Lecture 9: Price Discrimination



Similar documents
PRICE DISCRIMINATION Industrial Organization B

Chapter 15: Monopoly WHY MONOPOLIES ARISE HOW MONOPOLIES MAKE PRODUCTION AND PRICING DECISIONS

2. Price Discrimination

3 Price Discrimination

ECON 600 Lecture 5: Market Structure - Monopoly. Monopoly: a firm that is the only seller of a good or service with no close substitutes.

Lecture 6: Price discrimination II (Nonlinear Pricing)

Figure 1, A Monopolistically Competitive Firm

First degree price discrimination ECON 171

Price Discrimination

SECOND-DEGREE PRICE DISCRIMINATION

Pricing with Perfect Competition. Business Economics Advanced Pricing Strategies. Pricing with Market Power. Markup Pricing

Monopoly WHY MONOPOLIES ARISE

Economics 431 Fall st midterm Answer Key

Chapter 11 Pricing With Market Power

p, we suppress the wealth arguments in the aggregate demand function. We can thus state the monopolist s problem as follows: max pq (p) c (q (p)).

Economics 335, Spring 1999 Problem Set #7

1.4 Hidden Information and Price Discrimination 1

Price Discrimination: Part 2. Sotiris Georganas

Price Discrimination

Managerial Economics

Conditions for Efficiency in Package Pricing


Do not open this exam until told to do so.

Chapter 11 Pricing Strategies for Firms with Market Power

Chapter 14 Monopoly Monopoly and How It Arises

How To Understand The Market Structure Of A Monopoly

2.2 Price Discrimination

Pricing to Mass Markets. Simple Monopoly Pricing, Price Discrimination and the Losses from Monopoly

Thus MR(Q) = P (Q) Q P (Q 1) (Q 1) < P (Q) Q P (Q) (Q 1) = P (Q), since P (Q 1) > P (Q).

Part IV. Pricing strategies and market segmentation

A Detailed Price Discrimination Example

Answers to Chapter 6 Exercises

KEELE UNIVERSITY MID-TERM TEST, 2007 BA BUSINESS ECONOMICS BA FINANCE AND ECONOMICS BA MANAGEMENT SCIENCE ECO MANAGERIAL ECONOMICS II

Principle of Microeconomics Econ chapter 13

Price Discrimination and Two Part Tariff

An Integrated Approach to Teaching Price Discrimination

Economics of Regulation. Price Discrimination

ECON 103, ANSWERS TO HOME WORK ASSIGNMENTS

A. a change in demand. B. a change in quantity demanded. C. a change in quantity supplied. D. unit elasticity. E. a change in average variable cost.

Marginal cost. Average cost. Marginal revenue

Profit Maximization. 2. product homogeneity

Monopolistic Competition

chapter: Solution Solution Monopoly 1. Each of the following firms possesses market power. Explain its source.

Common in European countries government runs telephone, water, electric companies.

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

Econ 202 Exam 3 Practice Problems

Principles of demand management Airline yield management Determining the booking limits. » A simple problem» Stochastic gradients for general problems

Price competition with homogenous products: The Bertrand duopoly model [Simultaneous move price setting duopoly]

-1- Worked Solutions 5. Lectures 9 and 10. Question Lecture 1. L9 2. L9 3. L9 4. L9 5. L9 6. L9 7. L9 8. L9 9. L9 10. L9 11. L9 12.

Econ 201 Lecture 17. The marginal benefit of expanding output by one unit is the market price. Marginal cost of producing corn

Everything is worth what its purchaser will pay for it. Publilius Syrus (1st century B.C.)

Figure: Computing Monopoly Profit

Managerial Economics & Business Strategy Chapter 8. Managing in Competitive, Monopolistic, and Monopolistically Competitive Markets

1) If the government sets a price ceiling below the monopoly price, will this reduce deadweight loss in a monopolized market?

MODULE 62: MONOPOLY & PUBLIC POLICY

Lecture 10 Monopoly Power and Pricing Strategies

Product Pricing with Monopoly Power

Pricing in a Competitive Market with a Common Network Resource

All these models were characterized by constant returns to scale technologies and perfectly competitive markets.

