Optimization of Setting Take-Profit Levels for Derivative Trading

Similar documents
MTH6121 Introduction to Mathematical Finance Lesson 5

Term Structure of Prices of Asian Options

Chapter 7. Response of First-Order RL and RC Circuits

Optimal Investment and Consumption Decision of Family with Life Insurance

Optimal Stock Selling/Buying Strategy with reference to the Ultimate Average

Technical Appendix to Risk, Return, and Dividends

DYNAMIC MODELS FOR VALUATION OF WRONGFUL DEATH PAYMENTS

A general decomposition formula for derivative prices in stochastic volatility models

= r t dt + σ S,t db S t (19.1) with interest rates given by a mean reverting Ornstein-Uhlenbeck or Vasicek process,

Journal Of Business & Economics Research September 2005 Volume 3, Number 9

An Optimal Selling Strategy for Stock Trading Based on Predicting the Maximum Price


Verification Theorems for Models of Optimal Consumption and Investment with Retirement and Constrained Borrowing

Option Pricing Under Stochastic Interest Rates

A Generalized Bivariate Ornstein-Uhlenbeck Model for Financial Assets

INTEREST RATE FUTURES AND THEIR OPTIONS: SOME PRICING APPROACHES

Working Paper On the timing option in a futures contract. SSE/EFI Working Paper Series in Economics and Finance, No. 619

ON THE PRICING OF EQUITY-LINKED LIFE INSURANCE CONTRACTS IN GAUSSIAN FINANCIAL ENVIRONMENT

Stochastic Optimal Control Problem for Life Insurance

SPEC model selection algorithm for ARCH models: an options pricing evaluation framework

The option pricing framework

Optimal Time to Sell in Real Estate Portfolio Management

Cointegration: The Engle and Granger approach

Individual Health Insurance April 30, 2008 Pages

ARCH Proceedings

Random Walk in 1-D. 3 possible paths x vs n. -5 For our random walk, we assume the probabilities p,q do not depend on time (n) - stationary

A Probability Density Function for Google s stocks

A Note on Using the Svensson procedure to estimate the risk free rate in corporate valuation

Mathematics in Pharmacokinetics What and Why (A second attempt to make it clearer)

Option Put-Call Parity Relations When the Underlying Security Pays Dividends

DETERMINISTIC INVENTORY MODEL FOR ITEMS WITH TIME VARYING DEMAND, WEIBULL DISTRIBUTION DETERIORATION AND SHORTAGES KUN-SHAN WU

4. International Parity Conditions

Pricing Black-Scholes Options with Correlated Interest. Rate Risk and Credit Risk: An Extension

Differential Equations and Linear Superposition

Chapter 8: Regression with Lagged Explanatory Variables

LIFE INSURANCE WITH STOCHASTIC INTEREST RATE. L. Noviyanti a, M. Syamsuddin b

The naive method discussed in Lecture 1 uses the most recent observations to forecast future values. That is, Y ˆ t + 1

On the degrees of irreducible factors of higher order Bernoulli polynomials

cooking trajectory boiling water B (t) microwave time t (mins)

How To Find Opimal Conracs In A Continuous Time Model

Communication Networks II Contents

Niche Market or Mass Market?

Time Consisency in Porfolio Managemen

Dynamic Information. Albina Danilova Department of Mathematical Sciences Carnegie Mellon University. September 16, Abstract

Valuation of Life Insurance Contracts with Simulated Guaranteed Interest Rate

Single-machine Scheduling with Periodic Maintenance and both Preemptive and. Non-preemptive jobs in Remanufacturing System 1

Dependent Interest and Transition Rates in Life Insurance

CHARGE AND DISCHARGE OF A CAPACITOR

Risk Modelling of Collateralised Lending

How To Write A Demand And Price Model For A Supply Chain

Stochastic Calculus and Option Pricing

The Kinetics of the Stock Markets

ANALYSIS AND COMPARISONS OF SOME SOLUTION CONCEPTS FOR STOCHASTIC PROGRAMMING PROBLEMS

Measuring macroeconomic volatility Applications to export revenue data,

Markit Excess Return Credit Indices Guide for price based indices

9. Capacitor and Resistor Circuits

Modeling VIX Futures and Pricing VIX Options in the Jump Diusion Modeling

The Application of Multi Shifts and Break Windows in Employees Scheduling

On the Role of the Growth Optimal Portfolio in Finance

11/6/2013. Chapter 14: Dynamic AD-AS. Introduction. Introduction. Keeping track of time. The model s elements

