Lecture 7: Policy Design: Health Insurance & Adverse Selection



Similar documents
The Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania. Hillsdale College

Social insurance, private insurance and social protection. The example of health care systems in some OECD countries

Health Care a Public or Private Good?

TOWARDS PUBLIC PROCUREMENT KEY PERFORMANCE INDICATORS. Paulo Magina Public Sector Integrity Division

Connecting Theory to Data in Analyzing Social Insurance

On What Resources and Services Is Education Funding Spent?

Health Care in Crisis

Delegation in human resource management

Hong Kong s Health Spending 1989 to 2033

PUBLIC VS. PRIVATE HEALTH CARE IN CANADA. Norma Kozhaya, Ph.D Economist, Montreal economic Institute CPBI, Winnipeg June 15, 2007

Expenditure on Health Care in the UK: A Review of the Issues

Expenditure and Outputs in the Irish Health System: A Cross Country Comparison

Health Care Systems: Efficiency and Policy Settings

relating to household s disposable income. A Gini Coefficient of zero indicates

PUBLIC & PRIVATE HEALTH CARE IN CANADA

The U.S Health Care Paradox: How Spending More is Getting Us Less

Waiting times and other barriers to health care access

PERMANENT AND TEMPORARY WORKERS

HEALTH INSURANCE COVERAGE AND ADVERSE SELECTION

Size and Development of the Shadow Economy of 31 European and 5 other OECD Countries from 2003 to 2015: Different Developments

41 T Korea, Rep T Netherlands T Japan E Bulgaria T Argentina T Czech Republic T Greece 50.

4/17/2015. Health Insurance. The Framework. The importance of health care. the role of government, and reasons for the costs increase

Healthcare and Population Aging

Private Health insurance in the OECD

International comparisons of obesity prevalence

ORGANISATION FOR ECONOMIC CO-OPERATION AND DEVELOPMENT

Higher education institutions as places to integrate individual lifelong learning strategies

SWECARE FOUNDATION. Uniting the Swedish health care sector for increased international competitiveness


Private Health insurance in the OECD

Preventing fraud and corruption in public procurement

Foreign Taxes Paid and Foreign Source Income INTECH Global Income Managed Volatility Fund

A Comparison of the Tax Burden on Labor in the OECD

A Comparison of the Tax Burden on Labor in the OECD By Kyle Pomerleau

Cross-country comparison of health care system efficiency

How many students study abroad and where do they go?

Private Health Insurance in OECD Countries and Selection in Private Health Insurance Markets

THE LOW INTEREST RATE ENVIRONMENT AND ITS IMPACT ON INSURANCE MARKETS. Mamiko Yokoi-Arai

Heterogeneity, Demand for Insurance and Adverse Selection

Social Insurance: Connecting Theory to Data

Health Systems: Type, Coverage and Financing Mechanisms

Trends in Digitally-Enabled Trade in Services. by Maria Borga and Jennifer Koncz-Bruner

What Proportion of National Wealth Is Spent on Education?

STATISTICS FOR THE FURNITURE INDUSTRY AND TRADE

Eliminating Double Taxation through Corporate Integration

Insurance corporations and pension funds in OECD countries

POLICY BRIEF. Private Health Insurance in OECD Countries. Introduction. Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development

Public / private mix in health care financing

HEALTH CARE DELIVERY IN BRITAIN AND GERMANY: TOWARDS CONVERGENCE?

- 2 - Chart 2. Annual percent change in hourly compensation costs in manufacturing and exchange rates,

Government Intervention in Health Insurance Markets

How To Tax On Pension Income For Older People In European Countries

Capital Markets, Savings Division Annual Report Insurance

INTERNATIONAL COMPARISONS OF HOURLY COMPENSATION COSTS

Health Care Systems: An International Comparison. Strategic Policy and Research Intergovernmental Affairs May 2001

With data up to: May Monthly Electricity Statistics

Estimating welfare in insurance markets using variation in prices

ORGANISATION FOR ECONOMIC CO-OPERATION AND DEVELOPMENT

EIOPA Stress Test Press Briefing Frankfurt am Main, 4 July 2011

DEMOGRAPHICS AND MACROECONOMICS

VULNERABILITY OF SOCIAL INSTITUTIONS

Reporting practices for domestic and total debt securities

Second Hour Exam Public Finance Fall, Answers

ESC-ERC Recommendations for the Use of. Automated External Defibrillators (AEDs) in Europe

Social health insurance in Belgium. Charlotte Wilgos & Thomas Rousseau

What Is the Total Public Spending on Education?

