The Stakes in Limiting Climate Change

Similar documents
Annex 5A Trends in international carbon dioxide emissions

global warming. and Agriculture

Energy Prices, Climate Change Policy and U.S. Economic Growth

Figure 1. The circular flow of global warming science, impacts, and policy. From "Climate Casino" Copyright 2013 by William Nordhaus

Economic Development and the Risk of Global Climate Change

Keeping below 2 degrees

The Science and Ethics of Global warming. Global warming has become one of the central political and scientific issues of

Energy Projections Price and Policy Considerations. Dr. Randy Hudson Oak Ridge National Laboratory

Fossil fuels and climate change: alternative projections to 2050

Finding Ways to Postpone Climate Tipping Points Using Updated Metrics

Questions and Answers Emissions Reductions Needed to Stabilize Climate

Generating Heat. Part 1: Breathing Earth. Part 2: The Growth of Carbon Emitters. Introduction: Materials:

Economic Impacts of Potential Colorado Climate Change Initiatives: Evidence from MIT and Penn State Analyses. July 2007

OIL AND US FOREIGN POLICY. David S. Painter Department of History Edmund A. Walsh School of Foreign Service Georgetown University

Resolution: Energy and climate. Year and Congress: November 2009, Barcelona. Category: Environment and Energy. Page: 1. Energy and climate change

public support for climate and energy policies in november 2011

What will global annual emissions of greenhouse gases be in 2030, and will they be consistent with avoiding global warming of more than 2 C?

PRIZE WINNING ENTRY (FIRST PRIZE) IN ICAR NATIONAL ESSAY COMPETITION FOR SCHOOL CHILDREN Global Climatic Changes & Its Effect on Agriculture

climate science A SHORT GUIDE TO This is a short summary of a detailed discussion of climate change science.

Working Paper #54. Greenhouse Gas Implications in Large Scale Infrastructure Investments in Developing Countries: Examples from China and India

Pay Later: The Cost of Inaction. Climate change will have a negative impact on many of the industries that

degrees Fahrenheit. Scientists believe it's human activity that's driving the temperatures up, a process

CRS Report for Congress

IMPACTS OF EPA S CARBON PROPOSAL ON COLORADO

FACTS ABOUT CLIMATE CHANGE

Office of Climate Change, Energy Efficiency and Emissions Trading. Business Plan

Are Humans Responsible for Global Warming?

How to Earn the LEED Green Power Credit

World Energy Outlook Presentation to the Press London, 10 November 2009

GREENHOUSE GAS EMISSIONS INVENTORY

BBC Learning English Talk about English Insight plus Part 3 Global Warming

Economic Outcomes of a U.S. Carbon Tax. Executive Summary

Agriculture, Food Security and Climate Change A Triple Win?

Nuclear power is part of the solution for fighting climate change

41 T Korea, Rep T Netherlands T Japan E Bulgaria T Argentina T Czech Republic T Greece 50.

Why are developing countries exempt from the emissions targets?

The Global Chemical Industry: US, China and Global Status and Opportunities, 2015

How to implement renewable energy and energy efficiency options

Climate Change Mini-Simulation: Background Guide

Policy Brief International Renewable Energy Investment Credits Under a Federal Renewable Energy Standard

Six greenhouse gases covered by the United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change (UNFCCC) and its Kyoto Protocol are:

ANALYSIS OF US AND STATE-BY-STATE CARBON DIOXIDE EMISSIONS AND POTENTIAL SAVINGS IN FUTURE GLOBAL TEMPERATURE AND GLOBAL SEA LEVEL RISE

World Energy Outlook 2007: China and India Insights. International Energy Agency

THE SEARCH FOR T RENDS IN A GLOBAL CATALOGUE

Climate Change and Insurance. Challenges and Opportunities

Business proposals in view of a 2015 international climate change agreement at COP 21 in Paris

Emissions de CO 2 et objectifs climatiques

Industry Primer. Real Estate

Using Discount Rate for Water Sector Planning in Bangladesh under Climatic Changes

Tackling Climate Change in the U.S.

Climate change and economic analysis

New Zealand s response to climate change. March

World Economic Forum Insurance and Asset Management Council. Joachim Faber. Low Carbon Economy Finance Paper Q4 2011

The atmosphere has a number of gases, often in tiny amounts, which trap the heat given out by the Earth.

CLEAN POWER, CLEAR SAVINGS MAINE. The EPA Clean Power Plan Will Cut Maine Electricity Bills by 11.3 to 12.5 Percent by 2030

Pre-lab Homework Lab 10: Global Warming Prior to lab, answer the following questions to help you become prepared for the lab.

