Comments on Who Pays? A Distributional Analysis of the Tax Systems in All 50 States (Second Edition)

Similar documents
budget brief On Tuesday, August 3, legislative leaders proposed a new budget plan, including a tax swap that would increase some

Details and Analysis of Dr. Ben Carson s Tax Plan

A Comparison of the Tax Burden on Labor in the OECD By Kyle Pomerleau

A Dynamic Analysis of President Obama s Tax Initiatives

ITEP. Tax Reform in Kentucky. Serious Problems, Stark Choices. Institute on Taxation and Economic Policy. Institute on Taxation and Economic Policy

Details and Analysis of Senator Bernie Sanders s Tax Plan

Executive Summary. 204 N. First St., Suite C PO Box 7 Silverton, OR fax

Executive Summary Findings Policy Options I. Introduction II. Total State and Local Tax Systems III. Income Taxes...

The Economic Effects of Adopting the Corporate Tax Rates of the OECD, the UK, and Canada

Hard Choices: Revenue-Raising Options for Alaska. Citizens for Tax Justice Alaska Common Ground April 2004

A Comparison of the Tax Burden on Labor in the OECD

Average Federal Income Tax Rates for Median-Income Four-Person Families

INDEPENDENT FISCAL OFFICE Matthew Knittel, Director Testimony Before the Senate Finance Committee June 10, 2015

Governor Walker's Tax Reform Initiative. Wisconsin Department of Revenue February 2013

Eliminating Double Taxation through Corporate Integration

The Consequences of Increasing Oregon s Income Tax Deduction for Federal Income Taxes Paid

Understanding the Math of Roth IRA Conversions

CONGRESS OF THE UNITED STATES CONGRESSIONAL BUDGET OFFICE CBO. The Distribution of Household Income and Federal Taxes, 2008 and 2009

Looking for Tax Revenue in All the Wrong Places: 401(k) Plans Under Attack

Chapter 4: Key Conclusions from the Evaluation of the Current Washington Tax Structure

Is the Tax Code the Proper Tool for Making Higher Education More Affordable?

MEASURING INCOME FOR DISTRIBUTIONAL ANALYSIS. Joseph Rosenberg Urban-Brookings Tax Policy Center July 25, 2013 ABSTRACT

Note: This feature provides supplementary analysis for the material in Part 3 of Common Sense Economics.

Amendment 66 will improve Colorado s income tax

Kentucky and its Neighbors: How Different, How Similar Taxes?

NASFAA FAFSA WORKING GROUP REPORT FAFSA SIMPLIFICATION

Tax: Are we paying our fair share?

Notes - Gruber, Public Finance Chapter 20.3 A calculation that finds the optimal income tax in a simple model: Gruber and Saez (2002).

Lesson Description. Grade Level. Concepts. Objectives. Content Standards

The Consequences of Increasing Oregon s Income Tax Deduction for Federal Income Taxes Paid

Jobs and Growth Effects of Tax Rate Reductions in Ohio

Corporate Income Tax Rates and Base Broadening from Income Shifting

Policy Brief: Property Tax Relief for Low- and Middle-Income Property New Yorkers Must Remain a Priority

DATA AND CHART PACK February 2016

Income Tax RESEARCH POLICY PAPER

Roth IRA Conversion... Does Taking Action Get You to Point A or Point B

Tax Subsidies for Health Insurance An Issue Brief

cepr briefing paper Defaulting on The Social Security Trust Fund Bonds: Winner and Losers CENTER FOR ECONOMIC AND POLICY RESEARCH SUMMARY Dean Baker 1

The District of Columbia Considers Impressive Tax Reform Options

Chapter 10 Fiscal Policy Macroeconomics In Context (Goodwin, et al.)

The primary purpose of a tax system is to support public goods and services. State and local taxes

An Analysis of SB 535 s Proposed Corporate and Personal Income Tax Capital Gains Tax Cut

United States General Accounting Office. Testimony Before the Committee on Finance, United States Senate

Finance, Saving, and Investment

Topsy-Turvy State Income Tax Deductions for Federal Income Taxes Turn Tax Fairness on its Head

Supplemental Unit 5: Fiscal Policy and Budget Deficits

Macroeconomics 2301 Potential questions and study guide for exam 2. Any 6 of these questions could be on your exam!

A Hand Up: An Earned Income Credit Will Help Working Families

Taxing Capital Gains FREQUENTLY ASKED QUESTIONS: To Build A Better Future For Our Children: WHAT ARE CAPITAL GAINS?