An Analysis of the Effect of Income on Life Insurance. Justin Bryan Austin Proctor Kathryn Stoklosa

Experiences with tax relief for energy efficient equipment for industry

Review of R&D Tax Credit. Invitation for Submissions

Canada GO 2535 TM World Traveller's edition Maps of North America (Canada, US, Mexico), Western and Central Europe (including Russia) CAD 349,95

Access to Health Care: A Basic Human Right or Privilege?

Bismarck, Beveridge and The Blues

Health Care Reform in Korea: Key Challenges

Paul E. Lingenfelter President, State Higher Education Executive Officers

CO1.2: Life expectancy at birth

Percent of adults with postsecondary degree. Japan. Mexico. Canada. Poland. Denmark. Greece Germany. Italy. Austria. Korea.

INEQUALITIES IN HEALTH CARE SERVICES UTILISATION IN OECD COUNTRIES

What Are the Incentives to Invest in Education?

SF3.1: Marriage and divorce rates

How To Calculate Tertiary Type A Graduation Rate

Preference Heterogeneity and Insurance Markets: Explaining a Puzzle of Insurance

Internationalization and higher education policy: Recent developments in Finland

Culture Change in the Workforce in an Aging America: Are We Making Any Progress?

Government at a Glance 2015

Student Finance and Accessibility in an International Comparative Perspective

WELFARE STATES AND PUBLIC HEALTH: AN INTERNATIONAL COMPARISON. Peter Abrahamson University of Copenhagen

EU study on company car taxation: presentation of the main results

B Financial and Human Resources

Rationales for Social Insurance

BT Premium Event Call and Web Rate Card

Creating the Future of Public Education: Graduation Requirements in New York State. NYS Board of Regents Regional Forum

Appendix C. National Subscription Television Regulations

Transfer issues and directions for reform: Australian transfer policy in comparative perspective

How Good Is Canadian Health Care? 2008 Report

Flexicurity. U. Michael Bergman University of Copenhagen

Policy Brief. Tackling Harmful Alcohol Use Economics and Public Health Policy. Directorate for Employment, Labour and Social Affairs.

Private Health Insurance in OECD Countries

32 nd National Conference on Law & Higher Education

Finland must take a leap towards new innovations

Health, Private and Public Insurance, G 15, 16. U.S. Health care > 16% of GDP (7% in 1970), 8% in U.K. and Sweden, 11% in Switzerland.

Transcription:

Health Insurance Spending & Health Adverse Selection Lecture 7: Policy Design: Health Insurance & Adverse Selection Johannes Spinnewijn London School of Economics Lecture Notes for Ec426 1 / 25

Health Insurance Spending & Health Adverse Selection Outline 1 Health Insurance & Care 2 Rise in Spending & Impact on Health 3 Adverse selection: theory & empirics 2 / 25

Health Insurance Spending & Health Adverse Selection Health Insurance Different from other examples of social insurance triangle relationship between customer, insurer and provider co-existence of private and public initiative relation between health care and health outcomes some similar issues as with social security Health is an important field because of enormous size and rapid growth 1950: 4% of GDP devoted to health care in US 2003: 15% of GDP devoted to health care in US 2075: 38% of GDP devoted to health care in US Health economics is field in itself. We will focus on public sector interventions 3 / 25

Health Insurance Spending & Health Adverse Selection Health Care Spending in OECD Nations in 2002 Health Care Spending in OECD Nations in 2002 15 Health Care Spending (% of GDP) 12 9 6 3 0 Slovak Republic Korea Mexico Poland Luxembourg Turkey Finland Ireland Czech Republic Spain Austria United Kingdom Hungary Japan Italy New Zealand Norway Denmark Australia Belgium Netherlands Sweden Portugal Greece Canada France Iceland Germany Switzerland United States 4 / 25

