EFFECTS OF AN RFS ON U.S. ENERGY SAVINGS, NATIONAL COSTS OF GASOLINE PRODUCTION, AND THE REGIONAL PATTERN OF ETHANOL USE



Similar documents
STATEMENT OF HOWARD GRUENSPECHT DEPUTY ADMINISTRATOR ENERGY INFORMATION ADMINISTRATION U.S. DEPARTMENT OF ENERGY BEFORE THE

Policy Options for Integrated Energy and Agricultural Markets. Wally Tyner Farzad Taheripour

Representation of LPG Retail Costs TAFV Model Technical Note DRAFT David Bowman, Paul Leiby, and Jonathan Rubin

The Journal of Science Policy & Governance

Energy in 2020: Assessing the Economic Effects of Commercialization of Cellulosic Ethanol

H.R. 702 A bill to adapt to changing crude oil market conditions

Gas Prices in Idaho. What factors determine the price of gas in Idaho?

Residential Heating Oil Prices: What Consumers Should know

PETROLEUM WATCH September 16, 2011 Fossil Fuels Office Fuels and Transportation Division California Energy Commission

Competitive Electricity Prices: An Update 1

Analysis of Whether the Prices of Renewable Fuel Standard RINs Have Affected Retail Gasoline Prices

State Ethanol Blending Laws

The$Mortar$is$Nearly$Set$ $

Weekly Petroleum Status Report

Short-Term Energy Outlook Market Prices and Uncertainty Report

Missouri Soybean Economic Impact Report

Think About Energy Summit

Policy Options for Integrated Energy and Agricultural Markets and Global Biofuels Impacts

Governor s Executive Order, Dept. of Ecology, Air Quality Program Bob Saunders

Special Report. B&O Tax Pyramiding in. Briefly

FCStone Grain Recap January 6, 2016

EIA s U.S. Crude Oil Import Tracking Tool: Selected Sample Applications

The Economic Impact of Replacing Coal with Natural Gas for Electricity Production. William A. Knudson. Working Paper

Economic Outcomes of a U.S. Carbon Tax. Executive Summary

Managing Feed and Milk Price Risk: Futures Markets and Insurance Alternatives

National Heavy Duty Truck Transportation Efficiency Macroeconomic Impact Analysis

Hydrogen Infrastructure

OUR CONVERSATION TODAY

Levelized Cost and Levelized Avoided Cost of New Generation Resources in the Annual Energy Outlook 2015

Electric Power Monthly with Data for May 2015

Issue Brief: California Compared Fuel Taxes and Fees

Reducing Carbon Pollution in D.C s Renewable Portfolio Standard Will Clean the Air without Impacting Ratepayers. Frequently Asked Questions

Commodity Trading. NRGI Reader March Converting Natural Resources into Revenues KEY MESSAGES

What Drives U.S. Gasoline Prices?

The Changing Relationship Between the Price of Crude Oil and the Price At the Pump

Short-Term Energy Outlook Market Prices and Uncertainty Report

Renewable Energy Mandates Cost Texas Consumers. Bill Peacock Texas Public Policy Foundation

Economic Benefits of Lifting the Crude Oil Export Ban

Corn Transportation Profile

Texas: An Energy and Economic Analysis

U.S. Energy Outlook. Oil and Gas Strategies Summit May 21, 2014 New York, NY. By Adam Sieminski, EIA Administrator

Energy Projections Price and Policy Considerations. Dr. Randy Hudson Oak Ridge National Laboratory

Michigan Residential Heating Oil and Propane Price Survey

Review of the Boston Consulting Group Understanding the Impact of AB32 Report. Final Report

RISK FACTORS IN ETHANOL PRODUCTION

Keisuke Sadamori Director, Energy Markets and Security International Energy Agency Kuala Lumpur, 8 October

From Biomass. NREL Leads the Way. to Biofuels

The Challenge of Co-product Management for Large-scale Energy Systems: Power, Fuel and CO₂

CALIFORNIA POLICY BRIEFING MEMO MOTOR VEHICLE FUEL DIVERSIFICATION

Review of Varshney/Tootelian Report Cost Of AB 32 On California Small Businesses Summary Report Of Findings

Annual Energy Outlook 1998

Federal legislators are considering an increase in the federal

Keeping Our Options Open: Markets for Canadian Crude and the Pipeline Dilemma

Oil Company Profits and Tax Collections: Does the U.S. Need a New Windfall Profits Tax?