2052 A Global Forecast for the Next Forty Years

Climate Change and Infrastructure Planning Ahead

Data Sets of Climate Science

SECTION 3 Making Sense of the New Climate Change Scenarios

Climate Change Long Term Trends and their Implications for Emergency Management August 2011

The impact Equation where scientists and engineers fit in the picture

Democratic and Republican Positions on Environmental Issues. Edward H. Klevans, Professor and Department Head Emeritus of Nuclear Engineering

A Guide to Woodland Carbon for Business

Implications of Abundant Natural Gas

OVERVIEW CLIMATE ACTION IN BC. BC s Climate Action Secretariat. Action to date on climate change. BC s approach to regulating GHGs

Economics of Energy Efficiency in a CO 2 Constrained World

The Law and Economics of CO 2 as a Pollutant and Commodity

Residential & Commercial Sectors Overview CLIMATE

Issue. September 2012

Policy & Management Applications of Blue Carbon. fact SHEET

U.S. Agriculture and International Trade

The Business Case for Sustainability

Comparative tables. CPSS Red Book statistical update 427

Tracking intended nationally determined contributions: what are the implications for greenhouse gas emissions in 2030?

THE ECONOMICS OF GLOBAL WARMING: Not to Act at All, to Act Now or Later. (Ahmed M. Hussen, July 2007)

WORLD ENERGY OUTLOOK 2011 FACTSHEET How will global energy markets evolve to 2035?

Comprehensive emissions per capita for industrialised countries

Natural Gas / Electricity and the Industrial Sector. The Dismantling of US Manufacturing

II. Merchandise trade

A Message From The Chair

Is China Catching Up with the US?

As concern over climate change grows, policymakers

Ghana South Korea United States. Real GDP per capita (2005 dollars) Per centage of 1960 real GDP per capita real GDP per capita

Rush hour in Kolkata (formerly Calcutta), India. Between 1990 and 2000, the number of motor vehicles per capita more than doubled in four

World Simulations with GEM-E3

Examining Public Opinion on Climate Change Among Wisconsin College Students and Adults

Global Pension Assets Study Willis Towers Watson. All rights reserved.

The economic competitiveness of nuclear energy

Japan s Long Term Nuclear Power Policy and Rising Need for Energy in East Asia 1. Shinzo SAITO Vice Chairman Atomic Energy Commission of Japan

Open Doors Report on International Educational Exchange. Produced by the. Institute of International Education. In partnership with the

GLOBAL DATA CENTER SPACE 2013

HAS BRAZIL REALLY TAKEN OFF? BRAZIL LONG-RUN ECONOMIC GROWTH AND CONVERGENCE

How To Predict Climate Change

The Economics of Climate Change C 175. To Kyoto and Beyond. Spring 09 UC Berkeley Traeger 7 International Cooperation 22

Earth Day Coincides With Heated Debates Over Environmental Rules

Deciding our future in Copenhagen: will the world rise to the challenge of climate change? Nicholas Stern

2015 JET FUEL PRICE FORECAST

Appendix SM1: Sources of Modal Data and Calculation of Modal Shares

NET INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION

Transcription:

The Stakes in Limiting Climate Change William R. Cline, Peterson Institute for International Economics and Center for Global Development Remarks at the Symposium on US Climate Action: A Global Economic Perspective, sponsored by the Center for Global Development, Grantham Research Institute, Peterson Institute for International Economics, and World Resources Institute, Washington, DC, March 3, 2009. Peterson Institute for International Economics. Introduction In 1992 the Institute for International Economics published my book, The Economics of Global Warming (Cline 1992). In that book I concluded that cutting global carbon dioxide emissions by half passed a costs-benefits test because the abatement costs would be less than the benefits of avoiding the damages from warming. In 2007 the much more comprehensive analysis of the Stern Review reached the same conclusion (Stern 2007). It is a great pleasure and honor for me to share the podium with Lord Stern, and with Senator Warner, who has provided strong legislative leadership on this issue. Damages from Unrestrained Warming Agriculture To get a concrete feel for the scope of future damages, let me first review the results of my 2007 book (Cline 2007) on global warming and agriculture (figure 1). I have combined climate and agronomic models to project the impact of global warming on world agriculture by the 2080s when, under business as usual, average temperatures will have risen 3º C globally and 4.5º C for the world s agricultural land areas. Agricultural damages tend to be greater toward the equator, and hence concentrated in developing countries. Yields and agricultural production potential would fall about 15 to 30 percent in Africa and Latin America. 1 Losses in India could be 30 to 40 percent. For the United States, the effects would be severe for the south but milder and conceivably even positive for a while for the north. Productivity losses would range between 20 and 30 percent in the southeast, and from 25 to 35 percent in the southwest plains and Mexico. These effects would grow worse with still greater warming by 2100 and after. The impacts would also be much worse already by the 2080s if the upper-end rather than the center of the projected warming range were to occur. Figure 1 Impact on agricultural productivity without carbon fertilization, percent 1 The lower-end estimates are for the case in which higher atmospheric concentrations of carbon dioxide act as carbon fertilization.

