Number 2 2007. Year 1998. Year 1996. Year 1995. Year 1997



Similar documents
Health Care Systems: Efficiency and Policy Settings

HEALTH CARE DELIVERY IN BRITAIN AND GERMANY: TOWARDS CONVERGENCE?

Waiting times and other barriers to health care access

PUBLIC VS. PRIVATE HEALTH CARE IN CANADA. Norma Kozhaya, Ph.D Economist, Montreal economic Institute CPBI, Winnipeg June 15, 2007

PUBLIC & PRIVATE HEALTH CARE IN CANADA

relating to household s disposable income. A Gini Coefficient of zero indicates

4/17/2015. Health Insurance. The Framework. The importance of health care. the role of government, and reasons for the costs increase

Hong Kong s Health Spending 1989 to 2033

TOWARDS PUBLIC PROCUREMENT KEY PERFORMANCE INDICATORS. Paulo Magina Public Sector Integrity Division

International comparisons of obesity prevalence

What Is the Total Public Spending on Education?

SWECARE FOUNDATION. Uniting the Swedish health care sector for increased international competitiveness

Expenditure and Outputs in the Irish Health System: A Cross Country Comparison

The U.S Health Care Paradox: How Spending More is Getting Us Less

Delegation in human resource management

INEQUALITIES IN HEALTH CARE SERVICES UTILISATION IN OECD COUNTRIES

How To Understand The Health Care System In The United States

Cross-country comparison of health care system efficiency

Health Care Reform in Korea: Key Challenges

POLICY BRIEF. Private Health Insurance in OECD Countries. Introduction. Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development

THE ORGANISATION AND FINANCING OF HEALTH CARE SYSTEM IN LATVIA

Private Health insurance in the OECD

Public / private mix in health care financing

Private Health insurance in the OECD

Ageing OECD Societies

WEEK 10 SUPPLY SIDE REFORM AND REIMBURSEMENT. Activity- based funding versus block grants

Health Care a Public or Private Good?

Health Care in Crisis

41 T Korea, Rep T Netherlands T Japan E Bulgaria T Argentina T Czech Republic T Greece 50.

Social insurance, private insurance and social protection. The example of health care systems in some OECD countries

Preventing fraud and corruption in public procurement

Insurance corporations and pension funds in OECD countries

Early Childhood Education and Care

WELFARE STATES AND PUBLIC HEALTH: AN INTERNATIONAL COMPARISON. Peter Abrahamson University of Copenhagen

INTERNATIONAL PRIVATE PHYSICAL THERAPY ASSOCIATION DATA SURVEY

Expenditure on Health Care in the UK: A Review of the Issues

Health Care Systems: An International Comparison. Strategic Policy and Research Intergovernmental Affairs May 2001

A Comparison of the Tax Burden on Labor in the OECD By Kyle Pomerleau

The Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania. Hillsdale College

What Proportion of National Wealth Is Spent on Education?

International Women's Day PwC Women in Work Index

Updated development of global greenhouse gas emissions 2013

Public and private health insurance: where to mark to boundaries? June 16, 2009 Kranjska Gora, Slovenia Valérie Paris - OECD

(OECD, 2012) Equity and Quality in Education: Supporting Disadvantaged Students and Schools

How many students study abroad and where do they go?

Size and Development of the Shadow Economy of 31 European and 5 other OECD Countries from 2003 to 2015: Different Developments

INTERNATIONAL COMPARISONS OF PART-TIME WORK

PRINCIPLES FOR EVALUATION OF DEVELOPMENT ASSISTANCE

Review of R&D Tax Credit. Invitation for Submissions

Employee eligibility to work in the UK

Social health insurance in Belgium. Charlotte Wilgos & Thomas Rousseau

VULNERABILITY OF SOCIAL INSTITUTIONS

Private health care cost containment and supply-side regulation. CMS presentation to the Health Portfolio Committee 2014

