financial situation or needs of any particular person who may receive it. The value of shares/units and their derived income may fall as well as rise. Past performance or any prediction or forecast is not indicative of future results. No further distribution is allowed without prior written consent of the Issuer. The forecasts provided are based upon our opinion of the market as at this date and are subject to change, dependent on future changes in the market. Any prediction, projection or forecast on the economy, stock market, bond market or the economic trends of the markets is not necessarily indicative of the future or likely performance. For Investors in the United Kingdom: Issued in the United Kingdom by Deutsche Asset Management (UK) Limited of One Appold Street, London, EC2A 2UU. Authorised and regulated by the Financial Services Authority. This document is a non-retail communication within the meaning of the FSA s Rules and is directed only at persons satisfying the FSA s client categorisation criteria for an eligible counterparty or a professional client. This document is not intended for and should not be relied upon by a retail client. When making an investment decision, potential investors should rely solely on the final documentation relating to the investment or service and not the information contained herein. The investments or services mentioned herein may not be appropriate for all investors and before entering into any transaction you should take steps to ensure that you fully understand the transaction and have made an independent assessment of the appropriateness of the transaction in the light of your own objectives and circumstances, including the possible risks and benefits of entering into such transaction. You should also consider seeking advice from your own advisers in making this assessment. If you decide to enter into a transaction with us you do so in reliance on your own judgment. For Investors in Australia: In Australia, Issued by Deutsche Asset Management (Australia) Limited (ABN 63 116 232 154), holder of an Australian Financial Services License. This information is only available to persons who are professional, sophisticated, or wholesale investors under the Corporations Act. An investment with Deutsche Asset Management is not a deposit with or any other type of liability of Deutsche Bank AG ARBN 064 165 162, Deutsche Asset Management (Australia) Limited or any other member of the Deutsche Bank AG Group. The capital value of and performance of an investment with Deutsche Asset Management is not guaranteed by Deutsche Bank AG, Deutsche Asset Management (Australia) Limited or any other member of the Deutsche Bank Group. Deutsche Asset Management (Australia) Limited is not an Authorised Deposit taking institution under the Banking Act 1959 nor regulated by the Australian Prudential Authority. Investments are subject to investment risk, including possible delays in repayment and loss of income and principal invested. For Investors in Hong Kong: Interests in the funds may not be offered or sold in Hong Kong or other jurisdictions, by means of an advertisement, invitation or any other document, other than to Professional Investors or in circumstances that do not constitute an offering to the public. This document is therefore for the use of Professional Investors only and as such, is not approved under the Securities and Futures Ordinance (SFO) or the Companies Ordinance and shall not be distributed to non-professional Investors in Hong Kong or to anyone in any other jurisdiction in which such distribution is not authorised. For the purposes of this statement, a Professional investor is defined under the SFO. For Investors in MENA region: This information has been provided to you by Deutsche Bank AG Dubai branch, an Authorised Firm regulated by the Dubai Financial Services Authority. It is solely directed at wholesale clients of Deutsche Bank AG Dubai branch, who Deutsche Bank AG Dubai branch is satisfied meet the regulatory criteria as established by the Dubai Financial Services Authority. Copyright 2012 Deutsche Bank AG, Frankfurt am Main