Health Insurance Spending & Health Adverse Selection UK vs. US UK: publicly funded health care system (NHS) largest employer in UK insures most types of care private health care for top-ups, only taken by 8% Before Obama-care US tended to have less public intervention than other developed countries 50% compared to 75% on average elsewhere medicare vs. medicaid insurance provided by employers, large tax subsidy - financed with payroll tax many types of care uninsured, many people uninsured 5 / 25

Health Insurance Spending & Health Adverse Selection Rise in Health Spending: Reasons? General consensus: technological progress with more expensive methods (supply effect) example: angioplasty: expensive but saves lifes (of some patients...) Newhouse (1992): residual argument (a la growth accounting) only 1/4 to 1/2 of rise in spending can be explained by other facts demand effects: aging, increased income, subsidized by government, increased insurance other supply effects: supplier induced demand (fee-for-service), malpractice Limited direct evidence for impact of technological change 6 / 25

Health Insurance Spending & Health Adverse Selection Health Spending vs. Health Outcomes Is increase in health spending a problem? optimal health share is likely to grow with income voluntary choice to adopt (expensive) technological progress BUT prices are distorted due to insurance Does health insurance / higher spending improve health? margin vs. average evidence for "flat of the curve" health care extremely high average value of health improvements in the last decennia young vs. old substantial impact of Medicaid (Currie & Gruber 1996) insignificant impact of Medicare (Card et al. 2008) opportunity cost of each health policy (see RDD example) How to measure health improvements? Are health improvements of First Order importance for insurance policies? 7 / 25

Health Insurance Spending & Health Adverse Selection Opportunity Cost: An RDD Example Source: Almond, Doyle, Kowalski and Williams (2009) 8 / 25

Health Insurance Spending & Health Adverse Selection Opportunity Cost: An RDD Example Source: Almond, Doyle, Kowalski and Williams (2009) 9 / 25

Market Failures and Government Interventions 1 Asymmetric Information: heterogeneity of risk types adverse selection in insurance market price subsidies, insurance mandates,... 2 Externalities/Internalities/Consumer myopia tax subsidies for health insurance, government provided insurance sin taxes (alcohol/cigarettes), fat tax,... 3 Other reasons for government provision or regulation; 1 Suppliers exploiting asymmetric info about desirable care (e.g., licensing of doctors, fixing physician salaries) 2 Incomplete market: ex-ante risk uninsured, since we cannot contract before birth 3 Equity concerns: health inequality may directly enter social welfare function (e.g., in US, white infant mortality rate is 6/1000; black is 14/1000) 10 / 25

Adverse Selection as a Motivation for SI Key paper: Akerlof (1970), Rothschild and Stiglitz (1976) environment with asymmetric information: individuals know risk of becoming sick but insurer does not market failure: underprovision of insurance (complete unravelling in extreme case) government intervention: through mandated insurance can induce a Pareto improvement Renewed interest: negative correlation puzzle theory predicts that high risk types buy more insurance coverage empirically, the exact opposite is found in many insurance markets Most recently: estimate welfare cost of asymmetric information structural vs. reduced-form approaches strong assumptions on importance of preferences 11 / 25

Simple Demand and Supply of Insurance Based on Einav, Finkelstein & Cullen (2010) Consumers have the choice between contract H and L. Contract H provides more insurance coverage at additional premium p Assume unobserved heterogeneity ζ determines both the value and the cost of insurance. Additive model: v v H (ζ) v L (ζ) π (ζ) } {{ } + r (ζ) }{{} risk -term preference -term π (ζ) equals the insurer s cost of providing insurance r (ζ) captures the net-value of insurance for CARA γ and normal risk x: π (ζ) = Ex, r (ζ) = γ 2 var (x) 12 / 25

Heterogeneity in Risks: Adverse Selection Buy contract H iff v (ζ) p, Demand : D (p) = 1 F v (p) Cost of providing insurance depends on types buying insurance Average Cost : AC (p) = E (π v (ζ) p) Marginal Cost : MC (p) = E (π v (ζ) = p) More risky types tend to value insurance more such that the cost of providing insurance is increasing in p 13 / 25

Adverse Selection 14 / 25

Welfare Cost of Adverse Selection Competing firms price at average cost; effi cient to price at marginal cost Equilibrium price : p c = AC (p c ) Effi cient price : p = MC (p ) Ineffi ciently high equilibrium price since AC (p) > MC (p) individuals with willingness-to-pay higher than their cost do not buy insurance in equilibrium Welfare cost equals Γ = p c p [p MC (p)] d (D (p)) (= triangle CED) 15 / 25