ARTICLE IN PRESS Journal of Computational and Applied Mathematics ( )

New Pricing Framework: Options and Bonds

Time Series Analysis Using SAS R Part I The Augmented Dickey-Fuller (ADF) Test

PROFIT TEST MODELLING IN LIFE ASSURANCE USING SPREADSHEETS PART ONE

UNIVERSITY OF CALGARY. Modeling of Currency Trading Markets and Pricing Their Derivatives in a Markov. Modulated Environment.

USE OF EDUCATION TECHNOLOGY IN ENGLISH CLASSES

Option-Pricing in Incomplete Markets: The Hedging Portfolio plus a Risk Premium-Based Recursive Approach

DOES TRADING VOLUME INFLUENCE GARCH EFFECTS? SOME EVIDENCE FROM THE GREEK MARKET WITH SPECIAL REFERENCE TO BANKING SECTOR

BALANCE OF PAYMENTS. First quarter Balance of payments

Dynamic Option Adjusted Spread and the Value of Mortgage Backed Securities

Economics Honors Exam 2008 Solutions Question 5

Statistical Analysis with Little s Law. Supplementary Material: More on the Call Center Data. by Song-Hee Kim and Ward Whitt

A Re-examination of the Joint Mortality Functions

Inductance and Transient Circuits

On Galerkin Approximations for the Zakai Equation with Diffusive and Point Process Observations

Pricing Futures and Futures Options with Basis Risk

INDEX RULE BOOK Leverage, Short, and Bear Indices

Full-wave rectification, bulk capacitor calculations Chris Basso January 2009

Credit Index Options: the no-armageddon pricing measure and the role of correlation after the subprime crisis

Pricing Guaranteed Minimum Withdrawal Benefits under Stochastic Interest Rates

Real-time Particle Filters

adaptive control; stochastic systems; certainty equivalence principle; long-term

Market Liquidity and the Impacts of the Computerized Trading System: Evidence from the Stock Exchange of Thailand

Volatility in Returns of Islamic and Commercial Banks in Pakistan

Module 4. Single-phase AC circuits. Version 2 EE IIT, Kharagpur

Foreign Exchange and Quantos

Conditional Default Probability and Density

Can Individual Investors Use Technical Trading Rules to Beat the Asian Markets?

Morningstar Investor Return

Carbon Trading. Diederik Dian Schalk Nel. Christ Church University of Oxford

TEMPORAL PATTERN IDENTIFICATION OF TIME SERIES DATA USING PATTERN WAVELETS AND GENETIC ALGORITHMS

Multiprocessor Systems-on-Chips

Analysis of Pricing and Efficiency Control Strategy between Internet Retailer and Conventional Retailer

This document is downloaded from DR-NTU, Nanyang Technological University Library, Singapore.

LECTURE 7 Interest Rate Models I: Short Rate Models

Duration and Convexity ( ) 20 = Bond B has a maturity of 5 years and also has a required rate of return of 10%. Its price is $613.

Sensitivity Analysis for Averaged Asset Price Dynamics with Gamma Processes

T ϕ t ds t + ψ t db t,

Return Calculation of U.S. Treasury Constant Maturity Indices

Dynamic programming models and algorithms for the mutual fund cash balance problem

Transcription:

Mahemaical and Compuaional Applicaions Aricle Opimizaion of Seing Take-Profi Levels for Derivaive Trading Xiaodong Rui 1,3,, Yue Liu 2,,, Aijun Yang 1,,, Hongqiang Yang 1, and Chengcui Zhang 4, 1 College of Economics and Managemen, Nanjing Foresry Universiy, Nanjing 210037, China; rxd@ji.edu.cn (X.R; yhqnfu@aliyun.com (H.Y. 2 School of Finance and Economics, Jiangsu Universiy, Zhenjiang 212013, China 3 School of Business, Jinling Insiue of Technology, Nanjing 211169, China 4 School of Finance, Nanjing Audi Universiy, Nanjing 211815, China; cuicuinj@163.com * Correspondence: liuy0080@e.nu.edu.sg (Y.L.; ajyang81@163.com (A.Y.; Tel.: +86-150-5292-7422 (A.Y. These auhors conribued equally o his work. Academic Edior: Fazal M. Mahomed Received: 11 Sepember 2016; Acceped: 9 December 2016; Published: 22 December 2016 Absrac: This paper develops an opimal sopping rule by characerizing he ake-profi level. The opimizaion problem is modeled by geomeric Brownian moion wih wo swichable regimes and solved by sochasic calculaion. A closed-form profiabiliy funcion for he rading sraegies is given, and based on which he opimal ake-profi level is numerically achievable wih small cos of compuaional complexiy. Keywords: Black-Scholes model; passage ime; opimizaion 1. Inroducion Derivaive rading has been reshaped by quaniaive echniques in recen decades [1]. This paper aims o solve he opimizaion problem of seing ake-profi levels o maximize he profiabiliy. Considerable sudies on closing a deal are implemened ino rading pracice. Eloe e al. [2] opimized he hreshold levels of aking profi and sopping loss based on a regime-swiching model. On he oher hand, modeling wih regime-swiching has he advanage of flexibiliy in changing parameers. Since firs inroduced by [3], inensive research ineress have been drawn o his area, for example he research by Yao e al. [4] on pricing he European opion by a regime-swiching model. In his paper, we also apply swiched regimes, bu no driven by anoher independen process or exernal facors. To opimize he ake-profi level, regime-swiching in our model is riggered by he price process iself; hence, our model is less subjec o parameer esimaion and predicion, and performs more neurally o unveil he variaion brough by he ake-profi level. We proceed as follows. In Secion 2, we formulae he opimal selling problem. Secion 3 gives he probabiliy disribuion of he ransacion ime. In Secion 4, he profiabiliy funcion is explicily expressed in closed-form and opimal ake-profi level is achievable from his expression. Secion 5 proceeds he numerical simulaion o show ha he resuls obained by our mehod are consisen wih hose by crude Mone Carlo simulaion [5], bu ours consume less ime. 2. Problem Formulaion Suppose a pair of opposie rades are opened by he he curren ask price x + and bid price x a ime, he price X is recognized as x+ +x 2 and denoed as x. Thereby, he cos for a pair of orders are x + x, assumed as a consan θ < X 0. Le x(1 + η be he closing price for long rades, and x(1 η for shor rades, xη is he profi gained in each single deal, where η (0, 1 as he ake-profi rae. The price dynamic is simulaed by he process {X : [0, } formulaed by he following equaion: Mah. Compu. Appl. 2017, 22, 1; doi:10.3390/mca22010001 www.mdpi.com/journal/mca

