External Debt and Growth



Similar documents
What Are the Channels Through Which External Debt Affects Growth?

External Debt Sustainability Analysis 1

Formulas for the Current Account Balance

The economics of sovereign debt restructuring: Swaps and buybacks

Debt overhang and economic growth the Asian and the Latin American experiences

Determinants of Stock Market Performance in Pakistan

A non-linear Macroeconometric impact model of external debt cancellation in Severely Indebted Low Income Country (SILIC) economies

EFFECTS OF EXTERNAL FINANCIAL DEBT ON VARIOUS ECONOMIC SECTORS IN LATIN AMERICA. A thesis. Presented to the faculty

A full report of our recent meeting will be distributed to all the delegations. Let me briefly summarize some of the most salient conclusions.

Issue Paper on Debt Sustainability No.3. The Other Costs of High Debt in Poor Countries: Growth, Policy Dynamics, and Institutions

THE SUSTAINABILITY OF ROMANIA S EXTERNAL DEBT DURING THE RECENT FINANCIAL CRISIS

IS SOVEREIGN DEBT AN ISSUE FOR SUBSAHARAN AFRICA? By Fanwell Kenala Bokosi, PhD. Introduction

GAO. DEVELOPING COUNTRIES Challenges Confronting Debt Relief and IMF Lending to Poor Countries

THE GROUP OF 8 EXTERNAL DEBT CANCELLATION Effects and implications for Guyana

Chapter 13. Aggregate Demand and Aggregate Supply Analysis

The Liquidity Trap and U.S. Interest Rates in the 1930s

Real income (Y)

Building on International Debt Relief Initiatives. Testimony for the Senate Foreign Relations Committee

PROJECTION OF THE FISCAL BALANCE AND PUBLIC DEBT ( ) - SUMMARY

Econ 330 Exam 1 Name ID Section Number

Debt Relief, Investment and Growth

Debt Relief. Economics 426

Why a Floating Exchange Rate Regime Makes Sense for Canada

Reading the balance of payments accounts

Vol 2014, No. 10. Abstract

Latin America s Debt crisis 1980 s

MACROECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF VARIOUS PROPOSALS TO PROVIDE $500 BILLION IN TAX RELIEF

Fiscal Implications of Debt and Debt Relief: Issues Paper

Appendix 5. Heavily Indebted Poor Countries (HIPC) Initiative and

Economic Growth and Government Size. Mark Pingle Professor of Economics University of Nevada, Reno. and

Does Debt Relief enhance Growth in Third World Countries?

DOES COMMERCIAL BANK LENDING INCITE GROWTH? THE IMPACT OF COMMERCIAL LENDING ON REAL SECTOR GROWTH IN NIGERIA

Decomposition of External Capital Inflows and Outflows in the Small Open Transition Economy (The Case Analysis of the Slovak Republic)

THE IMPACT OF MACROECONOMIC FACTORS ON NON-PERFORMING LOANS IN THE REPUBLIC OF MOLDOVA

CHAPTER 11. AN OVEVIEW OF THE BANK OF ENGLAND QUARTERLY MODEL OF THE (BEQM)

Comments on \Do We Really Know that Oil Caused the Great Stag ation? A Monetary Alternative", by Robert Barsky and Lutz Kilian

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

Increasing farm debt amid decreasing interest rates: An explanation

The Federal Reserve System. The Structure of the Fed. The Fed s Goals and Targets. Economics 202 Principles Of Macroeconomics

HAS FINANCE BECOME TOO EXPENSIVE? AN ESTIMATION OF THE UNIT COST OF FINANCIAL INTERMEDIATION IN EUROPE

Government Spending Multipliers in Developing Countries: Evidence from Lending by Official Creditors

The (mis)allocation of capital

Does financial openness lead to deeper domestic financial markets? *

Domestic Debt and its Impact on the Economy The Case of Kenya

Growth and volatility will define global economy in 2016, says PineBridge Investments

Republic of Tajikistan: Joint Bank-Fund Debt Sustainability Analysis

Lecture 4: The Aftermath of the Crisis

THE PROCESS OF PLANNING AND INSTITUTIONAL FRAMEWORK FOR POVERTY REDUCTION STRATEGY: THE CASE OF UGANDA.