REC QUESTIONS & ANSWERS

Energy Value Chains. What is a Value Chain?

site Storage 7 million gallons of feedstock storage and 10 million of biodiesel storage Plant Info

Renewable Energy on Regional Power Grids Can Help States Meet Federal Carbon Standards

public support for climate and energy policies in november 2011

United States Progress Report on Fossil Fuel Subsidies Part 1: Identification and Analysis of Fossil Fuel Provisions

Business Tax Provisions of the Tax Relief, Unemployment Insurance Reauthorization and Job Creation Act of 2010

THE EFFECTS OF RISING FUEL COSTS ON U.S. TRADE

What s Hot in Oil, Gas and Energy Equipment Leasing

1st Session LNG AND LPG EXCISE TAX EQUALIZATION ACT OF Mr. HATCH, from the Committee on Finance, submitted the following R E P O R T

Northeast Propane Infrastructure, Supply Shortages & High Cost to Consumers

3 LEGS OF THE MOTOR FUEL INDUSTRY

Electricity Rates Forecasting:

Journal of Business Valuation and Economic Loss Analysis

Appendix F Alternatives for Estimating Energy Consumption

DISCUSSION PAPER. Ex Post Costs and Renewable Identification Number (RIN) Prices under the Renewable Fuel Standard

Producer Hedging the Production of Heavy Crude Oil

Analysis for Strategic Planning Applied to Ethanol and Distillers Grain

Q D = (5)(5) = 75 Q S = 50 + (5)(5) = 75.

Comparison of CO 2 Abatement Costs in the United States for Various Low and No Carbon Resources. Total System Levelized Cost Based on EIA LCOE

How to Green Your. Township Fleet. Sponsored by Maine Township Highway Department. Purpose. How to Green Your Township Fleet

Cutting Australia s Carbon Abatement Costs with Nuclear Power

Technical/Business Planning: For Small-Scale Oilseed Processing and Biodiesel Production

The Canadian Petroleum Products Institute Tony Macerollo, Vice President, Public and Government Affairs. June 2007

Biodiesel in Oregon: Policies, Programs, and Incentives. Local. Cleaner. Better.

Colonial Pipeline Company

RESPONSE TO PUB ORDER 117/06. PUB Order 117/06 Directive 6

Effects of Removing Restrictions on U.S. Crude Oil Exports

AGRICULTURE FOR FOOD AND FOR BIOENEGY: IS IT POSSIBLE?

Electric Power Monthly with Data for October 2015

HOW EXPANDING U.S. CRUDE EXPORTS CAN MEAN CHEAPER GAS FOR AMERICANS

Canadian Oil Sands. Enhancing America s Energy Security

Natural Gas and the U.S. Fertilizer Industry

California Energy Commission California Perspective on Biofuels and Energy

Rhode Island State Energy Plan Business-As- Usual Forecast

The interplay of physical and financial layers in today's oil markets

CHANGING CRUDE OIL MARKETS. Allowing Exports Could Reduce Consumer Fuel Prices, and the Size of the Strategic Reserves Should Be Reexamined

STATE OF ARKANSAS Department of Finance and Administration

Natural Gas and Transportation Fuels

Petroleum and Renewable Fuels Supply Chain. Megan Boutwell, David J. Hackett & Michael L. Soares Stillwater Associates LLC

U.S. Crude Oil Pricing Analysis

07 14 BUSINESS-CYCLE CONDITIONS Gas Prices Not a Risk to Growth by Robert Hughes, Senior Research Fellow