What colleges do for local economies: A direct measure based on consumption

Why 529 College Savings Plans Favor the Fortunate

Five Flaws of the Current Pension System

Promoting home ownership: How the FairTax s benefits for homeowners exceed the mortgage interest deduction

How Would Expanding Oregon s Deduction for Federal Income Taxes Paid Affect Elderly Oregonians? A Distributional Analysis of Ballot Measures 88 and 91

This chapter introduces some basic principles for evaluating your state s tax

Different nonprofits devote different

THE IRA PROPOSAL CONTAINED IN S. 1682: EFFECTS ON LONG-TERM REVENUES AND ON INCENTIVES FOR SAVING. Staff Memorandum November 2, 1989

AN OVERVIEW OF STATE INCOME TAXES ARKANSAS AND SURROUNDING STATES

Would a significant increase in the top income tax rate substantially alter income inequality?

Statistical Bulletin. The Effects of Taxes and Benefits on Household Income, 2011/12. Key points

Macroeconomics Machine-graded Assessment Items Module: Fiscal Policy

The Wealth of Households: An Analysis of the 2013 Survey of Consumer Finances

Employer Frequently Asked Questions

National Small Business Network

Simplify and Focus the Education Tax Incentives. June, 2006

employee benefits update october/november 2011

Chapter 1 Lecture Notes: Economics for MBAs and Masters of Finance

SOME STATES SCALING BACK TAX CREDITS FOR LOW- INCOME FAMILIES Measures Would Increase Poverty, Slow Job Growth By Nicholas Johnson and Erica Williams

IRA Opportunities. Traditional IRA vs. Roth IRA: Which is right for you? What kind of retirement funding vehicle is right for you?

Tax Relief for Low-Income Arkansans

How To Understand And Understand The Tax System In Colo

Tax Expenditures and Social Policy: A Primer

Retirement incomes. Aisur. Submission to the Tax White Paper Task Force. July 2015

April 8,2005 JEFFREY KUPFER, EXECUTIVE DIRECTOR PRESIDENT S ADVISORY PANEL ON FEDERAL TAX REFORM

Brendan Wood Business Solutions GAMING MACHINES ARRANGEMENT REVIEW

The Beneficiaries of the Dividend Tax Rate Reduction: A Profile of Qualified Dividend Shareholders

Under current tax law, health insurance premiums are largely taxexempt

A super waste of money

INTERACTION OF AUTOMATIC IRAS AND THE RETIREMENT SAVINGS CONTRIBUTIONS CREDIT (SAVER S CREDIT)

MICHIGAN EARNED INCOME TAX CREDIT Tax Year 2013

The tax package adopted by Gov. Rick Snyder and

ANSWERS TO END-OF-CHAPTER QUESTIONS

A HAND UP How State Earned Income Tax Credits Help Working Families Escape Poverty in Summary. By Joseph Llobrera and Bob Zahradnik

ira individual retirement accounts Traditional IRA

MANAGEMENT OPTIONS AND VALUE PER SHARE

Life Insurance Companies and Products

HANDOUTS Property Taxation Review Committee

PREVIEW. California Tax Facts. An Overview of the Golden State s Tax Structure

The Tax Benefits and Revenue Costs of Tax Deferral

Governor LePage s Tax Reform and Relief Plan

The Impact on Inequality of Raising the Social Security Retirement Age

Background Paper 79-1 PROPERTY TAX RELIEF

Where you hold your investments matters. Mutual funds or ETFs? Why life insurance still plays an important estate planning role

Poverty among ethnic groups

THE GRADUATED PERSONAL INCOME TAX ASSESSMENT: FREQUENTLY ASKED QUESTIONS

Selected Options to Raise Over $100 Billion in 2012 to Fund Health Care Reform (Revenue Impact in Billions of Dollars)

Eric T. Thoele Income Tax Inequalities. Intermediate Macroeconomics EC3100 Rockhurst University. Dr. Gerald Miller 03/31/05

Suggested Solutions to Assignment 3 (Optional)

Chapter 12: Gross Domestic Product and Growth Section 1

Issue Brief. Tax Relief from the Phase-down of the Personal Income Tax Disproportionately Goes to Illinois Wealthiest

Transcription:

FISCAL FACT Jan. 2015 No. 447 Comments on Who Pays? A Distributional Analysis of the Tax Systems in All 50 States (Second Edition) By Liz Malm & Kyle Pomerleau Economist Economist Key Findings The Institute on Taxation and Economic Policy (ITEP) released the fifth edition of its biennial study, Who Pays? A Distributional Analysis of the Tax System in All 50 States. We fifnd six key issues with the report and its fifndings. They are: 1. The study isn t focused on the distribution of taxes by income group, but rather, it is focused on how well state and local tax systems redistribute income. 2. The study includes one regressive portion of the federal income tax but fails to include any discussion of the federal income tax as a whole, even though it is highly progressive. 3. The study includes discussion of tax exporting in its explanation of property taxes but doesn t discuss tax exporting as it relates to other taxes. 4. The study ignores severance taxes and broad-based business taxes other than corporate income taxes. 5. The study refers to a problematic report completed by Standard and Poor s to prove its point. 6. The study recommends making tax policy changes that would cause tax revenue volatility and economic harm.

2 Every two years, the Institute on Taxation and Economic Policy (ITEP) publishes a study called Who Pays? A Distributional Analysis of the Tax Systems in All 50 States. Yesterday, the fifth edition was released. The report assess[es] the fairness of state and local tax systems by measuring the state and local taxes that will be paid in 2015 by different income groups as a share of their incomes. The report s key measure is the effective tax rate faced by various income groups when we consider state and local property, sales, excise, individual income, and corporate income taxes. Somewhat surprisingly, ITEP finds that every single state tax system is regressive, taxing lower income individuals more than they tax the wealthy. Here are six issues we found with the latest edition of Who Pays? (Note that several of these are similar to critiques we made regarding the 2013 edition of the report, which still stand two years later.) (1) The study isn t focused on the distribution of taxes by income group. Instead, it s focused on how well state and local tax systems redistribute income. Because of what it measures, Who Pays? is better characterized as a report about whether a state s tax code does a good job of redistributing income by making the rich less rich after taxes and the poor less poor. If the report was really about measuring the state and local taxes... paid by different income groups, ITEP would rank states by effective tax rates of the poorest residents. Instead, states are ranked based on a complex formula that compares various measures of pre- and after-tax income for various income groups. ITEP s formula for this Inequality Index is below. IIIIIIII IIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIII IIIIIIIIII = AAAAAAAAAA tttttt iiiiiiiiiiii oooo tttttt 1% AAAAAAAAAA tttttt iiiiiiiiiiii oooo tttttt 1% PPPPPP tttttt iiiiiiiiiiii oooo tttttt 1% PPPPPP tttttt iiiiiiiimmmm oooo tttttt 1% ( ) + ( ) + AAAAAAAAAA tttttt iiiiiiiiiiii oooo bbbbbbbbbbbb 20% AAAAAAAAAA tttttt iiiiiiiiiiii oooo mmmmmmmmmmmm 60% 1 [ PPPPPP tttttt iiiiiiiiiiii oooo bbbbbbbbbbbb 20% PPPPPP tttttt iiiiiiiiiiii oooo mmmmmmmmmmmm 60% 3 ( According to ITEP: AAAAAAAAAA tttttt iiiiiiiiiiii oooo tttttt 20% ( 1 2 ) ( PPPPPP tttttt iiiiiiiiiiii oooo tttttt 20% AAAAAAAAAA tttttt iiiiiiiiiiii oooo bbbbbbbbbbmm 40% PPPPPP tttttt iiiiiiiiiiii oooo bbbbbbbbbbbb 40% ) )] States with regressive tax structures have negative tax inequality indexes, meaning that incomes are less equal in those states after state and local taxes than before. States with progressive tax structures have positive tax inequality indexes; incomes are more equal after state and local taxes than before. If the goal is to measure redistribution, the ITEP Inequality Index isn t a good measure to use. Most tax redistribution happens at the federal level with the highly progressive federal income tax (which we ll address in our second point, below). Any income redistribution measure needs to include the spending side, as that s where most of the actual redistribution happens. To frame this in Robin Hood terms, the taking from the rich occurs predominantly on the tax side, and the giving to the poor occurs predominantly on the spending side. In 2013, we found that spending