HIPC DEBT RELIEF, THE DEBT SERVICE BURDEN AND POVERTY REDUCTION With a Special Reference to Uganda's Experience. Harpa Elín Haraldsdóttir

Government Expenditure Management and Control within the Framework of Ethiopian Economy


FISCAL POLICY* Chapter. Key Concepts

The Return of Saving

Exchange Rate Policy in the Policy Analysis Matrix

The International Crisis and Latin America: Growth Effects and Development Strategies. Vittorio Corbo Klaus Schmidt-Hebbel

China s Economic Reforms and Growth Prospects. Nicholas Lardy. Anthony M Solomon Senior Fellow. Peterson Institute for International Economics

Commentary: What Do Budget Deficits Do?

1 (a) Calculation of net present value (NPV) Year $000 $000 $000 $000 $000 $000 Sales revenue 1,600 1,600 1,600 1,600 1,600

In recent years, fiscal policy in China has been prudent. Fiscal deficits

FDI as a source of finance in imperfect capital markets Firm-Level Evidence from Argentina

Factoring Exchange Rate Policy into your Investment Strategy: Risks Facing Andean Countries

External Debt, Public Investment, and Growth in Low-Income Countries

Sovereign Debt Restructuring: What is the Problem? 1

Edmonds Community College Macroeconomic Principles ECON 202C - Winter 2011 Online Course Instructor: Andy Williams

Is the Forward Exchange Rate a Useful Indicator of the Future Exchange Rate?

A Brief Research Note on. Temasek Holdings. And Singapore: Mr. Madoff Goes to Singapore

Micro and macroeconomic determinants of net interest margin in the Albanian banking system ( )

Can Debt Relief Buy Growth?

DEBT SUSTAINABILITY FRAMEWORK FOR LOW INCOME COUNTRIES: POLICY AND RESOURCE IMPLICATIONS

Lecture17 Debt overhang, debt relief and poverty reduction in low-income countries

A BRIEF HISTORY OF BRAZIL S GROWTH

FINANCIALISATION AND EXCHANGE RATE DYNAMICS IN SMALL OPEN ECONOMIES. Hamid Raza PhD Student, Economics University of Limerick Ireland

Can Debt Relief Buy Growth?

Financial Market Outlook

China's debt - latest assessment SUMMARY

PROJECTIONS FOR THE PORTUGUESE ECONOMY: Box 1 Projection assumptions

The relationships between stock market capitalization rate and interest rate: Evidence from Jordan

Debt Dynamics and its Burden on National Economy: A Case Study of Pakistan ( )

Scottish Independence. Charting the implications of demographic change. Ben Franklin. I May 2014 I.

18 ECB STYLISED FACTS OF MONEY AND CREDIT OVER THE BUSINESS CYCLE

Long Term Business Financing Strategy For A Pakistan Business. Byco Petroleum Pakistan Limited

TRADE AND INVESTMENT IN THE NATIONAL ACCOUNTS This text accompanies the material covered in class.

The Business Credit Index

ASIAN DEVELOPMENT FUND (ADF) ADF X MIDTERM REVIEW MEETING. Update on the Status of Debt Relief

UNIVERSITY OF NOTTINGHAM. Discussion Papers in Economics THE CURRENCY DENOMINATION OF SOVEREIGN DEBT

2016 Comprehensive Capital Analysis and Review

Economics 101 Multiple Choice Questions for Final Examination Miller

Fiscal Stimulus Improves Solvency in a Depressed Economy

The Economic Impact of a U.S. Slowdown on the Americas

Adjusting to a Changing Economic World. Good afternoon, ladies and gentlemen. It s a pleasure to be with you here in Montréal today.