Oil and Natural Gas Outlook: Implications for Alaska The Alliance Meet Alaska. Remarks by Marianne Kah Chief Economist

Oil and Gas U.S. Industry Outlook

Pet Coke Consulting, LLC. Phil Fisher Argus Conference, Houston September 19-21, 2012

Public Opinion on US Energy and Environmental Policy

Transcription:

EFFECTS OF AN RFS ON U.S. ENERGY SAVINGS, NATIONAL COSTS OF GASOLINE PRODUCTION, AND THE REGIONAL PATTERN OF ETHANOL USE Prepared for American Petroleum Institute By MathPro Inc. May 23, 25 MathPro Inc. P.O. Box 3444 West Bethesda, Maryland 2827-44 31-951-96

OVERVIEW The U.S. Congress is considering RFS proposals requiring progressively increasing volumes of ethanol in U.S. gasoline, with total ethanol use reaching 5, 6, or 8 billion gallons per year (bgy) in 212. The major effects of increasing ethanol use from the AEO 25 1 projection for 212 (3.8 bgy) to the proposed RFS volumes would include: Energy Savings. An RFS would reduce fossil energy use by about 25 3 thousand coeb/day at 5 bgy, 3 45 thousand coeb/day at 6 bgy, and 6 8 thousand coeb/day at 8 bgy with corresponding reductions in U.S. fossil fuel imports. 2 These reductions in fossil fuel imports would be less than.5% of projected net U.S. oil and natural gas imports of 17 million coeb/day in 212 3, or less than 2 months of typical recent growth in oil and natural gas imports. Cost of Energy and Import Savings. The energy and import savings from an RFS would cost about $9-$13/coeb at 5 bgy, $95-$15/coeb at 6 bgy, and $11-19/coeb at 8 bgy, over and above the price of crude oil. National Cost. An RFS would increase the cost of producing gasoline by about $.9 billion/year at 5 bgy, $1.9 billion/year at 6 bgy, and $3.8 billion/year at 8 bgy. These costs would fall on U.S. consumers (through higher costs of gasoline production) and taxpayers (through increased subsidies for ethanol production). Regional Ethanol Use. The additional ethanol use mandated by an RFS would be concentrated in the Midwest, to minimize costs, but would extend into the East Coast and Gulf Coast as well. Ethanol use in all of these regions would increase with increasing RFS mandate volume. In general, gasoline producers in the Midwest and East Coast would be net sellers of ethanol credits and gasoline producers in other regions, along with foreign suppliers, would be net buyers of ethanol credits. The findings reported here come from a detailed technical and economic analysis, originally conducted and recently updated by MathPro Inc., of the effects of an RFS on the refining economics of U.S. gasoline supply. 1 Annual Energy Outlook 25; U.S. Department of Energy/Energy Information Administration; Table 17 2 Coeb stands for crude oil equivalent barrel, a unit of energy equal to the average energy content in a barrel of crude oil. Energy flows are often expressed in coeb to place flows of oil, natural gas, coal, and other energy sources on a consistent basis. 3 AEO 25, Tables 11 and 13 May 23, 25 1

EFFECTS ON FOSSIL ENERGY SAVINGS, IMPORTS, AND ENERGY USE An RFS would provide savings in U.S. fossil energy use ranging (in energy-equivalent terms) from about 25 3 thousand coeb/day at 5 bgy, 3 45 thousand coeb/day at 6 bgy, and 6 8 thousand coeb/day at 8 bgy with corresponding reductions in U.S. fossil fuel imports (combined imports of crude oil, petroleum products, and natural gas). (Figure 1) The indicated total energy savings at all RFS levels would lead to import reductions amounting to less than.5% of projected net U.S. oil and natural gas imports of 17 million coeb/day in 212 4, or less than 2 months of typical recent growth in oil and natural gas imports. 3 2 Figure 1: Energy Savings from an RFS in 212 Extra Ethanol Use (K b/d) Total Energy Savings (K coeb/d) Domestic Energy Savings (K coeb/d) K b/d 1 5 6 8 RFS Volume (bgy) The lower numbers in each range are the net domestic savings in fossil energy use resulting from the indicated level of ethanol use; the higher number in each range is the total savings in fossil energy use, including both domestic and foreign producers of U.S. gasoline. Both U.S. producers and foreign producers of U.S. gasoline would increase their production of gasoline for ethanol blending in response to an RFS. To the extent foreign refineries do so, some the total energy savings produced by an RFS would actually be realized in the countries of origin instead of in the U.S. On the other hand, the costs of ethanol production would be incurred in the U.S., regardless of where the base gasoline blend was produced. The savings in fossil fuel use and the corresponding import displacements due to additional ethanol use result from a complex set of interactions among the various energy effects of additional ethanol use. 4 AEO 25, Tables 11 and 13 May 23, 25 2