Second degree price discrimination

The economics of online personalised pricing

Final Exam 15 December 2006

BEE2017 Intermediate Microeconomics 2

SOLUTIONS TO HOMEWORK SET #4

Business Ethics Concepts & Cases

How To Calculate Profit Maximization In A Competitive Dairy Firm

Chapter 14 Monopoly Monopoly and How It Arises

Microeconomics Topic 7: Contrast market outcomes under monopoly and competition.

Market Power and Pricing Strategies

Learning Objectives. Chapter 6. Market Structures. Market Structures (cont.) The Two Extremes: Perfect Competition and Pure Monopoly

Examples on Monopoly and Third Degree Price Discrimination

Versioning Information Goods

Variable Cost. Marginal Cost. Average Variable Cost 0 $50 $50 $ $150 A B C D E F 2 G H I $120 J K L 3 M N O P Q $120 R

Dynamic Pricing and Revenue Management Lecture 3: Price Differentiation

Cooleconomics.com Monopolistic Competition and Oligopoly. Contents:

Price Discrimination

Profit maximization in different market structures

1. Supply and demand are the most important concepts in economics.

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

Econ 101: Principles of Microeconomics

CHAPTER 10 MARKET POWER: MONOPOLY AND MONOPSONY

Final Exam Microeconomics Fall 2009 Key

Problem Set 9 (75 points)

Advertising. Sotiris Georganas. February Sotiris Georganas () Advertising February / 32

MICROECONOMICS II PROBLEM SET III: MONOPOLY

CHAPTER 12 MARKETS WITH MARKET POWER Microeconomics in Context (Goodwin, et al.), 2 nd Edition

ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS (TUTORIAL)

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

Chapter 14: Pricing. Figure 14.1: The Structure of E-Commerce

Part IV. Pricing strategies and market segmentation. Chapter 8. Group pricing and personalized pricing

Economics Chapter 7 Review

CHAPTER 18 MARKETS WITH MARKET POWER Principles of Economics in Context (Goodwin et al.)

N. Gregory Mankiw Principles of Economics. Chapter 15. MONOPOLY

Oligopoly: How do firms behave when there are only a few competitors? These firms produce all or most of their industry s output.

MPP 801 Monopoly Kevin Wainwright Study Questions

Efficient Access Pricing and Endogenous Market. Structure. Kaniska Dam, Axel Gautier and Manipushpak Mitra CAHIER DE RECHERCHE / WORKING PAPER

How To Price Bundle On Cable Television

Chapter 8 Production Technology and Costs 8.1 Economic Costs and Economic Profit

1 of 14 11/5/2013 4:33 PM

Chapter 7: Market Structures Section 1

Transcription:

Lecture 9: Price Discrimination EC 105. Industrial Organization. Fall 2011 Matt Shum HSS, California Institute of Technology September 9, 2011 September 9, 2011 1 / 23

Outline Outline 1 Perfect price discrimination 2 Third-degree price discrimination: pricing-to-market 3 Second-degree price discrimination 4 Bundling 5 Durable goods and secondary markets 6 Pharmaceutical pricing after patent expiration C 105. Industrial Organization. Fall 2011 ( Matt Shum HSS, California LectureInstitute 9: Price of Discrimination Technology) September 9, 2011 2 / 23

Outline Price discrimination Up to now, consider situations where each firm sets one uniform price Consider cases where firm engages in non-uniform pricing: 1 Charging customers different prices for the same product (airline tickets) 2 Charging customers a price depending on the quantity purchased (electricity, telephone service) Consider three types of price discrimination: 1 Perfect price discrimination: charging each consumer a different price. Often infeasible. 2 Third-degree price discrimination: charging different prices to different groups of customers 3 Second-degree price discrimination: each customer pays her own price, depending on characteristics of purchase (bundling) Throughout, consider just monopoly firm. September 9, 2011 3 / 23

