Trade and Welfare: Does industrial organization matter?

Similar documents
MIT PhD International Trade Lecture 9: Increasing Returns to Scale and Monopolistic Competition (Theory)

Gains from Trade: The Role of Composition

The Simple Analytics of the Melitz Model in a Small Economy

Heterogeneous firms and dynamic gains from trade

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES MISSING GAINS FROM TRADE? Marc J. Melitz Stephen J. Redding. Working Paper

Markups and Firm-Level Export Status: Appendix

ECO 745: Theory of International Economics. Jack Rossbach August 26, Week 1

INTERNATIONAL ECONOMICS, FINANCE AND TRADE Vol.I - Economics of Scale and Imperfect Competition - Bharati Basu

Specialization Patterns in International Trade

Calibration of Normalised CES Production Functions in Dynamic Models

Measuring the Cross-Country Distribution of Gains from Trade

Increasing Returns and Economic Geography

ECON 35101: International Macroeconomics and Trade University of Chicago, Fall Quarter, 2015 Syllabus

Dynamic Selection and the New Gains from Trade with. Heterogeneous Firms

Gains from trade: the Costa Rican case (Preliminary draft - do not cite)

New trade models, elusive welfare gains

Some information on using a right approach in applied trade analysis. Based on ARTNeT capacity building workshop materials artnet.unescap.

International Trade, Technology, and the Skill Premium

VI. Real Business Cycles Models

Market Size, Competition and the Product Mix of Exporters

2. Real Business Cycle Theory (June 25, 2013)

Macroeconomics Lecture 1: The Solow Growth Model

Global Gains from Reduction of Trade Costs

IMF Institute. The Welfare Analysis of a Free Trade Zone: Intermediate Goods and the Asian Tigers 1

Graduate Macro Theory II: The Real Business Cycle Model

THE NON-EQUIVALENCE OF EXPORT AND IMPORT QUOTAS

Micro to Macro: Optimal Trade Policy with Firm Heterogeneity

Econ 102 Aggregate Supply and Demand

Name: Date: 3. Variables that a model tries to explain are called: A. endogenous. B. exogenous. C. market clearing. D. fixed.

Sovereign Defaults. Iskander Karibzhanov. October 14, 2014

Gains from trade in a Hotelling model of differentiated duopoly

Midterm Exam - Answers. November 3, 2005

Lecture 3: Growth with Overlapping Generations (Acemoglu 2009, Chapter 9, adapted from Zilibotti)

Online Appendix for. Economies of Scale and the Size of Exporters

A Three-Sector Model of Structural Transformation and Economic Development

Problem Set #5-Key. Economics 305-Intermediate Microeconomic Theory

1 National Income and Product Accounts

Monopoly Distortions and the Welfare Gains from Trade

The basics of Dixit-Stiglitz lite

Lecture 14 More on Real Business Cycles. Noah Williams

U = x x x 1 4. What are the equilibrium relative prices of the three goods? traders has members who are best off?

Imported Inputs and the Gains from Trade

Selected Topics in International Economics

6. Budget Deficits and Fiscal Policy

TAXATION AND SAVINGS. Robin Boadway Queen s University Kingston, Canada. Day Six

Volatility, Productivity Correlations and Measures of. International Consumption Risk Sharing.

OF CONSTRUCTION AND USE OF TORNIO-KEMI HIGHWAY

The Elasticity of Taxable Income: A Non-Technical Summary

Keywords: Overlapping Generations Model, Tax Reform, Turkey

A Simple Model of Price Dispersion *

Falling Trade Costs, Heterogeneous Firms, and Industry Dynamics

Macroeconomic impact of Pannonia Ethanol in Hungary

Macroeconomic Effects of Financial Shocks Online Appendix

Intermediate Macroeconomics: The Real Business Cycle Model

Conditional guidance as a response to supply uncertainty

FDI VERSUS EXPORTS: MULTIPLE HOST COUNTRIES AND EMPIRICAL EVIDENCE

Lecture 1: Asset Allocation

Economic Growth. (c) Copyright 1999 by Douglas H. Joines 1

Unit 6 Plane Stress and Plane Strain

Discussion of Cacciatore and Ghironi

Instructions: Please answer all of the following questions. You are encouraged to work with one another (at your discretion).