The total energy input to corn ethanol production mainly from oil and natural gas is about 75% of ethanol s energy content. Ethanol has energy content (and fuel economy) about 66% that of gasoline. Hence, adding a gallon of ethanol to the gasoline pool displaces about.66 gallon of gasoline. Putting ethanol into low-emission gasolines such as RFG and low-rvp gasoline requires taking out some other gasoline components, in order to maintain volatility standards. Energy use for transporting ethanol via rail, truck, or barge to gasoline blending sites would increase. Refineries would accommodate additional ethanol volumes in U.S. gasoline by reducing crude oil and other inputs, refined product outputs, and energy use. The natural gas needed for additional ethanol production would be imported from sources outside North America the marginal sources of supply for both oil and natural gas. Because our analysis accounts for these and other energy effects of increased ethanol use, the total energy savings shown in Figure 1 exceed ethanol s net energy value alone. Figure 2 illustrates the net effect on total fossil energy use of the various energy effects of ethanol use. 1 5 Figure 2: Effects on Energy Use of an RFS in 212, K coeb/d Net energy savings in refining less energy loss in distibution K coeb/d -5 5 6 8 Net ethanol energy contribution Energy used in corn production & transport -1-15 Energy used in ethanol conversion less by-product credit As Figure 2 indicates, the total energy savings of additional ethanol use is the sum of (1) the net energy contribution of ethanol (its total energy content minus the fossil energy inputs to produce May 23, 25 3

it) plus (2) the net energy savings in refining and distribution from reducing crude oil and other inputs, refined product outputs, and refinery energy use. The net energy contribution of ethanol changes in direct proportion to ethanol volume. But, the net energy savings in refining and distribution can change in relative terms as ethanol volume increases, because the distribution of ethanol use by region and gasoline type and other technical factors can change with ethanol volume. At all mandate volumes, some of the net energy savings in the refining industry will accrue to foreign suppliers of gasoline for ethanol blending, accounting for the difference between total energy savings and domestic energy savings. COST OF ENERGY SAVINGS The energy and import savings shown in Figure 1 would cost about $9-$13/coeb at 5 bgy, $95-$15/coeb at 6 bgy, and $11-19/coeb at 8 bgy, over and above the price of crude oil. (Figure 3) 2 18 16 Figure 3: Average Cost of RFS Energy Savings in 212 ($/coeb) Upper Bound Cost (domestic energy savings) Lower Bound Cost (total energy savings) $/coeb 14 12 1 8 4 5 6 7 8 9 Ethanol Use (bgy) The higher cost number in each range applies to the net U.S. savings in fossil energy use resulting from the indicated level of ethanol use; the lower number to the total savings in fossil energy use, including those accruing to both domestic and foreign producers of U.S. gasoline. May 23, 25 4