Mah. Compu. Appl. 2017, 22, 1 2 of 8 dx = ] [µ (µ 2 2 1 { ˆX 0, X 0 (1+η or ˇX 0, X 0 (1 η} X d + X dw (1 where µ IR, > 0, X 0 > 0, and ˆX s1,s 2 := sup s1 r s 2 X r, ˇX s1,s 2 := inf s1 r s 2 X r. The naure filraion (F IR+ is generaed by a Wiener process (W IR+. For any T > 0, consider he process {X : [0, T]}; o make i under a risk-neural seing, a new probabiliy measure ˆP is defined by where he process ϕ is given by ( T T 1 d ˆP = exp ϕ dw 0 0 2 ϕ2 d dp, ϕ := µ (µ 2 2 1 { ˆX 0, X 0 (1+η or ˇX 0, X 0 (1 η}, [0, T], hence under his measure, ˆP, W 0 ϕ udu is a sandard Brownian moion and X is also a maringale. Wihou loss of generaliy and for convenience of noaion, we sill proceed under he original measure P insead of ˆP for he remaining par. For any IR +, in he even ha X 0 (1 η < X s < X 0 (1 + η for all s [0, ], (X s s [0,] follows a geomery Brownian moion as in he Black Scholes model. The drif facor µ is se according o he prediced rend based on he previous informaion. Therefore, once he hreshold level is achieved, we abandon he previously obained value of he drif facor µ, and make no more predicion for he uncerainy; raher, he price hereafer is simulaed by a maringale namely, leing he drif facor vanish. According o our sopping rule, wo sopping imes are defined as follows, T 1 := inf{s 0 X s X 0 (1 + η or X s X 0 (1 η}, (2 T 2 := inf{s 0 ˆX 0,T1 +s X 0 (1 + η and ˇX 0,T1 +s X 0 (1 η}. (3 To measure he efficiency of profi-aking, we define he profiabiliy funcion: [ ] 2ηX0 θ φ(η := E T 1 + T 2 (4 for any ake-profi rae η (0, 1. Wih definiion (2 of T 1, SDE (1 is rewrien equivalenly: dx = µx 1 {<T1 } d + X dw. Nex, we define wo geomeric Brownian moions (Y IR+ and (Z IR+ by dy = µy d + Y dw and dz = Z dw. For any posiive sequence { i } i IN ha i < i+1 for any i IN, in he even i < T 1 for all i, {Y i } i IN has he same join disribuion as {X i } i IN. On he oher hand, {Z i } i IN has he same join disribuion as {X i } i IN in he even ha i > s T 1 for all i. Therefore, in he following compuaion, we may subsiue X by Y and Z in each case, respecively. For convenience, we define W λ := W + λ, λ := µ 2, S := sup 0 r W r, and I := inf 0 r W r. 3. Compuaion of Transacion Time 3.1. Independence beween T 1 and T 2 In his subsecion, we show by Lemma 1 he independence beween T 1 and T 2 for furher compuaion. Lemma 1. For any 1, 2 > 0, P(T 1 d 1, T 2 d 2 = P(T 1 d 1 P(T 2 d 2, where T 1, T 2 are defined by (2 and (3. Proof. By definiion (2 of T 1, T 1 = 0 since X 0 > 0, hen X T1 = X 0 (1 + η or X T1 = X 0 (1 η, hence we have

Mah. Compu. Appl. 2017, 22, 1 3 of 8 P(T 1 d 1, T 2 d 2 = E[1 {T1 d 1 } E[1 {T 2 d 2 } T 1 d 1, X T1 = X 0 (1 + η]]p(x T1 = X 0 (1 + η + E[1 {T1 d 1 } E[1 {T 2 d 2 } T 1 d 1, X T1 = X 0 (1 η]]p(x T1 = X 0 (1 η. (5 To simplify (5, by definiion (3, we noe ha E[1 {T2 d 2 } T 1, X T1 = X 0 (1 η] =P( inf{s 0 Ẑ T1,T 1 +s X 0 (1 + η} d 2 T 1, Z T1 = X 0 (1 η, (6 Applying he srong Markov propery of (Z IR+ for all T 1 given T 1, we have P( inf{s 0 Ẑ T1,T 1 +s X 0 (1 + η} d 2 T 1, Z T1 = X 0 (1 η ( log(1 + η log(1 η =P ds 2, (7 where for he propery of Wiener process, we apply Theorem 1.12 of [6]. Combining (6 and (7, we see ha ( log(1 + η log(1 η E[1 {T2 d 2 } T 1, X T1 = X 0 (1 η] = P ds 2. (8 By he symmeric propery of Wiener process (see Chaper 2 of [7], E[1 {T2 d 2 } T 1 d 1, X T1 = X 0 (1 η] = E[1 {T2 d 2 } T 1 d 1, X T1 = X 0 (1 + η]. (9 By (5, (8, and (9, we obain ( log(1 + η log(1 η P(T 1 d 1, T 2 d 2 = P(T 1 d 1 P ds 2. (10 On he oher hand, repeaing he approach above, we see ha ( log(1 + η log(1 η P(T 2 d 2 = P ds 2, (11 hence we conclude Lemma 1 by (10 and (11. 3.2. Disribuion of T 1 Define a funcion G(y, a, b, for any a > y > b > 0 and IR + by G(y, a, b, = [κ(, y 2b + 2(n 1(a b + κ(, y 2a 2(n 1(a b κ(, y + 2n(a b κ(, y 2n(a b], (12 where he normal densiy funcion κ is defined by κ(, x := disribuion of T 1 is given by Proposiion 2 as follows. Proposiion 2. For any > 0, e x2 2 2π for any > 0, x IR. Then, he P(T 1 < = log(1+η ( e λy 1 2 λ2 G y, log(1 + η log(1 η, log(1 η ( log(1 + η +1 Φ ( log(1 η λ + Φ, dy λ,