3 (federal, state, and local combined) primarily benefits the lowest income families in America. For example, the bottom 20 percent of American families received more back in total government spending than they pay in total taxes. In 2012, they received $5.28 back in government spending for every $1 they paid in taxes. The top 1 percent, conversely, received only $0.06 back in spending for every dollar of taxes paid. Spending at both the federal and state and local level is progressive (but more so at the federal level). The point is that leaving spending out paints an incomplete picture of the government s redistributive policies. ITEP s Inequality Index relies on arbitrary break points for its rankings. Is income equality achieved when the after-tax income of the top 1 percent equals the aftertax income of the bottom 1 percent? Is it when the after-tax income of the top 1 percent is equal to the after-tax income of the bottom 20 percent? If the percentage ranges in the Inequality Index formula was changed (say from top 1 percent to top 10 percent or from bottom 20 percent to bottom 30 percent), the state rankings would likely change. The point of the ITEP report is not to actually rank the states but to showcase ITEP s preferred tax structure in light of its conclusion that all state tax systems are regressive, even if doing so means leaving a lot of relevant contextual information out of the report and including inconsistent assumptions. (2) Including the federal offset but leaving out the progressive federal income tax. Perhaps the most problematic part of ITEP s report is its selective inclusion of federal policy. When ITEP presents effective state and local tax rates they also include what is known as the federal offset. The federal income tax code allows taxpayers who itemize their deductions to claim tax payments to state and local governments as a deduction. ITEP argues that since this benefit disproportionately helps high-income taxpayers lower their total tax bill, it should be accounted for in an analysis of regressivity. While it is true that this deduction is primarily taken by higher-income taxpayers, it is misleading to include this one regressive feature of the federal tax code in a study of state tax systems, while excluding the rest of the highly progressive federal tax code. When the federal offset is not included in the calculations of state and local effective rates, ITEP s regressivity conclusions are much less severe. (ITEP relegates pre-federal offset effective rates in its appendices, not in its main discussion of results.) ITEP also breaks the top quintile into three smaller income groups, making the difference between the richest and the poorest appear much more pronounced. In

4 the charts below, we present the top quintile as a whole, rather than breaking it up into smaller income groups (breaking out the bottom 20 percent into smaller income groups and showing their effective rate would be a good compromise). Figure 1 shows the U.S. average of state and local effective tax rates, with and without the federal offset. Figure 1. State and Local Effective Tax Rates by U.S. Totals 12% 10% 8% 10.9% 10.9% 9.9% 10.0% 9.4% 9.7% 8.7% Including Federal Offset Excluding Federal Offset 9.3% 7.4% 8.5% 6% 4% 2% 0% Bottom Second Middle Source: Institute on Taxation and Economic Policy; Tax Foundation calculations. Fourth Top Correcting these problems still produces a mildly regressive result but one far less pronounced than ITEP asserts: the difference is only 2.4 percentage points between the highest 20 percent and the lowest 20 percent, rather than the 5.5 point difference between the highest 1 percent and the lowest 20 percent originally presented in the report. Including the federal offset makes effective tax rates look more regressive than they actually are. Related to this point, if ITEP believes it s important to include the federal offset in the discussion of state and local taxes, it should be equally important to also include the amount of federal taxes paid by various income groups, because it provides important context for ITEP s results. Figure 2 shows federal effective tax rates for 2013 as reported by the Urban-Brookings Tax Policy Center. Though these are a bit outdated, general trends today will be similar. These federal rates are presented alongside ITEP s national average effective state and local tax rates by income quintile to demonstrate the high degree of progressivity of federal effective rates compared to state and local effective rates. Figure 3 shows the two types of effective rates combined to demonstrate the progressivity of the tax system as a whole federal, state, and local combined.

5 Figure 2. Effective Tax Rates by Federal vs. State and Local 30% Federal Taxes (as reported by Tax Policy Center) 28.1% 30% State and Local Taxes (as reported by ITEP) 25 25 20 19.0% 20 15 15.6% 15 10 9.5% 10 10.9% 9.9% 9.4% 8.7% 7.4% 5 5 1.9% 0 Bottom Second Middle Fourth Top 0 Bottom Second Middle Fourth Top Source: Urban-Brookings Tax Policy Center, Institute on Taxation and Economic Policy. Figure 3. Effective Tax Rates by Combined Federal and State & Local 40% 30 35.5% 30 27.7% 25 25.0% 20 19.4% 15 12.8% 10 5 0 Bottom Second Middle Fourth Top Source: Tax Foundation calculations. Federal effective rates are much more progressive than state and local effective rates. When the entirety of the tax system is examined, the top 20 percent of individuals pay a much larger percentage of their income in taxes than the other four income groups. ITEP should not pick and choose which federal tax policy information to include in their analysis, because doing so skews the results in favor of their desired outcome.