Price Subsidies vs. Mandates Prices are too high due to adverse selection government intervention? Price Subsidy: lower equilibrium price towards the effi cient price generate higher surplus, but pay subsidy s to all who buy insurance MC of public funds λ is higher than 1 p c W subsidy = [p MC (p)] d (D (p)) λsd p c s (pc s) Universal Mandate: force everyone to buy insurance generate positive surplus for those with p > MC (p), but negative surplus for those with p < MC (p) diffi cult to implement q when rationing is not effi cient W mandate = Γ triangle EGH 16 / 25

Welfare Analysis using Suffi cient Statistics Suffi cient to estimate demand curve and average cost curve need information on available options, contract choices and the medical claims for given prices need exogenous price variation as well Approach allows to calculate welfare loss due to ineffi cient pricing and gain from policy interventions Einav et al. (2010) analyze employer-provided health insurance consider choice between high-deductible and low-deductible contract exploit variation in the premium across business units observe how many buy and how much they claim effi ciency cost is small (only 3% of total surplus), both price subsidy and mandate would decrease welfare! 17 / 25

18 / 25

Adverse Selection: Pricing vs. Screening Akerlof (1970): presence of high risk types prices lower risk types out of the market extreme unravelling: no one buys contract (except highest risk type) - even when everyone prefers to buy at actuarially fair price measure of ineffi ciency: E (π v (ζ) p) E (π v (ζ) = p) Rothschild and Stiglitz (1976): previous approach takes contracts as given allow insurers to provide a menu of contracts specifying price ánd coverage screen low risk types by providing less insurance at reduced premium 19 / 25

Positive Correlation Test Robust prediction of Adverse Selection Model: high risk types will buy more insurance positive correlation, conditional on observables Empirical evidence started with Chiappori and Salanié (2000), finding no significant correlation in car industry, conditional on observables other markets with insignificant correlation: life insurance (Cawley & Philipson 1999); health insurance (Cardon & Hendel 2001) markets with negative correlation: long-term care insurance (Finkelstein & McGarry 2006), Medigap insurance (Fang, Keane and Silverman 2008) Empirically, heterogeneity in risks do not play the role we expected... 20 / 25

Heterogeneity in Preferences Current literature conjectures the importance of heterogeneous preferences Back to model (v = π + r) - assume normal heterogeneity MC curve simplifies to MC (p (q)) = µ π + cov (π, v) var (v) [p (q) µ v ] MC curve flattens if the variance in preferences increases MC curve is upward sloping if cov (π, v) (= var (π) + cov (π, r)) < 0 Suffi cient statistics approach: unnecessary to uncover the underlying heterogeneity adverse selection if MC curve is decreasing advantageous selection if MC curve is increasing 21 / 25

Advantageous Selection 22 / 25

Heterogeneity in Preferences? While current empirical approaches attribute residual heterogeneity in demand to heterogeneous preferences, direct evidence is limited. Recent work questions stability of preferences for given individual across domains. Suggests importance of other drivers of the demand for insurance (risk perceptions, inertia, cognitive ability,...), possibly unrelated to the actual value of insurance. 23 / 25

Adverse Selection vs. Moral Hazard Insurance of medical care induces moral hazard ex ante: less precautionary efforts ex post: overconsumption of medical care Moral hazard predicts the same positive correlation. insurers reduce insurance coverage to provide optimal incentives (either ex ante or ex post) very different from reducing insurance coverage to screen good risk types How to distinguish from adverse selection? no precautionary efforts (life insurance/annuities) use experimental or quasi-experimental variation use dynamic data Moral hazard and heterogeneous preferences may explain negative correlation-puzzle people who are more risk-averse buy more insurance, but exert more effort as well 24 / 25

In Sum Health insurance is a particular type of Social Insurance (care provider, private vs. public, impact on health). Expenditures on health care are growing exponentially. Private information about health risks may cause adverse selection; underprovision of insurance would justify government interventions. However, empirical evidence suggests minor role of people s risk as a determinant of their insurance choice. 25 / 25