Mah. Compu. Appl. 2017, 22, 1 4 of 8 where Φ( denoes he disribuion funcion of a sandard normal variable. Proof. By he definiion (2 of T 1, for any > 0, we have P(T 1 < = P(Ŷ 0, X 0 (1 + η or ˇY 0, X 0 (1 η. Applying he sandard echnique of Girsanov heorem, cf. Theorem 8.6.4 of B. Oksendal [8], we obain ha P(T 1 < = E[1 {S 1 log(1+η or I 1 log(1 η}eλw 1 2 λ2 ], for which we hen apply he Lemma 3 proved by some similar argumens as in Chaper 2.8 of [9]; he deails of he proof are saed in he Appendix. Lemma 3. For any a > c > b > 0, > 0 and x (a, b, we have P(S a or I b ; W c W 0 = x [ ( c + x 2n(a b 2a = Φ + Φ ( ( c x 2n(a b b + x 2n(a b 2a Φ Φ Φ +Φ ( ( ] b x + 2n(a b b x 2n(a b + Φ. ( ( c + x + 2n(a b 2b c x + 2n(a b Φ ( b + x + 2n(a b 2b 4. Opimizaion of Take-Profi Levels In his secion, we express he profiabiliy funcion in a closed-form and consider he maximizaion problem over η (0, 1. By (4 and (11, and Proposiion 2, we have P(dT φ(η = (2ηX 0 θ 1 P(dT 2 1 = (2ηX (R + 2 T 1 + 0 θ T 2 (R + 2 + s ϕ 1(ϕ 2 (sdds, (13 where he probabiliy densiy funcions are given by ϕ 1 ( := log(1+η log(1 η 1 log(1+η 2 λ2 log(1 η e λy 1 2 λ2 G 1 e (log(1 η λ2 2 2 2π ( y, log(1 η, dy log(1 + η, ( e λy 1 2 λ2 log(1 + η log(1 η G y,, ( log(1 η 2 + λ 3 2, dy + 1 e (log(1+η λ2 2 2 2π ( log(1 + η 2 + λ 3 2 for > 0, where he funcion G is defined by (12, and ϕ 2 ( = log(1+η log(1 η 2π for > 0. Then, we consider he maximizaion problem of seing suiable 3 η. Firs, o enlarge φ(η, we ensure i o be posiive; herefore, η should saisfy he condiion ha η > 2X θ 0. Noe ha η (0, 1 and θ < X 0 as we assumed before, η should be wihin ( 2X θ 0, 1. Nex, we check he convergence of he inegraion in (13. Acually, under he condiion ha η ( 2X θ 0, 1, we see ha (2X 0 θ 2 e (log(1+η log(1 η2 2 2 0 < φ(η <, which also provides a uniform upper bound for he profiabiliy (log(2x 0 +θ log(2x 0 θ 2 ( funcion. The opimal ake-profi rae η = max η θ 2X 0, 1 φ(η = max φ(r, is ready o be θ solved numerically. 5. Numerical Simulaion 2X 0 r 1 In Table 1 below, we compare he esing errors and running ime for boh approaches. Noe ha he average esing errors are measured by comparison wih he resul obained by programming wih much more samples and smaller ime discreizaion seps, which consume several imes he running