The O rg a n iz ati on f or Economic

Swe den Structure, delive ry, administration He althcare Financing Me chanisms and Health Expenditures Quality of Bene fits, C hoice, Access

Improving the quality and flexibility of data collection from financial institutions

Background Briefing. Hungary s Healthcare System

How To Calculate Tertiary Type A Graduation Rate

PERMANENT AND TEMPORARY WORKERS

ORGANISATION FOR ECONOMIC CO-OPERATION AND DEVELOPMENT

The Netherlands. Highlights from A Good Life in Old Age? Monitoring and Improving Quality in Long-Term Care, OECD Publishing, 2013.

Cross-national data on child maltreatment, policy and legislation across the OECD

Higher Education in Finland

Social security: Iceland

Overview of the OECD work on transfer pricing

CO1.2: Life expectancy at birth

With data up to: May Monthly Electricity Statistics

International investment continues to struggle

Public Sector and it s Functions. The framework. Why we need public sector? What is the public sector?

Eliminating Double Taxation through Corporate Integration

Working Holiday Maker visa programme report. 31 December 2014

VOLUNTARY HEALTH INSURANCE AS A METHOD OF HEALTH CARE FINANCING IN EUROPEAN COUNTRIES

Accountable Care Organization Workgroup Glossary

AGREEMENT ON AN INTERNATIONAL ENERGY PROGRAM. (As amended 30 November 2007)

Is Medicare sustainable? and, Is this question helpful or not?

Higher education institutions as places to integrate individual lifelong learning strategies

Working Holiday Maker visa programme report

On What Resources and Services Is Education Funding Spent?

VISA AND RESIDENCE PERMIT FOR GERMANY FOR INTERNATIONAL STUDENTS AND Ph.D. STUDENTS

How To Compare Health Care In European Countries

Government at a Glance 2015

U.S. Health Care Spending: Comparison with Other OECD Countries

skills mismatches & finding the right talent incl. quarterly mobility, confidence & job satisfaction

Belgium (Fr.) Australia. Austria. England. Belgium (Fl.) United States 2. Finland 2. Norway 2. Belgium (Fr.) Australia. Austria Norway 2, 4.

Trends in Digitally-Enabled Trade in Services. by Maria Borga and Jennifer Koncz-Bruner

Private Health Insurance in OECD Countries

Lecture 7: Policy Design: Health Insurance & Adverse Selection

(OECD, 2012) Equity and Quality in Education: Supporting Disadvantaged Students and Schools

(OECD, 2012) Equity and Quality in Education: Supporting Disadvantaged Students and Schools

COMMUNICATION FROM THE COMMISSION

Testing Theories of Policy-Making: Educational Funding MICAH MCFADDEN

FISCAL CONSOLIDATION: HOW MUCH IS NEEDED TO REDUCE DEBT TO A PRUDENT LEVEL?

HEALTH PROFESSIONALS IN EUROPE: NEW ROLES, NEW SKILLS

Evolution of Territorial Tax Systems in the OECD

Gilead Transparency Reporting Methodological Note

ANNUAL HOURS WORKED. Belgium:

UTX Europe V2 - Enhancements

SURVEY OF INVESTMENT REGULATION OF PENSION FUNDS. OECD Secretariat

Reporting practices for domestic and total debt securities

U.S. Health Care Spending: Comparison with Other OECD Countries

Transcription:

Number 2 2007 PROVIDER PAYMENTS AND COST-CONTAINMENT LESSONS FROM OECD COUNTRIES Historically the OECD countries have struggled to curb their public spending on health care through the use of both demand-oriented and supply side regulations. Empirical evidence suggests that the simultaneous use of different provider payment methods can restrain expenditure on health while maintaining good quality care and fair access to services. Regulatory commitment is necessary to maximize the efficiency of these tools. The need for health care cost-containment To a large extent, the pressures for cost-containment are attributable to the higher growth rate of health spending compared to aggregate income. One reason is that because of aging more medical services are needed. Further medical technology advanced remarkable in the last years, so treatments often have become more expensive. Intervention for cost-containment is deemed necessary when 'capacity to pay' of the economy as a whole is lower than the costs of the population's health care requirement; generally the latter relates to budget constraints in the public sector as well as to limits on what households can afford to allocate to health from their incomes. Figure 1 shows that both GDP and total expenditure on health care (THE) have increased in the OECD 1 countries, with the rate of growth of THE systematically being higher. The red area indicates the gap from the disproportional increase in health spending. Since 1997 this gap has widened: illustrated by THE accounting for 8.8 % of GDP in 2003 compared to 7.8% in 1997. Figure 1. Nominal average growth rate of GDP and THE in the OECD countries (1990 as reference point: GDP =16,033 and THE=1,205 at international dollar per capita). THE GDP 2 1.8 1.6 1.4 1.2 1 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 1 The OECD refers to Organization for Economic Cooperation Development and has 30 member countries: Australia, Austria, Belgium, Canada, Czech Republic, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Hungary, Iceland, Italy, Japan, Republic of Korea, Luxembourg, Mexico, Netherlands, New Zealand, Norway, Poland, Portugal, Slovak, Spain, Sweden, Switzerland, Turkey, UK, and USA.

Overview of cost-containment instruments The introduction of cost containment instruments dates back to the 1970s during the global economic recession but its pervasive use in the OECD countries has only been apparent since 1990 due to the occurrence of public deficits in several OECD-countries, especially in the period 1990-95. Cost-containment instruments can be classified into four groups, on the basis of whether they are monetary or non monetary and designed to target providers or consumers. Currently the OECD countries widely use monetary incentives to restrain consumer demand in the form of co-payments: consumers have to meet part of the cost of services out-of-pocket and health insurance and/or government pays the rest. They also use many non-monetary incentives to regulate provider behavior, including clinical guidelines, clinical pathway management or the use of standardized evidence-based treatments. However, attention has focused increasingly on the use of monetary incentives targeting providers. Provider payment schemes and their impacts Most would agree that the level and structure of provider payments are a core element for influencing providers' behavior. To pay providers has been an area of contention among policy makers. The most prevalent provider payment methods among OECD members are salaries, feefor-service payments, diagnosis related groups, capitation or per-diem payments. Another way of paying providers is via a budget remunerating a set of pre-defined health-related activities in a lump-sum fashion. For the sake of this technical brief, we focus on individual doctors and hospitals as providers. Salary All OECD countries make a partial or complete use of salaries for paying doctors, whether they are working as individual doctors or within the context of hospitals. Under salary payment doctors' income is not linked to output such as quantity of items or quality of services. Therefore, salaried doctors in the public sector are often associated with low motivation, low productivity and low quality of services. Recently, however, salaries are also being combined with capitation and performance based components to promote motivation as well as higher productivity and quality. As personnel costs are only one part of the total treatment costs it is important to see in which context salaries are used as a provider payment method. For example there can be a notable impact from hospital management on hospital doctors' treatment decisions if salaries are paid under strict budgetary limitations, prompting doctors to favour low cost treatments and perhaps tolerating treatments of lower quality. Fee-for-service (FFS) The FFS method pays providers according to number of services delivered. As it gives them a strong incentive to deliver more and lucrative items, FFS can be a bad instrument for containing costs. Nonetheless, especially in ambulatory care, FFS has been popular in several OECD countries where the majority of physicians are private; for example, it has been an important payment method in Belgium, Germany, Japan, the Republic of Korea, Switzerland and the US. In those countries patients enjoy the freedom to directly choose their physician and generally benefit from an adequate access to health care services. Doctors working within this FFS framework also undertake efforts to improve the quality of health care services in order to attract more patients. There are situations, however, where FFS can be made coherent with cost-containment policy. For example, in Germany in the last years FFS payments are combined with sectoral budgets for ambulatory care. Each type of service is linked to a specific number of points. The value for each 2