Perfect price discrimination Perfect price discrimination (PPD) 1 Graph. Monopolist sells product with downward-sloping demand curve Each consumer demands one unit: demand curve graphs number of consumers against their willingness-to-pay for the product. Perfect price discrimination: charge each consumer her WTP Perfectly discriminating monopolist produces more than regular monopolist: both produce at q where MC(q) = MR(q), but for PD monopolist MR(q) = p(q). PD monopolist produces at perfectly competitive outcome where p(q) = MC(q)! Perfectlly discriminating monopolist makes much higher profits (takes away all of the consumer surplus) September 9, 2011 4 / 23

Perfect price discrimination Perfect price discrimination (PPD) 2 This simple example illustrates: Profit motive for price discrimination In order for PPD to work, assume consumers can t trade with each other: no resale condition. With resale, marginal customer buys for whole market. Equivalent to assuming that monopolist knows the WTP of each consumer: if consumers could lie, same effect as resale (everybody underreports their WTP: public goods problem). Purchase constraints also prevent resale and support price discrimination: limit two per customer sales? Lower consumer welfare (no consumer surplus under PPD) but high output. When consumers demand more than one unit, but have varying WTP for each unit, firm may offer price schedules or quantity discounts (example: electricity, telephone pricing, TTC tokens) Next: focus on models where monopolist doesn t know the WTP of each consumer. September 9, 2011 5 / 23

Third-degree price discrimination: pricing-to-market 3rd-degree price discrimination (3PD) 1 Monopolist only knows demand functions for different groups of consumers (graph): groups differ in their price responsiveness Cannot distinguish between consumers in each group (ie., resale possible within groups, not across groups) Student vs. Adult tickets Journal subscriptions: personal vs. institutional Gasoline prices: urgent vs. non-urgent Main ideas: under optimal 3PD 1 Charge different price to different group, according to inverse-elasticity rule. Group with more elastic demand gets lower price. 2 Can increase consumer welfare: group with more elastic demand gets lower price under 3PD. September 9, 2011 6 / 23

Third-degree price discrimination: pricing-to-market 3rd-degree price discrimination (3PD) 2 Consider two groups of customers, with demand functions group 1: q 1 = 5 p group 2: q 2 = 5 2 p (graph) Assume: monopolist produces at zero costs September 9, 2011 7 / 23

Third-degree price discrimination: pricing-to-market 3rd-degree price discrimination (3PD) 3 If monopolist price-discriminates: max p1,p 2 p 1 (5 p 1 ) + p 2 (5 2 p 2 ). Given independent demands, solves the two problems separately. graph p PD 1 = 5 2 p PD 2 = 5 4 q PD 1 = 5 2 q PD 2 = 5 2 CS PD 1 = 25 8 CS PD 2 = 25 16 π PD 1 = 25 4 π PD 2 = 25 8 Compare with outcome when monopolist cannot price-discriminate. September 9, 2011 8 / 23

Third-degree price discrimination: pricing-to-market 3rd-degree price discrimination (3PD) 3 If monopolist doesn t price-discriminate (uniform pricing): max p π m = p (5 + 5 (1 + 2) p) = p (10 3p) p M 1 = 5 3 p M 2 = 5 3 q M 1 = 10 3 q M 2 = 5 3 CS M 1 = 50 9 CS M 2 = 25 36 π M 1 = 50 9 π M 2 = 25 9 September 9, 2011 9 / 23

Third-degree price discrimination: pricing-to-market 3rd-degree price-discrimination (3PD) 4 Effects of 3PD: 3PD affects distribution of income: higher price (lower demand) for group 1, lower price (higher demand) for group 2, relative to uniform price scheme Total production is same (5) under both scenarios (specific to this case). In general, if total output higher under 3PD, increases welfare in economy. Higher profits for monopolist under 3PD (always true: if he can 3PD, he can make at least as much as when he cannot) Compare per-unit consumer welfare (CS/q) for each group under two scenarios: (CS/q) M 1 = 5 3 = 1.67 (CS/q)M 2 = 5 12 = 0.42 (CS/q) PD 1 = 5 4 = 1.25 (CS/q)M 2 = 5 8 = 0.625 Group 2 gains; group 1 loses Compare weighted average of (CS/q) under two regimes: CS 1+CS 2 q 1+q 2 1 without PD: 1.25 2 with PD: 1.5625 Average consumer welfare higher under 3PD: specific to this model September 9, 2011 10 / 23