Source: Cline 2007. Other The 2007 report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change, in its most plausible business as usual scenario, projected that by 2100 global mean temperature would rise by 2 to 5.4 degrees Celsius above 1990 levels, with a best estimate of 3.4 degrees. The world would be committing to even larger temperature increases after 2100, because of the long time lags from higher atmospheric concentrations to the eventual new equilibrium temperature. In addition to agricultural damages, the report stressed decreased water availability in most regions, species loss, coastal flooding and wetlands loss, and health damages from heat waves and wider spheres of infectious diseases. For the United States, recent estimates suggest relatively large losses from increased costs for water supply in the western states, increased hurricane damage, real estate losses from sea level rise, and increased electricity needs as higher cooling requirements exceed heating cost reductions, with total damages by 2100 at nearly 2 percent of GDP annually for just these four categories (Ackerman and Stanton 2008). These damages cannot be dismissed simply because they occur in the distant future. Indeed, the so-called time discount rate that both the Stern Review and I use explicitly recognizes that future generations should not be discounted simply because they are born later (Cline 1992, Chapter 6; Stern 2007, Appendix 2A). Catastrophic Risks Ultimately, however, it is probably the risk of catastrophic effects that is more troublesome than these central-case damages. Three major risks include a shut-down in the ocean conveyor belt that produces the Gulf Stream and keeps northern Europe relatively warm; the break-up of the West Antarctic ice shelf that, when it arrives, could

raise global sea levels by 7 meters in the space of a few weeks (but probably at least a century or two from now); and a runaway greenhouse effect as massive amounts of frozen methane are released from permafrost and continental shelves. Perhaps the most widely used economic model of global warming, the DICE model of William Nordhaus at Yale University, attempts to incorporate both the central damage estimates and some probability of catastrophic effects (Nordhaus 2008). For the world as a whole, he estimates that warming of 4 degrees Celsius would impose damage of 5 percent of world product; warming of 6 degrees would cause damage amounting to 10 percent of world product. Economist Martin Weitzman of Harvard University has argued instead that it is the small probability of much more catastrophic impacts that truly matters in deciding how much to pay for insurance against climate damage. He argues that there is a 1 percent chance that by 2100 warming could amount to 10 degrees Celsius, which would impose enormous damage (Weitzman 2009). Identifying the 50-50 and 80-20 Targets Especially because of uncertainty about catastrophic effects, arriving at a time path for economically optimal emissions is inherently problematic. Instead, it is attractive to consider whether the benefits broadly exceed abatement costs for meeting a physical target ceiling for atmospheric concentrations. Internationally the target that has gained the most support is to cut global carbon dioxide emissions by 50 percent below 1990 levels by the year 2050. I call this the 50-50 target. This amount of abatement would limit atmospheric concentrations to about 500 parts per million, or 80 percent above preindustrial levels and one-third above today s level. This ceiling would give a 50 percent chance of limiting warming to about 2.5 degrees Celsius above 1990 levels. There is a corresponding distributional target that has gained considerable support: Industrial countries would cut emissions 80 percent below 1990 levels, and developing countries 20 percent below 1990 levels (figure 2). An 80 percent cut from 1990 levels by 2050 is what the Obama administration has proposed. In 1990, industrial-country emissions somewhat exceeded those of developing countries. By now, after China has passed the European Union in emissions and other developing-country emissions have also risen sharply, developing countries account for almost 60 percent of global emissions. It will be imperative that developing countries not follow the earlier highcarbon development path of the industrial countries, but instead participate in abatement. Otherwise, as my colleague David Wheeler at the Center for Global Development has calculated, increased emissions from the developing countries alone will be sufficient to cause global warming that will impose severe damages on them (Wheeler and Ummel 2007). Figure 2 CO 2 emissions: developing and industrial countries, billion tons CO 2

35 30 25 20 15 10 dvl ind sum 5 0 1980 1990 2000 2010 2020 2030 2040 2050 Fairness does compel an earlier and deeper cutback by the industrial countries. Per capita emissions of carbon dioxide today amount to 13 tons per person in the industrial countries (and 20 tons per person in the United States) but only about 3 tons per person in developing countries. Figure 3 shows what would happen to per capita emissions under the 50-50 target with 80-20 cuts, after allowing for population growth. Figure 3 Per capita CO 2 emissions, tons per person 14 12 10 8 6 dvl ind 4 2 0 2005 2008 2011 2014 2017 2020 2023 2026 2029 2032 2035 2038 2041 2044 2047 2050