point is obtained by dividing the sectoral budget for ambulatory care by the total number of points 'produced' by all general practitioners. A doctor's final remuneration (paid on quarterly basis) is then equivalent to the total value of the points he 'earned' through his provision of health services. Diagnosis Related Groups (DRG) The Diagnosis-Related Groups (DRG)-system is a patient classification system developed to classify patients into groups economically and medically similar, expected to have comparable hospital resource use and costs. Under DRGs providers are reimbursed at a fixed rate per discharge based on diagnosis, treatment and type of discharge. Therefore DRGs have a strong incentive for cost containment. As the remuneration refers to diagnoses and procedures, providers are motivated to deliver services as cost-effective as possible with the shortest possible length of stay. On the other hand, concerns about premature discharges, selection of low-cost patients and the increase of admissions should be dealt with. Therefore quality and monitoring measures are essential to avoid negative side effects. The first DRG payment system was introduced in 1983 for US Medicare. By now a form of DRG-system is adopted by several OECD members. Australia began to pilot the American system in 1985 and has now developed its own DRG-system. As recent examples, since 2003 Germany is developing its own DRG-system based on the Australian system. Switzerland decided to use the German base for the future introduction of Swiss-DRGs. Capitation With capitation scheme providers are paid a fixed amount of money on the basis of number of patients for delivering a range of services. The predominantly tax-based health financing systems in Italy and the UK have adopted this payment method for general practitioners (GPs) to provide primary care to the population. Underprovision of services within the risk group, for which a particular flat-rate capitation amount is applicable, is a problem to be dealt with. Adjusted capitation payment according to patients' profile such as age and sex can help guaranteeing quality of service and equitable access, by stimulating GPs to accept and treat patients with various characteristics rather than shifting a number of them to specialists or hospitals. In the US, capitation payments are pervasive in both outpatient and inpatient care, especially within the framework of Health Maintenance Organizations (HMOs) or managed care plans. Per Diem Daily payment gives hospitals a strong incentive to increase the number of admissions and to extend the length of stay, thereby enhancing health expenditure. Norway abandoned per diem payments at the beginning of the 1980s and over the past years health reforms in the OECD countries confirm the trend of a limited use of daily payment. For example, an excessively high length of stay under the per diem payment scheme was one main reason for Germany to introduce DRGs for the remuneration of inpatient care. Budget Since 1970s budgets have been introduced as health care cost-containment instruments in a substantial number of OECD countries. One can first distinguish budgets for the whole health care system, and budgets for parts of it such as for ambulatory care, hospital care, pharmaceuticals etc. These are referred to as global and sectoral budgets, respectively. Budgets are also being set for health facilities such as hospitals, as is the case in France. However, this does not preclude hospitals from using other provider payment methods. For example, DRGs may 3