Mah. Compu. Appl. 2017, 22, 1 5 of 8 ime. From he average running ime lised, we conclude ha our approach is much more efficien han ha of crude Mone Carlo [ simulaion. ] The reason is also mahemaically obvious, as i is well known ha E[T 2 ] = while E 1T2 is finie, i is quie ime-consuming o sample he sopping ime T 2 (so is T 1. From he daa of difference pairs of (µ, obained by boh approaches, we find ha he opimal ake-profi level is more sensiive o he changes of han ha of µ. Besides, larger volailiy yields large opimal ake-profi level, which reinforces he widely-held financial wisdom ha he larger he volailiy, he larger he ake-profi level we can se. Table 1. For 25 pairs of parameers (µ,, we repor he value of η obained by Mone Carlo simulaions and our approach of maximizaion of he closed-form. Mone Carlo Our mehod X 0 = 10, θ = 0.001 = 0.10 = 0.15 = 0.20 = 0.25 = 0.30 = 0.05 0.029 0.042 0.046 0.058 0.064 = 0.10 0.031 0.047 0.049 0.056 0.072 = 0.15 0.035 0.049 0.053 0.064 0.077 = 0.20 0.038 0.050 0.058 0.080 0.095 = 0.25 0.039 0.058 0.063 0.084 0.103 Average Tesing Errors 0.028 Average Running Time 54.60 min = 0.05 0.028 0.040 0.049 0.056 0.068 = 0.10 0.032 0.045 0.051 0.061 0.075 = 0.15 0.035 0.051 0.054 0.066 0.080 = 0.20 0.040 0.052 0.059 0.077 0.091 = 0.25 0.041 0.061 0.065 0.083 0.096 Average Tesing Errors 0.011 Average Running Time 30.11 min 6. Conclusion and Fuure Work This paper gives an opimal sopping rule by characerizing he ake-profi level. Compared o ohers effecs on his, ours has less compuaional complexiy and is applicable o improving he rading sraegy for he issue of closing posiion. Our work can be exended o oher more difficul models wih regime swiching, such as ha wih Markov chains; however, i could be challenging o ge a closed form, since our work benefis from he advanages of Brownian moion. Acknowledgmens: The work is parly suppored by Naional Naural Science Foundaion of China (No. 11501294 and China Posdocoral Science Foundaion (2015M580374, 2016T90398. Auhor Conribuions: X.R. colleced and processed he daa, and checked resuls and manuscrip. Y.L. drafed his manuscrip, esablished he research paper design and paper mehodology. A.Y. and H.Y gave suggesions for he inpu-oupu analysis and for he manuscrip during he whole wriing process. C.Z. helped processing raw daa. All he auhors have read and approved he final manuscrip. Conflics of Ineres: The auhors declare no conflic of ineres. Appendix A. In his secion, we proceed o prove Lemma 3 by applying he echnique in Chaper 2.8 of [9]. For any a > c > b > 0, x (a, b, > 0, we have = P x (S a or I b ; W c [ Φ Φ ( c + x 2n(a b 2a + Φ ( c + x + 2n(a b 2b ( ( c x + 2n(a b c x 2n(a b Φ

Mah. Compu. Appl. 2017, 22, 1 6 of 8 ( b + x 2n(a b 2a Φ +Φ Φ ( b + x + 2n(a b 2b ( ( ] b x + 2n(a b b x 2n(a b + Φ. Proof. Firs, several sequences of sopping ime are defined as follows: 0 = 0, τ 0 = inf{ 0 I b}; π 0 = 0, ρ 0 = inf{ 0 S a}; n = inf{ π n 1 W = a}; τ n = inf{ n 1 W = b}; π n = inf{ ρ n 1 W = b}; ρ n = inf{ π n 1 W = a}. Wih he reflecion propery of Brownian moion (refer o [9], for y (b, a, P x (W y P x (W y P x (W y P x (W y F τn = P x (W 2b y F τn F τn = P x (W 2b y F πn F τn = P x (W 2a y F n F τn = P x (W 2a y F ρn on {τ n }; on {π n }; on { n }; on {ρ n }. Noe ha 2b y < b and 2a y > a; hereby, for any n 1, P x (W y, τ n = P x (W 2b y, τ n = P x (W 2b y, n ; P x (W y, n = P x (W 2a y, n = P x (W 2a y, τ n 1 ; P x (W y, ρ n = P x (W 2a y, ρ n = P x (W 2a y, π n ; P x (W y, π n = P x (W 2b y, π n = P x (W 2b y, ρ n 1. The above formulas are alernaely and recursively applied o gain he following expressions. Therefore we have, P x (W y, τ n = P x (W 2b y, n = P x (W 2a (2b y, τ n 1 = P x (W 2b y 2(a b, n 1 = P x (W y + 2n(a b, τ n n = P x (W 2b y 2n(a b, 0, and P x (W y, n = P x (W 2a y, τ n 1 = P x (W y 2(a b, n 1 = P x (W y 2n(a b, 0.