Bolivia's Debt Problem - Overview

STABILITY PROGRAMME

LECTURE NOTES ON MACROECONOMIC PRINCIPLES

On the Dual Effect of Bankruptcy

chapter: Aggregate Demand and Aggregate Supply Krugman/Wells 2009 Worth Publishers 1 of 58

EUROSYSTEM STAFF MACROECONOMIC PROJECTIONS FOR THE EURO AREA

Big Concepts. Balance of Payments Accounts. Financing International Trade. Economics 202 Principles Of Macroeconomics. Lecture 12

The Real Problem With Obama s Tax-Cut Priorities

Key elements of Monetary Policy

Keynote Speech, EIB/IMF Meeting, 23 October, Brussels

Transcription:

External Debt and Growth Catherine Pattillo, Hélène Poirson and Luca Ricci Reasonable levels of external debt that help finance productive investment may be expected to enhance growth, but beyond certain levels additional indebtedness may reduce growth. An IMF study estimates two critical turning points: when additional debt slows growth and when it contributes negatively to growth, making the country worse off. Over the past three decades, developing countries have borrowed large amounts, often at highly concessional interest rates (Chart 1). The hope was that these loans would put them on a faster development path through higher investment and faster growth. But as debt ratios reached very high levels in the 1980s, it became clear that for many of these countries, repayment would not just constrain economic performance but be virtually impossible. Thus, in the 1980s, several middle-income countries particularly in Latin America faced severe debt crises and, in the mid-1990s, the IMF and the World Bank launched the Heavily Indebted Poor Countries (HIPC) Initiative to bring the debt of lowincome countries most of which are in sub-saharan Africa to sustainable levels. Despite the importance of this issue and the public attention it has received, including from the Pope and rock stars, policymakers and economists around the world still have only a partial understanding of fundamental questions, such as Beyond what level does external debt impair economic performance? What is the quantitative effect of debt on economic growth for the typical developing country? Is the effect of debt on growth nonlinear in other words, does the effect on growth of additional debt vary, depending, for example, on the level of the debt stock? What are the channels through which debt affects growth?

What effect on growth can we expect from the debt reduction associated with the HIPC Initiative? We conducted a study that examined these questions, looking at nearly 100 developing countries over a 30-year period. Countries heavily dependent on oil exports, countries with populations of less than 400,000, and countries in transition are excluded from the analysis. What theory tells us Economic theory suggests that reasonable levels of borrowing by a developing country are likely to enhance its economic growth. Countries at early stages of development have small stocks of capital and are likely to have investment opportunities with rates of return higher than those in advanced economies. As long as they use the borrowed funds for productive investment and do not suffer from macroeconomic instability, policies that distort economic incentives, or sizable adverse shocks, growth should increase and allow for timely debt repayments. These predictions hold up even in theories based on the more realistic assumption that countries may not be able to borrow freely because of the risk of debt repudiation. Why do large levels of accumulated debt lead to lower growth? The best-known explanation comes from "debt overhang" theories, which show that if there is some likelihood that, in the future, debt will be larger than the country's repayment ability, expected debt-service costs will discourage further domestic and foreign investment and thus harm growth. Potential investors will fear that the more a country produces, the more it will be "taxed" by creditors to service the external debt, and thus they will be less willing to incur costs today for the sake of increased output in the future. This argument is represented in the debt "Laffer curve" (Chart 2), which posits that larger debt stocks tend to be associated with lower probabilities of debt repayment. On the upwardsloping or "good" section of the curve, increases in the face value of debt are associated with increases in expected debt repayment, while increases in debt reduce expected debt repayment on the downward-