well be used to remunerate specific hospital departments, all the while respecting a predetermined budget for the hospital as a whole. In this sense, budgets are different from other provider payment schemes: they are used more to allocate pre-determined amounts of money to providers, thereby setting the framework for the subsequent introduction of other provider payment schemes. Whether cost-containment can be achieved, depends on the type of budget and its rigidity. First, to reflect the degree of rigidity, one can distinguish hard and soft budgets. Under hard budgets providers are fully responsible for all profits and losses while soft budgets entail a fixed amount of spending but without penalty in case of excess. Therefore, the hard type is more effective for cost-containment but may reduce access and quality of services or produce waiting lists. In terms of cost-containment potential, only hard global and sectoral budgets are effective. With soft budgets, the risk of overspending is large. For example, a system of sectoral budgets may raise overall health expenditure due to shifting of patients and their need for health services to other sectors. The findings on advantages and disadvantages of different provider payment methods used in OECD countries are summarized in table1. Table1. Summary of advantages and disadvantages of alternative provider payment methods Provider payment Salary Budget DRG Potential Advantages Cost containment, equitable provision, easy administration Cost containment, simple to administrate Cost containment, cost-effective treatment, reduction in unnecessary care Possible Disadvantages Low productivity, low quality of service, low moral of providers, informal payment with out -of-pocket money Low investment in technologies, selection of patients, patient shifting, substitution costs under sectoral budget Selection of patients, increase in admission, premature discharge, monitoring cost, under-treatment Empirical Evidence of a selected country In Hungary, most medical specialists are public employees and salaried. Physicians receive the bulk of informal payments. Since 2002, the current government has raised the salary by an average of 50% to tackle the problem. The German hospital care system uses flexible budgets to control expenditures. Every hospital has a budget. In case of exceeding this budget hospitals get only the variable costs of the DRG remuneration inside the budget corresponding to around 35 % of the surplus. Therefore hospitals have a strong incentive to stay inside the budget. In Australia DRG payment is considered to be efficient but criticized for quicker but sicker discharge. Attention now is being paid to developing comparable measures of quality and health outcomes. FFS High accessibility, high quality in the presence of competition Overprovision, high administration cost The Belgian reforms in 1990s were focused mainly on eliminating abuse, inefficiency, over supply and over consumption resulted from the nature of FFS system. Capitation (GP based care) Cost containment, provision of preventive care Under provision, increase in referral to hospitals and specialists, low quality of care In Spain general practitioners receive a fixed salary plus a capitation component. This can depend either on the age of patients they treat or the nature of the population in their service area, e.g. the percentage of the population over 65 years of age. The exact kind of capitation component depends on the province as it is responsible for the regional health system. 4

Provider payment Potential Advantages Possible Disadvantages Empirical Evidence of a selected country Per diem Simple administration, more attention given to patients Increase in number of admission and length of stays, provision of less cost effective treatment Until 1995, Luxembourgian hospitals were financed mainly on the basis of a uniform per diem payment. Following a financial shortfall the government abolished it and introduced a prospective payment system. Simultaneous use of provider payment schemes Generally speaking, salary, budget, and capitation are expected to have a strong effect on costcontainment but cause concerns on low productivity and quality. In contrast DRG, FFS, and Per Diem encourage providers to deliver more and better services but give no incentives for restraining costs, unless these forms of provider payment are applied within the framework of hard budgets or in the case of a competitive environment. Historically different types of providers in the same country have been paid according to different methods. However, reforms in the OECD countries demonstrate a movement towards the simultaneous use of different provider payment methods, in other words paying the same provider in different ways. For example, the Finnish government remunerates its physicians under the personal doctor system as follows: a basic salary (60%), a capitation amount (20%), FFS (15%) and a local allowance (5%). The rationale behind a mixed payment system is that a combination of alternative methods can compensate for the weakness of a single provider payment scheme. Some reform experiences with mixed payment methods in the OECD countries are presented in table 2. Table 2. Combination of provider payment methods Combination Countries Theoretical background Reform Experience of a selected country Capitation + FFS Czech, Denmark, Finland, Italy, New Zealand, Norway, Portugal, Slovakia, UK DRG + Budget FFS + Budget Australia, Czech, Denmark, Germany, Hungary, Italy, New Zealand, Norway Czech, Hungary, Netherlands, Poland FFS encourages providers to reduce number of referrals to hospitals. The case mix adjusted budget will improve accessibility of services The tendency of overprovision of services under FFS can be capped by limits on price or volume. The 1992 and 1999 Italian reforms complemented the basic capitation fee given to GPs and pediatricians with additional FFS remuneration for specific treatments (e.g. minor surgery, preventive cares, post surgery follow up). In Portugal the case-mix adjusted component of each hospital budget has been increased; the implementation of the model started in 1997 as 10% DRG-based and reached 50% in fiscal year 2002. Since 2000, in Dutch hospital financing efforts have been undertaken to integrate the fee-for-service system for specialists and the hospital budget system into a single integrated budget. 5