OF PROPERTY TAX LEVY CAPS ON ECONOMIC ACTIVITY IN NEW JERSEY

Exercises Lecture 8: Trade policies

Allocative Effi ciency, Mark-ups, and the Welfare Gains from Trade

Sample Midterm Solutions

INTRODUCTION TO ADVANCED MACROECONOMICS Preliminary Exam with answers September 2014

ON THE JOB SEARCH AND WORKING CAPITAL

Economic Development and Gains from Trade

Documentation of the Applied Dynamic Analysis of the Global Economy (ADAGE) Model

Macro Effects of Disability Insurance

Chapter 12 Unemployment and Inflation

MICROECONOMICS AND POLICY ANALYSIS - U8213 Professor Rajeev H. Dehejia Class Notes - Spring 2001

CH 10 - REVIEW QUESTIONS

Quality Ladders, Competition and Endogenous Growth Michele Boldrin and David K. Levine

Lecture 3: The Theory of the Banking Firm and Banking Competition

Competition, Markups, and the Gains from International Trade

The elements used in commercial codes can be classified in two basic categories:

The impact of increased efficiency in the use of energy: A computable general equilibrium analysis for Spain

Chapter 4: Labor Demand Elasticities

Employment and Pricing of Inputs

Pricing in a Competitive Market with a Common Network Resource

Multi-variable Calculus and Optimization

Trade and Resources: The Heckscher-Ohlin Model. Professor Ralph Ossa International Commercial Policy

Real Business Cycle Models

Documents de Travail du Centre d Economie de la Sorbonne

Mundell Revisited: A simple approach to the Costs and Benefits of a Single Currency Area. Abstract

Agricultural Technology and Marketing Margins in Vietnam 1. Henning Tarp Jensen Department of Economics University of Copenhagen

How to Calculate the True Gains From Trade

Further Discussion of Temporary Payroll Tax Cut During Recession(s) Mark Bils and Pete Klenow, December 12, 2008

Schooling, Political Participation, and the Economy. (Online Supplementary Appendix: Not for Publication)

Trade, Technology Adoption and the Rise of the Skill Premium in Mexico

Inflation. Chapter Money Supply and Demand

8. Simultaneous Equilibrium in the Commodity and Money Markets

R&D cooperation with unit-elastic demand

Existence of J-Curve between Thailand and ASEAN: A Real Business Cycle Perspective

Chapter 1. Introduction

International Trade Lecture 3: The Ricardian Model (Theory)

Implications of Intellectual Property Rights for Dynamic Gains from Trade

CARLETON ECONOMIC PAPERS

Economic Growth: Theory and Empirics (2012) Problem set I

Transcription:

Trade and Welfare: Does industrial organization matter? Edward J. Balistreri Colorado School of Mines Russell H. Hillberry University of Melbourne September 2009 Thomas F. Rutherford ETH Zürich Abstract Many contemporary theoretic studies of trade over geography reduce to an examination of constant-elasticity reactions to changes in iceberg trade costs. These impacts are readily analyzed in simple constant-returns models based on the Armington (1969) assumption of regionally differentiated goods. Following the line of reasoning suggested by Arkolakis et al. (2008) one can reach the surprising conclusion that industrial organization does not matter. In the present paper, we show that this finding is fragile, and with a minor elaboration of their model, the rich industrial-organization features of the popular Melitz (2003) model do, in fact, generate important differences for trade and welfare. Keywords: Variety effects; Heterogeneous firms; Gains from trade JEL classification: F1 1 Introduction Arkolakis et al. (2008) show that, given appropriate parameterization to match trade responses, many contemporary theoretic models of trade over geography generate equivalent gains from trade. We can push this result further to show equivalence between a model based on the Melitz (2003) theory of heterogeneous firms and a simple constant-returns Corresponding author: Engineering Hall 311, Division of Economics and Business, Colorado School of Mines, Golden, CO 80401-1887, USA; email: ebalistr@mines.edu; voice: (303) 384-2156; fax: (303) 273-3416.