sloping or "bad" section of the curve. Although the debt overhang models do not analyze the effects on growth explicitly, the implication is that large debt stocks lower growth partly by reducing investment. But in addition, the incentive effects associated with debt stocks tend to reduce the benefits to be expected from policy reforms that would enhance efficiency and growth, such as trade liberalization and fiscal adjustment: the government will be less willing to incur current costs if it perceives that the future benefit in terms of higher output will accrue partly to foreign lenders. Thus, some considerations suggest that, at reasonable levels of debt, further borrowing would be expected to have a positive effect on growth. Others stress that large accumulated debt stocks may be a hindrance to growth. Both these elements together imply that debt is likely to have nonlinear effects on growth. Although the debt overhang theories have not explicitly traced the effect on growth, it may be possible to extend and translate the debt Laffer curve posited by these models into a Laffer curve for the effect of debt on growth. Since the peak of the debt Laffer curve shows the point at which rising debt stocks begin acting as a tax on investment, policy reforms, or other activities that require up-front costs in exchange for future benefits, the peak may relate to the point at which debt begins to have a negative marginal impact on growth. How are debt and growth linked? In our study, we tried to find out if this type of curve exists, essentially asking, what is the link between debt and growth? To do this, we used various debt stock indicators, including a recent World Bank data set that measures the net present value of debt a measure that takes into account the fact that a significant part of the external debt is contracted at an interest rate below the prevailing market rate. This is important because most studies have simply considered debt ratios (to exports and to GDP) in nominal terms, whereas most countries sampled have

contracted debt at concessional rates meaning that the actual amount they will have to repay in the future is less than the face value of the debt. To properly identify the debt overhang effect through the above debt stock indicators, we also include the ratio of debt service to exports to control for any crowding-out effects arising from resources being spent on debt service instead of investment or growth-enhancing domestic spending. We found that debt does indeed seem to have an inverted-u relationship with growth (Chart 3, next page). When countries open up to foreign capital and start borrowing, the impact on growth is likely to be positive (moving from zero indebtedness to point A in Chart 3). As debt ratios increase beyond point A, additional debt eventually slows growth down even though the overall debt level continues to make a positive contribution to growth. Thus, point A can be considered as the growth-maximizing level of debt. When debt reaches point B, however, the overall contribution of debt turns negative: the country becomes worse off than in the case of no indebtedness. Besides confirming this inverted-u relationship between debt and growth, our study also quantifies the two critical turning points. The one we can identify with more confidence is point B: the overall contribution of debt to growth appears to become negative at 160-170 percent of exports and 35-40 percent of GDP (in net present value terms). The marginal impact appears to become negative (point A) at about half these levels, although our results do not allow us to estimate those levels precisely. The results also indicate that the growth differential between countries with low indebtedness (less than 100 percent of exports or 25 percent of GDP) and those with the highest indebtedness (more than 367 percent of exports or 95 percent of GDP) is, on average, in excess of 2 percent a year. Our results were found to be robust across the many specifications, methodologies, and debt indicators employed (see box). In particular, it

is interesting to note that debt indicators based on the face value or the net present value of debt generate similar results. This outcome is consistent with the fact that the countries that benefit from concessional lending (or from debt restructuring at concessional rates) are those that already have excessive indebtedness. Approach and methodology Our study uses multiple regression analysis to test whether debt and per capita growth are related. It controls for standard determinants of growth (lagged income per capita, the investment rate, secondary schooling, population growth rate (all in logs)); policy indicators (openness and the fiscal balance); and external shocks (terms of trade growth). The analysis uses 3-year average panel data for 93 developing countries over the period 1969-98. We also use 10- year averages to check the robustness of our findings to cyclical effects. We employ four estimation methodologies to test for robustness: (1) ordinary least squares; (2) instrumental variables using lagged values as instruments to correct for potential endogeneity of debt, investment, schooling, openness, and fiscal balance; (3) fixed effects to control for unobserved country-specific factors, such as institutional quality and history; and (4) system-gmm (generalized method of moments) to correct for endogeneity and for the bias introduced by the lagged income variable in the presence of fixed effects. In addition, to ensure that our results are not driven by timespecific effects or the presence of outliers, we estimate most regressions with and without time dummies, as well as with the full sample and with a reduced sample from which outliers are eliminated. Finally, we estimate the same specifications excluding investment to test whether investment is the main channel through which debt affects growth. To identify the turning point of the debt-growth Laffer curve (point A in Chart 3), we use two alternative nonlinear specifications: a quadratic and a spline function. We estimate a quadratic (inverted