Third-degree price discrimination: pricing-to-market 3rd-degree price discrimination (3PD) 5 In general, price-discriminating monopolist follows inverse elasticity rule with respect to each group: (p i MC(q i )) p i or (assuming constant marginal costs) p i = 1 + 1 ɛ j p j 1 + 1 ɛ i = 1 ɛ i This is the Ramsey pricing rule : (roughtly speaking) consumers with less-elastic demands should be charged higher price Senior discounts Food at airports, ballparks, concerts Optimal taxation Caveat: this condition is satisfies only at optimal prices (and elasticity is usually a function of price) September 9, 2011 11 / 23

Second-degree price discrimination 2nd-degree price discrimination 1 Firm charges different price depending on characteristics of the purchase. These characteristics include: Amount purchased (nonlinear pricing). Examples: sizes of grocery products Bundle of products purchased (bundling, tie-ins). Examples: fast-food combos, cable TV Difference with 3rd-degree PD: here, assume that monopolist cannot classify consumers into groups, ie., it knows there are two groups of consumers, but doesn t know who belongs in what group. Set up a pricing scheme so that each type of consumer buys the amount that it should: rely on consumer self-selection Groups, or types, of consumers are distinguished by their willingness-to-pay for the firm s product. Characteristic of purchase is a signal of a consumer s type. So signal-contingent prices proxy for type-contingent prices. September 9, 2011 12 / 23

Second-degree price discrimination 2nd-degree price discrimination 2 Simple example: airline pricing Assume firm cannot distinguish between business travellers and tourists, but knows that the former are willing to pay much more for 1st-class seats. Formally: firm wants to price according to type (business or tourist) but cannot; therefore it does next best thing: set prices for 1st-class and coach seats so that consumers self-select. Airline chooses prices of first-class (p F ) vs. coach fares (p C ). such that business travellers choose first-class seats and tourists choose coach seats. This entails: 1 Ensuring that each type of traveller prefers his allocated seat (self-selection constraints): u B (first class) p F > u B (coach) p C (1) u T (coach) p C > u T (first class) p F (2) 2 Ensuring that u B (first class) p F > 0, and u T (coach) p C > 0, so that both types of travellers prefer travelling to not: participation constraints September 9, 2011 13 / 23

Second-degree price discrimination 2nd-degree price discrimination 3 Airline pricing example: add some numbers 2 travellers, one is business (B), and one is tourist (T), but monopolist doesn t know which. Plane has one first-class seat, and one coach seat. u B (F) = 1000 u B (C) = 400 u T (F) = 500 u T (C) = 300 If firm knew each traveller s type, charge p C = 300, and p F = 1000. But doesn t know type, so set p C, p F, subject to: 1000 p F 400 p C Type B buys first class (3) 300 p C 500 p F Type T buys coach (4) 1000 p F 0 Type B decides to travel (5) 300 p C 0 Type T decides to travel (6) September 9, 2011 14 / 23

Second-degree price discrimination 2nd-degree price discrimination 4 Solution to airline pricing example Charge p C = 300. Any higher would violate (6), and any lower would not be profit-maximizing. If charge p F = 1000, type B prefers coach seat: violate constraint (3). By constraint (3), type B must receive net utility from first-class of at least 100, which he would get from purchasing coach at price of 300. Thus upper bound on p F is 900, which leaves him with net utility=100. Lower bound on p F is 500, to prevent type T from prefering first-class. To maximize profits, charge the upper bound p F = 900. September 9, 2011 15 / 23

Second-degree price discrimination 2nd-degree price discrimination 5 In general: p C = u B (C): Charge low demand types their valuation (leaving them with zero net utility) p F = u F (F) (u F (C) p C ): Charge high demand types just enough to make them indifferent with the two options, given that low demand receive zero net utility. At optimal prices, only constraints 1 and 4 are binding: participation constraint for low type, and self-selection constraint for the high type = make low type indifferent between buying or not, and make high type indifferent between the high and low products General principle which holds when more than 2 types See this in next lecture. September 9, 2011 16 / 23