model based on the Armington (1969) assumption of trade in regional aggregates. We show, however, that this result is fragile. Addition of a second sector which competes for factor services breaks the equivalence. That is, if the elasticity of factor supply to the traded sector is larger than zero the models will produce divergent assessments of the impact of commercial policy on trade and welfare. 2 Models Our analysis begins with two models calibrated to a common benchmark dataset, one model based on Melitz (2003) and another based on Armington (1969) as elaborated by Devarajan et al. (1993). In our simulations we include three regions (indexed by r or s). Each region is endowed with a primary factor (labor) which can be used in a traded sector or directly consumed as leisure. Trade theories concerning these models are well developed in the literature, so we simply present our notation and the equilibrium conditions for each model. The theoretical setup employed by Arkolakis et al. (2008) is a special case of the Melitz model when we parameterize it such that the implied factor-supply elasticity to the traded sector is zero. 1 Tables 1 and 2 define our notation, and the algebraic formulation of the alternative models is presented in Table 3. Given the initial conditions and values of the fixed parameters, the calibrated parameters of the Melitz model are found by inverting the equilibrium conditions. The Armington distribution parameters (the ξ rs ) are calculated such that the Armington and Melitz models have identical benchmark trade flows. In the calibration we choose labor and welfare units such that the initial wages and true- 1 Our setup is equivalent to having a second constant-returns sector which uses only labor. The labor supply elasticity to the traded sector is zero either when the value share of the non-traded sector is zero or when preferences are Cobb-Douglas. 2

Table 1: Variables Melitz Armington Welfare: W r Unit expenditure index: e r Price index on traded composite: P r Nominal demand for traded composite: V r Number of entered firms: M r Number of operating firms: N rs Average-firm revenues: r rs Average-firm price: p rs Average-firm productivity: ϕ rs Wage: w r Nominal income: Y r Table 2: Parameters Fixed parameters: Pareto shape parameter: a = 3.4 Pareto lower support: b = 0.2 Substitution elasticity Melitz varieties: σ M = 3.8 Substitution elasticity Armington varieties: σ A = 4.4 (= a + 1) Probability of firm death: δ = 0.05 Value share of traded sector: γ = 0.5 Labor endowment L = 2/3 Instruments: Iceberg trade-cost factor: τ rs Top-level substitution elasticity between traded and non-traded goods: α Assumed initial conditions: Benchmark home-market trade cost factor: τrr 0 = 1.0 Benchmark external-market trade cost factor: τrs 0 = 2.0 ( r s) Benchmark number of entered firms: m 0 r = 10 Benchmark number of operating home firms: n 0 rr = 9.5 Benchmark number of operating export firms: n 0 rs = 0.6 ( r s) Calibrated parameters: Fixed operating-cost on r to s link: f rs Fixed cost of productivity draw: fr e Preference weight on traded sector: ψ T Preference weight on non-traded sector: ψ L Armington bilateral CES weights: ξ rs 3