U-curve) specification, where the debt variable is entered in both linear and quadratic terms, and then a spline (inverted V-shaped curve) specification, where the impact of debt can have a structural break, endogenously determined as the break that maximizes the fit of the regression. It still turns out to be very difficult to accurately estimate the turning point (point A in Chart 3) because of the limited variation in the growth experiences of countries with low indebtedness and those with low to moderate indebtedness. Does our study shed any light on how debt affects growth? It provides indirect evidence that the efficiency of investment not the quantity of investment might be the relevant channel. In fact, all of the results depicted above hold in regressions where investment is also controlled for, and the impact of debt on growth is only slightly stronger when we eliminate investment from the regressions. Thus, our results confirm the theoretical claims that excessive debt is likely to constrain growth not just by lowering how much is spent on investment activities but also by distorting their allocation (for example, toward projects with short-term horizons even if less efficient) and perhaps altering the incentives for policymakers to provide a healthy policy environment. This is consistent with recent empirical claims that total factor productivity rather than factor accumulation is the main determinant of growth differences across countries. Implications for HIPC Initiative What might our findings imply for policymakers? The growth dividend that may be expected from debt reduction can be quantified. For example, halving indebtedness from, say, 200 percent of exports (close to the debt-to-export ratio carried by the average country in the sample over the past three decades) to 100 percent of exports would boost per capita growth by about a half to a full percentage point. How about the heavily indebted poor countries? For most of those countries on the verge of being approved for debt relief, debt-to-export ratios average about 300 percent. If their debt loads were lowered to

the target of 150 percent, our study seems to indicate that this would raise growth by about 1 percentage point. This increase in growth might initiate a virtuous cycle that, in the absence of additional increases in debt levels, would help to further reduce indebtedness ratios. Clearly, however, such a growth dividend might not occur because these economies are often severely affected by other macroeconomic and structural distortions. This article is based on the authors' "External Debt and Growth," IMF Working Paper 02/69 (Washington, 2002). References: Guillermo A. Calvo, 1998, "Growth, Debt and Economic Transformation: The Capital Flight Problem" in New Theories in Growth and Development, ed. by Fabrizio Coricelli, Massimo di Matteo, and Frank Hahn (New York: St. Martin's Press). Daniel Cohen, 1991, Private Lending to Sovereign States: A Theoretical Autopsy (Cambridge, Massachusetts: MIT Press)., 1997, "Growth and External Debt: A New Perspective on the African and Latin American Tragedies," Center for Economic Policy Research Discussion Paper No. 1753 (London). William Easterly, 2001, "Growth Implosions, Debt Explosions, and My Aunt Marilyn: Do Growth Slowdowns Cause Public Debt Crises?" World Bank Policy Research Working Paper No. 2531 (Washington). and Ross Levine, 2001, "What Have We Learned from a Decade of Empirical Research on Growth? It's Not Factor Accumulation: Stylized Facts and Growth Models," World Bank Economic Review, Vol. 15, No. 2 (August), pp. 177-219. Ibrahim Elbadawi, Benno Ndulu, and Njuguna Ndung'u, 1997, "Debt Overhang and Economic Growth in Sub-Saharan Africa," in

External Finance for Low-Income Countries, ed. by Zubair Iqbal and Ravi Kanbur (Washington: International Monetary Fund).