6 (3) Treatment of tax exporting. ITEP assumes that business property taxes are partly passed on by business owners to renters, and that some of these business taxes are exported across state lines: The business tax component reduces the regressivity of the property tax as it generally falls on owners of capital and to a significant degree is exported to residents of other states. On average this study finds that about 40 percent of a typical state s property taxes fall on business (excluding the portion of apartment taxes that is assigned to renters). However, the same logic should also apply to several other tax types. Corporate income and sales taxes are partially exported, because a portion of them are paid by businesses. However, ITEP does not assume tax exporting for any tax other than property taxes. Not accounting for a portion of the sales tax that is exported is especially problematic, because it assumes all sales taxes in a state are borne by state residents, when in fact they are likely borne by the residents of other states in the form of higher prices. (4) Exclusion of other taxes from the analysis ignores significant portions of some state budgets. Similarly, ITEP does not include taxes such as severance taxes, business license taxes, and other types of business taxes (such as gross receipts taxes and modified gross receipts taxes) in its analysis. This is problematic, because in some states, these taxes make up a significant share of the state budget and significantly alter the over distributional impact of a state s tax system. For example, 68.7 percent of total state and local taxes in Alaska were severance taxes in fiscal year 2012 (the most recent data available). Ignoring two-thirds of a state s tax system while making broad statements about the state s overall regressivity does not present an accurate picture. Similarly, several states depend on gross receipts taxes, modified gross receipts taxes, and business license taxes, but these are not included in the report. For example, in 2012, Delaware obtained over 35 percent of total taxes from taxes other than sales, income, excise, or property taxes much of these are business license fees and Delaware s gross receipts tax. Again, these are an important part of some state tax codes. These omissions are related to why Washington State is shown as the most regressive state in the nation. The Census Bureau, the main data source for state and local tax researchers, inaccurately classifies Washington s gross receipts tax on businesses as a sales tax. This makes Washington s sales tax collections look much higher than they actually are and thus makes ITEP allocate more taxes than it should to lower income groups in Washington. (Note that this classification of Washington s

7 gross receipts tax was confirmed via direct email correspondence with the Census Bureau.) (5) Citation of Standard and Poor s report on income inequality. A new feature of the fifth edition of ITEP s report is a discussion of a Standard & Poor s (S&P) report from September 2014 linking state income inequality to state tax revenues. ITEP states: [A] September 2014 Standard & Poor s (S&P) study concludes that rising income inequality can make it more difficult for state tax systems to pay for needed services over time. The more income that goes to the wealthy, the slower a state s revenue grows. Digging deeper, S&P also found that not all states have been affected in the same way by rising inequality. States that rely heavily on sales taxes tend to be hardest hit by growth income inequality, while states that rely heavily on personal income taxes don t experience the same negative effects. While the report does show a correlation between inequality and state tax revenue growth, these types of analyses can be riddled with confounding factors or issues that make this conclusion less clear cut. It may not be the case that inequality has a direct effect on state tax revenue in states that rely heavily on sales taxes. It may have more to do with how states structure those sales taxes and how the economy has changed over time. A sales tax works best when it is levied evenly on all final consumption. Many states break from this ideal and have large sales tax exemptions, especially for services such as legal fees. This has had a large impact on revenue growth given that the United States economy has shifted away from a goods economy and more toward a service economy (see Figure 4). The result is a shrinking tax base for state sales taxes. Coincidently, this shift has occurred at the same time that S&P has seen increasing income inequality. The S&P report may just be observing two independent trends that are happening simultaneously.