NATIONAL COSTS INCURRED IN GASOLINE PRODUCTION The additional ethanol use mandated by an RFS would increase the national costs of gasoline production by about $.9 billion/year at 5 bgy, $1.9 billion/year at 6 bgy, and $3.8 billion/year at 8 bgy. (Figure 4) The national cost of an RFS is the net loss in U.S. economic resources resulting from the additional ethanol use mandated by the RFS: the amount by which the full cost of meeting U.S. gasoline demand with an RFS exceeded the full cost without an RFS. These costs would fall on U.S. consumers (through higher costs of gasoline production) and taxpayers (through increased subsidies for ethanol production). 4 Figure 4: National Costs of an RFS in 212 ($ Billion/Year) 3 $ billion/year 2 1 5 6 8 RFS Volume (bgy) Ethanol use raises the cost of producing gasoline because ethanol s value as a gasoline component is less than the full cost of producing and delivering it. Furthermore, ethanol s refining value decreases and its production cost increases as the volume of ethanol use increases. Hence, the larger the RFS volume, the larger the national cost in terms of both total dollars per year and /gal of ethanol. May 23, 25 5

REGIONAL PATTERN OF ETHANOL USE The additional ethanol use mandated by an RFS would be concentrated in the Midwest, to minimize costs, but would extend into the East Coast and Gulf Coast as well. Ethanol use in all of these regions would increase with increasing RFS mandate volume. (Figure 5) K b/d 35 3 25 2 15 Figure 5: Regional Ethanol Use with an RFS in 212 (K barrels/d) Baseliine 5 bgy 6 bgy 8 bgy 1 5 PADD 1 PADD 2 PADD 3 PADDs 4&5 Calif. Region PADD 1 (New England, Mid-Atlantic, Southeast) Local ethanol use would increase by 3 K bbl/day at 5 bgy, 35 K bbl/day at 6 bgy, and 5 K bbl/day at 8 bgy. The additional ethanol would be blended into conventional gasoline and federal RFG, using base blends produced in PADD 1 refineries as well as in PADD 3 and foreign refineries. PADD 2 (Midwest) Local ethanol use would increase by 75 K bbl/day at 5 bgy, 1 K bbl/day at 6 bgy, and 19 K bbl/day at 8 bgy. The additional ethanol would be blended into conventional gasoline, federal RFG, and even low-rvp gasolines, using base blends produced in PADD 2 refineries as well as in PADD 3 and PADD 1 refineries. PADD 3 (Gulf Coast) Local ethanol use would increase by a negligible amount at 5 bgy, 1 K bbl/day at 6 bgy, and 3 K bbl/day at 8 bgy. The additional ethanol would be blended into conventional gasolines. PADD 3 refineries would produce progressively increasing volumes of base blends for ethanol blending in PADDs 1 and 2. PADDs 4& 5, ex California (Mountain States and Northwest) and California Local ethanol use would increase by only small volumes under all RFS levels. May 23, 25 6

INTER-REGIONAL CREDIT TRADING Every gasoline producer would have to comply with an RFS, either through physical ethanol blending or the use of ethanol credits. The credit-trading program associated with an RFS would allow producers who use more than their pro-rata share of ethanol to earn excess ethanol credits that could be sold; producers who use less than their pro-rata share would buy ethanol credits to make up the shortfall. A credit trading system reduces the national cost of an RFS, because it concentrates ethanol use where it is least costly. As Figure 5 suggests, all RFS mandate volumes would lead to excess ethanol credits in PADDs 1 and 2, which would be sold to buyers in the rest of the country. This sale and purchase of ethanol credits would lead to inter-regional monetary flows, and those inter-regional monetary flows would increase with increasing RFS mandate volume. 5 (Figure 6) $ million/yr 6 4 2-2 Figure 6: Revenue Flows from Ethanol Credit Trading under an RFS in 212 ($ million/yr) PADD 1 PADD 2 PADD 3 PADDs 4&5 ex CA California Foreign 5 6 8 RFS Volume (bgy) -4-6 PADD 2 could realize net revenues from trading in the range of about $125 million per year at 5 bgy to about $6 million/year at 8 bgy. PADD 1 could realize net revenues from trading in the range of $9-$11 million per year. PADD 3, PADDs 4 & 5 (ex California), California, and foreign gasoline suppliers would be net credit buyers and so would experience revenue outflows from trading. PADD 3 could experience the largest revenue outflows, ranging from about $11 million per year at 5 bgy to about $44 million per year at 8 bgy. 5 Little is known about how an ethanol credit-trading program would work. To estimate the revenue flows shown in Figure 6, we assumed that (1) surplus credits would be earned in the regions producing gasoline for ethanol blending and (2) the value of ethanol credit would reflect the difference between ethanol s purchase cost and its refining value as a gasoline component. May 23, 25 7