Bundling Bundling: indirect price discrimination Indirect price discrimination is pervasive, and many market institutions can be interpreted in this light. Stigler: Block booking Monopoly offers two movies: Gone with the Wind and Getting Gertie s Garter. There are movie theaters with high and low WTP for each movie: Theater WTP for GWW WTP for GGG A 8000 2500 B 7000 3000 Specific assumption about preferences: Theater A is high for GWW, and low for GGG. Theater B is low for GWW and high for GGG preferences for the two products are negatively correlated Monopolist would like to charge each theater a different price for GWW (same with GGG), but that is against the law. Question: does bundling the movies together allow you to price discriminate? September 9, 2011 17 / 23

Bundling Bundling 2 Without bundling, monopolist charges 7000 = min(8000, 7000) for GWW and 2500 = min(2500, 3000) for GGG. Total profits: 2 (7000 + 2500) = 19500. With bundling, monopolist charges 10000 = min(8000 + 2500, 7000 + 3000) for the bundle: profits = 2*10000 (higher) What about price discrimination? Akin to charging theater B 7000 and 3000 for GWW and GGG, and theater A 8000 and 2000. This will not work if preferences are not negatively correlated: Theater WTP for GWW WTP for GGG A 8000 2500 B 7000 1500 With or without bundling, preferences of theater B (low type) dictate market prices. September 9, 2011 18 / 23

Bundling Also will not work if extremely negatively correlated: Theater WTP for GWW WTP for GGG A 8000 10 B 20 4000 Here, monopolist maximizes profits by just selling GWW to A, and GGG to B: need one product to be better than other (cable TV bundling?) More generally, (this view of) bundling illustrates other methods of indirect price discrimination September 9, 2011 19 / 23

Durable goods and secondary markets Other examples Consider a simple durable goods market: cars live two periods (new/used) Consumer type WTP for new WTP for old Hi 8000 2000 Low 3000 3000 Without secondary markets, consumers can only buy new cars, and hold onto them for two periods. Pricing without secondary markets? Pricing with secondary markets? September 9, 2011 20 / 23

Pharmaceutical pricing after patent expiration Pharmaceutical pricing after patent expiration 84 Journal of Economics & Management Strategy FIGURE 2. Generic Entry and the Pricing of Pharmaceuticals 83 FIGURE 1. FIGURE 3. September 9, 2011 21 / 23

Pharmaceutical pricing after patent expiration Pharmaceutical pricing after patent expiration Generic Entry and the Pricing of Pharmaceuticals 87 Table III. Brand-Name Price Regression a Variable Fixed Effects TS Fixed Effects b TS Fixed Effects c NMFT 0.007 (2.25) NMFTHAT 0.011 0.016 (2.97) (3.96) Constant 1.487 1.479 1.486 (101.97) (95.12) (101.38) N 343 179 179 a Dependent variable: P B (t statistics in parentheses). b First-stage fixed-effects model (column 1 of Table II) c First-stage variance components with time trend (column 2 of Table II) What is going on? number of competitors. The parameter estimate suggests that each new entrant is associated with roughly a 0.7% rise in the brand-name price. The estimated models reported in the second and third columns of Table III each treat the number of competitors as endogenous. Recall that our two-stage estimators rely on rather strong assumptions about the information accounted for by the time trend measured by the time since patent expiration and the demand for brand-name drugs. For this EC 105. reason Industrial the results Organization. reported Fall 2011 below ( Matt should Shum HSS, be interpreted California LectureInstitute 9: cautiously. Price of Discrimination Technology) The September 9, 2011 22 / 23

Pharmaceutical pricing after patent expiration Conclusions Perfect PD: monopolist gets higher profits, consumers pay more 3rd-degree PD: monopolist gets high profits, but possible that consumers are better off. 2nd-degree PD: used when monopolist cannot distinguish between different types of consumers. Indirect price discrimination September 9, 2011 23 / 23