Mah. Compu. Appl. 2017, 22, 1 7 of 8 Similarly, anoher wo formulas are: P x (W y, ρ n = P x (W 2a y + 2n(a b. P x (W y, π n = P x (W y + 2n(a b. Taking he derivaive regarding y in he above four formulas, anoher four expressions are gained. where κ(, x = P x (W dy, τ n = κ(, x + y 2b + 2n(a bdy, P x (W dy, n = κ(, x y + 2n(a bdy, P x (W dy, ρ n = κ(, x + y 2a 2n(a bdy, P x (W dy, π n = κ(, x y 2n(a bdy, e x2 2 2π as defined before, for any > 0, x R. Noe ha τ n 1 ρ n 1 = n π n and n π n = π n ρ n for any n 1, hen for any ineger k 1, P x (W dy, τ k ρ k = P x (W dy, τ k + P x (W dy, ρ k P x (W dy, k π k = P x (W dy, τ k + P x (W dy, ρ k [P x (W dy, τ k 1 + P x (W dy, ρ k 1 P x (W dy, τ k 1 ρ k 1 ]. Repeaedly apply his recursive expression for k imes, and have: P x (W dy, τ k ρ k = k [P x (W dy, n + P x (W dy, π n P x (W dy, τ n 1 P x (W dy, ρ n 1 ] +P x (W dy, τ 0 ρ 0. Consider he convergence of he above summaion when k goes o infiniy. Since he summaion equals P x (W dy, τ k ρ k P x (W dy, τ 0 ρ 0, he above summaion should decrease on k, and consrained wihin [ 1, 1], he limi exiss and is bounded. Noe ha S a or I b is he same even as τ 0 ρ, hen pass k o infiniy and gain ha P x (W dy, S a or I b = = [P x (W dy, τ n 1 + P x (W dy, ρ n 1 P x (W dy, n P x (W dy, π n ] [κ(, x + y 2b + 2(n 1(a b +κ(, x + y 2a 2(n 1(a b κ(, x y + 2n(a b κ(, x y 2n(a b]dy. Finally, ake inegraion regarding y from b o c, and hence complee he proof. References 1. Vidyamurhy, G. Pairs Trading: Quaniaive Mehods and Analysis. Pearson Schweiz Ag. 2004, 35 47. 2. Eloe, P.; Liu, R.H.; Yasuki, M.; Yin, G.; Zhang, Q. Opimal selling rules in a regime-swiching exponenial Gaussian diffusion model. SIAM J. Appl. Mah. 2008, 69, 810 829.

Mah. Compu. Appl. 2017, 22, 1 8 of 8 3. Hamilon, J.D. A new approach o he economic analysis of non-saionary ime series. Economerica 1989, 57, 357 384. 4. Yao, D.D.; Zhang, Q.; Zhou, X.Y. A regime-swiching model for European opions. In. Ser. Oper. Res. Manag. Sci. 2006, 94, 281 300. 5. Hammersley, J.M.; Handscomb, D.C. Mone Carlo Mehods. Springer Neh. 1964, 30, 347 385. 6. Mörers, P.; Peres, Y. Brownian Moion; Cambridge Universiy Press: Cambridge, UK, 2010. 7. Schilling, R.L.; Böcher, B.; Parzsch, L. Brownian Moion: An Inroducion o Sochasic Processes; Waler de Gruyer GmbH & Co KG: Berlin, Germany, 2012. 8. Oksendal, B. Sochasic Differenial Equaions, 6h ed.; Springer: New York, NY, USA, 2003. 9. Karazas, I.; Shreve, S.E. Brownian Moion and Sochasic Calculus; Springer: New York, NY, USA; Berlin, Germany, 1991. c 2016 by he auhors; licensee MDPI, Basel, Swizerland. This aricle is an open access aricle disribued under he erms and condiions of he Creaive Commons Aribuion (CC-BY license (hp://creaivecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/.