Policy development and regulatory commitment The combination of various provider payment methods has been arrived at after evaluating the outcomes of using a single provider payment method. For example, in the Czech Republic since mid-1997 hospital inpatient health care has been remunerated according to a budget. This was the result of some problems with the previous points-based FFS payment system, implemented from 1993 to 1997. Since 2001, in addition to these budgets, DRG payment has been introduced so as to improve productivity in hospitals and stimulate the provision of cost-effective treatments. From the Czech reform experience, a sequence for the development of a particular health policy can be distilled, starting from the need for cost-containment need up to the monitoring of results of that policy. These results may then feed back into the design of an adjusted policy. Box 1 illustrates the process of undertaking a pharmaceutical reform in the Republic of Korea in the year 2001. Box 1. Policy development sequence INTERVENTION REQUIRED POLICY DESIGN IMPLEMENTATION & INTRODUCTION RESULTS Drug costs in Korea Total expenditure on drugs in 2000: 28,2% of THE versus the OECD average of 17,2%. Drug as major income source for physicians: 40% of total revenue The 2001 Reform Separation between dispensing and prescription to contain costs, to reduce overuse of antibiotics, and to rectify pharmaceutical industries' illegal marketing activities Resistance Physicians' nationwide strike against reform. Public support for eliminating super profit of physicians The parliamentary approved the law in 2001 Perverse Outcome Drug costs as a share of total health expenditure in 2003: 28.8% Patient channeling and collusion among physicians and pharmacists A health policy that has proved to be effective in a number of countries may not work in all countries, however. For example, the political power shown by doctors' associations in the Republic of Korea against the 2001 pharmaceutical reform had a critical impact on policy development. Still, the separation between prescription and dispensing of drugs has been approved thanks to a strong commitment of the government and to public support. However, the operation has not been successful so far. Physicians attempt to maintain their income by channeling patients to colluding pharmacies nearby their practice offices. One of the lessons from this policy process is that regulatory instruments need to be foreseen so as to ensure that a policy's objectives will be met. Competition framework More competition in health care is a further important factor for cost containment. In the last years most of the OECD-member states have strengthened the influence of competition in their health care system to enhance efficiency and to promote cost-containment. It follows that the impact of provider payment schemes will need to be assessed taking account of the competition framework. In general all provider payment schemes can be used and combined, but some provider payment schemes are more appropriate for competition than others. For example DRGs are based on the principle that patients with a comparable disease, complexity and costs belong to the same DRG. The latter therefore is a good basis to let providers compete for the provision of care to these patients. Important, however, is that all providers fulfill the same quality conditions. Budgets or per diem payments are not ideal provider payment schemes in a competitive environment as it is difficult to relate these to the providers' performance. 6

Summary and important considerations Every provider payment scheme has advantages and disadvantages. An optimally mixed provider payment system with regulatory commitment can be a powerful 'side-effect free' cost containment instrument but some trade offs will be inevitable. Quality management and the use of monitoring indicators will help to minimize such side effects. The choice of the best provider payment scheme depends on a country's framework, especially the competition environment. Another important factor may be the influence of lobby groups on the sustainability of the provider payment scheme. The introduction of monetary provider incentives is mandatory for cost-containment but not sufficient for achieving a sustainable health care system. Other important factors include a continuous medical education, professional satisfaction and the human relationship with patients. Non monetary consumer incentives such as medical education may lead physicians to provide high quality and cost effective services as well. World Health Organization 2007 This brief was prepared by M. Park, T. Braun, G. Carrin, and D. Evans of the Department of Health Systems Financing (HSF). The comments by Dr Hossein Salehi are gratefully acknowledged. The views expressed in this "Technical Brief for Policy-Makers" are those of the authors, and do not necessarily reflect the official position of the World Health Organization. 7