Table 3: Algebraic Conditions Melitz Armington (eq.) Top-level unit expenditure function: a e r = ( ψ T Pr 1 α + ψ L wr 1 α ) 1/(1 α) (1) Price index on traded aggregate: P r = ( s N sr p 1 σ M sr P r = ( s ξ sr(τ sr w s ) 1 σ A ) 1/(1 σm ) ) 1/(1 σa ) Nominal demand for traded aggregate: V r = ψ T Y r ( er P r ) α 1 (3) Firm-level nominal demand: ( ) σm 1 r rs = V Ps s p rs (2a) (2b) (4) Optimal pricing: w p rs = r τ rs ϕ rs (1 1/σ M ) (5) Free entry: w r δf e r = s N rs M r r rs (σ M 1) aσ M (6) Zero cutoff profits: w r f rs = rrs(a+1 σ M ) aσ M (7) Average productivity: ( ) 1/(σM 1) ( ) 1/a a ϕ rs = b Nrs a+1 σ M M r (8) Labor market ( clearance: ) α Y L r = ψ r er L e r w r + δf e r M r + s N rs ( ) α Y L r = ψ r er L e r w r + ξ rs τ rs V s s P s ( ) f rs + τrs rrs ϕ rs p rs (9a) ( Ps τ rs w r ) σa (9b) Nominal Income: Y r = w r L (10) Welfare: W r = Y r /e r (11) a If α = 1 this reverts to the familiar Cobb-Douglas form. 4

cost-of-living indexes are one; w 0 r = e 0 r = 1. This is a convenient choice because it simplifies our calculation of the elasticity of labor supply available to the traded sector of the economy. The relevant residual labor supply function is given by Y r g(w r ) = L r ψ L e r (w r ) ( ) α er (w r ), (12) w r which is derived from equation (9a). Substituting in the unit expenditure function and Y r = w r Lr, and then calculating the elasticity evaluated at the benchmark (w = e(w) = 1), yields η = (1 γ)(α 1) = α 1. (13) 2 So, we use the instrument, α, to control the implied labor supply elasticity. If we set α = 1 then the elasticity is zero and we have a model that is consistent with Arkolakis et al. (2008). 2 3 Experiment and Results In order to compare the Armington versus Melitz models we compute a simple experiment where we eliminate iceberg trade costs between regions one and two. Using the instrument α, we control the implied labor-supply elasticity (η) faced by the trade sectors. Setting the Armington elasticity as suggested by Arkolakis et al. (2008) (σ A = a + 1), we find that the welfare impacts of removing the iceberg costs are different across the models, except in the special case that the implied labor-supply elasticity is exactly zero. Figure 1 plots the region-1 welfare impact of reductions in trade-costs as a function of the implied labor-supply elasticity. Notice that the welfare impacts are only equivalent at η = 0. The results for region 2 are identical to region 1, because of the symmetry built into 2 We also ran experiments where we fixed α = 3 and calibrated γ to the assumed labor-supply elasticity. Again, at values of η above zero the models did not generate the same results. It is only in the special case that γ = 1 is equivalence between the Armington and Melitz models is obtained. 5

20 Figure 1: Region-1 welfare comparison (σ A = a + 1) Armington Melitz 18 Percent Equivalent Variation 16 14 12 10 8 6-0.4-0.2 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 1.2 1.4 1.6 Implied Factor-supply Elasticity for Traded Sector our illustrative model. Figure 2 shows the welfare impacts on the third region for the same set of experiments. Although the curves in Figure 2 intersect twice, it is only at η = 0 that we have equivalence in the models across the multiregion equilibrium. One key feature of the environment set up by Arkolakis et al. (2008) is that the number of entered firms is unaffected by changes in iceberg costs. Labor supply is perfectly inelastic so all of the adjustments in firm revenues and number of operating firms shows up in the wage. Changes in nominal entry costs are mirrored by changes in expected profits, so equation (6) is satisfied with no changes in M r. At η 0, however, the wage only partially absorbs the adjustments in the industrial organization and M r changes. In Table 4 we present the basic industrial organization in the Melitz model in the benchmark and in scenarios with different labor supply responses. At η = 1 we have entry as labor is drawn into the Melitz sector. At η = 0 Table 4 shows the anti-variety effect emphasized by Baldwin and Forslid (forthcoming) where the new import varieties generated by trade liberalization are more than 6