The Price of Climate Insurance Returning to the target path for global emissions, how much would it cost to achieve this path? Representative abatement models would place the cost at the global level at about 0.25 percent of world product by 2020, 0.5 percent by 2030, and 1.5 percent by 2040 50. 2 For the United States, several models of the Lieberman-Warner bill cutting US emissions by 75 percent by 2050 place abatement cost at about 1 percent of GDP annually by 2025, and about 1.5 to 2 percent by 2050 (figure 4). Some models would show a considerably lower price by 2050 because they have a backstop technology providing unlimited supplies of carbon-free energy. Figure 4 Abatement cost as percent GDP, global and United States (Lieberman-Warner) 3 2.5 2 1.5 1 0.5 D5050 MIT EIA NAM CRA EPA 0 2015 2020 2025 2030 2035 2040 2045 2050 Source: DICE model (Nordhaus 2008), Paltsev 2008, EIA 2008, ACCF and NAM 2008, CRA 2008, and EPA 2008). Technological change will be crucial in keeping down the abatement costs. Most of the models make some allowance for declining unit abatement costs over time as the technological alternatives expand. The most dramatic example would be carbon capture and sequestration (CCS) technology that would make it possible to use coal and store the carbon dioxide underground. The bottom line is that for something on the order of one-half of one percent of world product or less globally over the next quarter century, and 1 percent or less for the United States, it should be possible to purchase climate insurance that should easily pay for itself even in the central estimates but more importantly would greatly reduce the risk of truly catastrophic results. With a strong boost to technological change, it seems likely that the abatement costs could be held close to this modest range even in later decades. Moreover, there is a wide range of agreement among economists studying this issue that inaction would be a mistake. Indeed, by 2015 even the optimal abatement path in the Nordhaus DICE model, using his preferred, higher time discount rate, calls for the same 14 percent 2 Based on the DICE model (Nordhaus 2008).

cutback from the business-as-usual emissions as in the 50-50 path, and by 2025 his optimal cutback is still relatively close (25 percent versus 33 percent). Ensuring Global Action The principal task will be enlisting cooperation of all of the major emitting nations. It turns out that only 15 countries (counting the European Union as one) account for 85 percent of global emissions, and this concentration should facilitate meaningful negotiation. The super emitters are the United States and China (each about 20 percent of the world total) and the European Union (15 percent). In the next tier, Russia, Japan, and India each contribute about 5 to 6 percent. Then Canada and Korea each account for about 2 percent. Finally, South Africa, Mexico, Iran, Indonesia, Australia, Brazil, and Saudi Arabia each contribute 1.3 to 1.5 percent of the world total of industrial emissions. It will be essential for agreement to be reached among these large emitters. For this purpose, it seems likely that a meaningful program of technological assistance to these (and other) developing countries will need to be part of the international strategy. Since I wrote my book in 1992, I have acquired several grandchildren. I hope that the world we leave to them and their grandchildren will be one that avoids unrestrained global warming. I believe it is possible to do so at a relatively reasonable price. However, to succeed will require nearly unprecedented political cooperation among the nations.

References Ackerman, Frank, and Elizabeth A. Stanton. 2009. The Cost of Climate Change: What We ll Pay if Global Warming Continues Unchecked. New York: Natural Resources Defense Council. American Council for Capital Formation (ACCF) and the National Association of Manufactures (NAM). 2008. Analysis of the Lieberman-Warner Climate Security Act (S. 2191) Using the National Energy Modeling System (NEMS/ACCF/NAM). Available at www.accf.org (accessed on March 5, 2009). Cline, William R. 1992. The Economics of Global Warming. Washington: Institute for International Economics. Cline, William R. 2007. Global Warming and Agriculture: Impact Estimates by Country. Washington: Peterson Institute for International Economics and Center for Global Development. Energy Information Administration (EIA). 2008. Energy Market and Economic Impacts of S. 2191, the Lieberman-Warner Climate Security Act of 2007. SR/OIAF/2008-01. Environmental Protection Agency (EPA). 2008. EPA Analysis of the Lieberman-Warner Climate Security Act of 2008, S. 2191 in the 110 th Congress. Available at www.epa.gov (accessed on March 5, 2009). Nordhaus, William. 2008. A Question of Balance: Weighing the Options on Global Warming Policies. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press. Paltsev, Sergey, et al. 2008. Appendix D: Analysis of the Cap and Trade Features of the Lieberman-Warner Security Act (S. 2191). MIT Joint Program on the Science and Policy of Global Change, Report 146. Pifer III, Howard W., et al. 2008. Managing the Risks of Greenhouse Gas Policies. CRA International. Stern, Nicholas. 2007. The Economics of Climate Change. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Weitzman, Martin L. 2009. On Modeling and Interpreting the Economics of Catastrophic Climate Change, Review of Economics and Statistics, February. Wheeler, David, and Kevin Ummel. 2007. Another Inconvenient Truth: A Carbon- Intensive South Faces Environmental Disaster, No Matter What the North Does. Working Paper No. 134. Washington: Center for Global Development.