8 Figure 4. Percent of Total Personal Consumption Expenditures Goods vs. Services, U.S. (1929 2013) 100% 90 80 70 Services 60 50 40 Goods 30 20 10 0 1929 1934 1939 1944 1949 1954 1959 1964 1969 1974 1979 1984 1989 1994 1999 2004 2009 Source: Bureau of Economic Analysis, National and Product Accounts (Personal and Outlays). Another issue with the S&P report is that their measure of inequality is flawed. They measure inequality using IRS data on adjusted gross income (AGI), which is a narrower concept than what most of us consider income. One of the biggest issues with AGI is its treatment of investment income, or the income one earns from saving in a tax-deferred retirement account: U.S. households have $19.8 trillion worth of pension entitlements. Every single dollar in a 401(k), Traditional IRA, or employer-sponsored plan, public or private, has never once been counted by the IRS as anyone s income. In 2013, for example, pension funds had assets of $18.9 trillion, all of which was earned by somebody. None of that money has yet showed up on an individual tax return. A lot of pension income accrues to individuals in middle and lower income quintiles, income that the IRS never sees. In contrast, wealthier individuals usually earn investment income that is not tax deferred and is measured by the IRS in AGI, skewing the measure of capital income toward the top. Changes in income inequality depend a lot on how you measure income. It is entirely likely that this report overstates the growth in inequality.

9 (6) ITEP s idea tax system (no sales tax, very progressive income tax with lots of taxation of capital gains, and heavy reliance on individual income taxes) would lead to volatile tax systems that dampen economic growth. ITEP s report characterizes several features of state tax systems as either regressive or progressive. States are criticized for having narrow income tax brackets that don t tax higher income levels at high enough rates, the lack of high taxes on capital gains income, a high reliance on sales and excise taxes, or not having a state income tax. States are praised for relying little on consumption taxes, having graduated income tax structures that tax high income levels at comparatively higher rates, and using refundable tax credits such as the Earned Tax Credits. ITEP s ideal tax structure would result in a state with significant year-to-year revenue volatility. tax revenues are more volatile than sales taxes or property taxes, and the more they rely on high-income earners, the more volatile they are. Using state and local government finance data from the Census Bureau, we analyzed the U.S. totals of various combined state and local tax revenue sources to identify the most volatile sources of tax revenue from year to year. Figure 5 shows the annual percentage change in various types of state and local tax revenues. Figure 5. Annual Percentage Change in Tax Collections U.S. Totals by Tax Type (FY 1978 FY 2012) 40% 30 Property Tax Sales Tax Individual Tax Corporate Tax 20 10 0-10 -20-30 1978 1983 1988 1993 1998 2003 2008 Source: Census Bureau. According to this Census data, the most volatile source of state and local government tax revenues in the U.S. is corporate income taxes, followed by individual income taxes, then sales taxes, then property taxes. While it is true that income tax revenues (both corporate and individual) grow faster than the economy

10 when the economy is in an upswing, the reverse is also true: when the economy dips, these dip faster, too. ITEP s ideal tax system relies heavily even exclusively on these volatile elements. Flatter income taxes are less volatile over the business cycle, while graduated income taxes are much more unstable. ITEP praises the least regressive states that have high reliance on PIT [personal income tax]. But depending largely on a volatile source of revenue can cause budget issues in economic downturns. Comparing 2009 and 2007 IRS data, we found that not only did the number of millionaires fall by 40 percent during the recession, but the overall income of millionaires fell by 50 percent. The result for the U.S. Treasury was that 54 percent of the total drop in tax revenues during this period was due to the falling tax collections from millionaires. Though this example uses federal tax collections, the principle still applies to state and local governments. The more a government relies on volatile sources of revenue, the more unstable overall funding will be when the economy dips. Another consequence of depending more on income taxes and less on sales taxes is the impact on economic growth. Two years ago, we published a review of the academic literature on the relationship between taxes and growth. Within this study, we examined the work that distinguishes between tax types that is, what types of taxes have a larger negative growth impact. Researchers found that the taxes most harmful to growth were corporate and individual income taxes, followed by taxes on consumption. The least harmful were taxes on property. ITEP suggests states move away from sales taxes. Conclusion The Tax Foundation is a 501(c)(3) non-partisan, non-profift research institution founded in 1937 to educate the public on tax policy. Based in Washington, D.C., our economic and policy analysis is guided by the principles of sound tax policy: simplicity, neutrality, transparency, and stability. Overall, fairness is a subjective term and largely depends on how you define it. Despite this, there are some methodological concerns and some concerns with the way ITEP presents data that should be addressed. On top of this, it is important to point out the caveats of depending on one type of tax over another. While acknowledging the degree of progressivity or regressivity of a tax is a worthy pursuit, focusing only on that when making tax policy recommendations can lead to some undesirable economic and budgetary side effects. 2015 Tax Foundation Editor, Donnie Johnson Designer, Dan Carvajal Tax Foundation National Press Building 1325 G Street, NW, Suite 950 Washington, DC 20005 202.464.6200 taxfoundation.org