-0.15-0.2 Figure 2: Region-3 welfare comparison (σ A = a + 1) Armington Melitz -0.25 Percent Equivalent Variation -0.3-0.35-0.4-0.45-0.5-0.55-0.6-0.4-0.2 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 1.2 1.4 1.6 Implied Factor-supply Elasticity for Traded Sector Table 4: Heterogeneous-firms model region-1 entry and consumption of varieties Benchmark Scenario Scenario η = 0 η = 1 Entered Firms: M 1 10.00 10.00 12.30 Varieties Consumed: N 1,1 9.50 5.47 6.77 N 2,1 0.59 3.61 4.47 N 3,1 0.59 0.48 0.53 Total Varieties: r N r,1 10.69 9.55 11.77 Feenstra Ratio: (λ 1 1/λ 0 1) 1/(σ M 1) 1.00 1.08 7

offset by lost domestic varieties. Notice, however, that the total number of varieties consumed in region 1 goes from 10.69 in the benchmark to 11.77 in the scenario, when η = 1. The anti-variety effect is dominated when there is enough response in factor supplies. Feenstra (forthcoming) emphasizes, however, that because these varieties enter the expenditure system at different prices we cannot simply count up varieties and infer variety gains or losses. Feenstra shows that variety gains, when comparing equilibriums t versus t 1, are given by deviations in the ratio (λ t r/λ t 1 r ) 1/(σ M 1) from unity, where λ z r represents region-r s share of expenditures at equilibrium z on goods available in both equilibria to the total expenditures at z. We confirm the Feenstra (forthcoming) analytical result that there are no importvariety gains or losses in the Melitz structure (for the case that η = 0), but we find that the variety gains reemerge when we allow resources to be drawn into the Melitz sector. To emphasize fundamental differences between the Armington and Melitz models we look at trade flows. In the case that η = 0 the trade patterns before and after the removal of trade costs are identical. One might think that σ A parameter can be set to match the trade reactions in the Melitz model when η 0, but this is not the case. If we adjust σ A to match some of the Melitz-model trade flows the errors on other flows in the bilateral matrix become larger. (Norman (1990) reached a similar conclusion nearly 20 years ago.) 4 Conclusion Arkolakis et al. (2008) analyze a single sector model with heterogeneous-firms and concluded that new theories do not really offer new gains from trade, given observed trade levels. We replicate this finding in comparing Armington and Melitz formulations with iceberg trade costs. Provided that the labor supply elasticity is zero and the Armington elasticity of substitution equal to one plus the Melitz Pareto-shape parameter, these models are idential. This result is, however, fragile. If the labor-supply elasticity is different than zero the 8

industrial organization begins to matter. Firm entry and import variety effects become important if the labor-supply elasticity is not zero. References Arkolakis, Costas, Svetlana Demidova, Peter J. Klenow, and Andrés Rodríguez-Clare (2008) Endogenous variety and the gains from trade. American Economic Review: Papers & Proceedings 98(2), 444 450 Armington, Paul S. (1969) A theory of demand for products distinguished by place of production. Staff Papers - International Monetary Fund 16(1), 159 178 Baldwin, Richard, and Rikard Forslid (forthcoming) Trade liberalization with heterogeneous firms. Review of Development Economics Devarajan, Shanta, Jeffrey D. Lewis, and Sherman Robinson (1993) Policy lessons from trade-focused, two-sector models. Journal of Policy Modeling 12, 625 657 Feenstra, Robert C. (forthcoming) Measuring the gains from trade under monopolistic competition. Canadian Journal of Economics Melitz, Marc J. (2003) The impact of trade on intra-industry reallocations and aggregate industry productivity. Econometrica 71(6), 1695 1725 Norman, Victor D. (1990) Assessing trade and welfare effects of trade liberalization: A comparison of alternative approaches to CGE modelling with imperfect competition. European Economic Review 34, 725 745 9