BASIS FOR THE FINDINGS REPORTED HERE The findings reported here come from a detailed technical and economic analysis, originally conducted and recently updated by MathPro Inc., of the effects of an RFS on the refining economics of U.S. gasoline supply. The analysis Reflects baseline ethanol use of 3.8 bgy, corresponding to DoE s projection of ethanol use in 212, without an RFS. Used (1) Department of Agriculture estimates of the net energy inputs to ethanol production (net of by-product credits); (2) Department of Energy forecasts of crude oil and natural gas prices, U.S. gasoline demand, and domestic gasoline production; and (3) Global Insight forecasts of corn prices and by-product values at different levels of ethanol use. Assumed continuation of (1) the federal excise tax credit for ethanol blending (currently at 51 /gal) after its scheduled expiration in 21, (2) the 1 psi RVP waiver for ethanol-blended conventional gasoline and (in the Midwest) low-rvp gasoline, (3) existing state tax subsidy programs for ethanol blending (e.g., Illinois, Iowa), (4) existing state ethanol mandates (e.g., Minnesota, Arizona (winter)), and (5) existing state credits for ethanol production. All prices are in 23 US$. All ethanol volumes are annual averages. May 23, 25 8

ADDENDUM to EFFECTS OF AN RFS ON U.S. ENERGY SAVINGS, NATIONAL COSTS OF GASOLINE PRODUCTION, AND THE REGIONAL PATTERN OF ETHANOL USE Prepared for American Petroleum Institute By MathPro Inc. June 3, 25 MathPro Inc. P.O. Box 3444 West Bethesda, Maryland 2827-44 31-951-96

INTRODUCTION Recently, MathPro Inc. submitted to the American Petroleum Institute an analysis of the primary energy effects of proposed Renewable Fuels Standards (RFS) being considered in Congress. Those RFS proposals call for progressively increasing volumes of ethanol in U.S. gasoline, with total ethanol use reaching 5, 6, or 8 billion gallons per year (bgy) in 212. This addendum extends the analysis to additional RFS proposals, calling for ethanol use of 1 and 12 bgy in 212. It has the same organization and format as the original report, but differs from it in terms of the ethanol mandate volumes considered. OVERVIEW The major effects of increasing ethanol use from the AEO 25 1 projection for 212 (3.8 bgy) to the proposed RFS volumes of 1 and 12 bgy would include: Energy Savings. An RFS would reduce fossil energy use by about 75-13 thousand coeb/day at 1 bgy and 85-17 thousand coeb/day at 12 bgy with corresponding reductions in U.S. fossil fuel imports. 2 The lower number in each range is the net domestic savings in fossil energy use resulting from the indicated level of ethanol use; the higher number in each range is the total savings in fossil energy use, including both domestic and foreign producers of U.S. gasoline. These reductions in fossil fuel imports would be less than 1% of projected net U.S. oil and natural gas imports of 17 million coeb/day in 212. 3 Cost of Energy and Import Savings. The energy and import savings from an RFS would cost about $12-$23/coeb at 1 bgy and $13-$27/coeb at 12 bgy. National Cost. An RFS would increase the cost of producing gasoline by about $6 billion/year at 1 bgy and $8.5 billion/year at 12 bgy. These costs would fall on U.S. consumers (through higher costs of gasoline production) and taxpayers (through increased subsidies for ethanol production). Regional Ethanol Use. The additional ethanol use mandated by an RFS would be concentrated in the Midwest, to minimize costs, but would extend into the East Coast and Gulf Coast as well. Ethanol use in all of these regions would increase with increasing RFS 1 Annual Energy Outlook 25; U.S. Department of Energy/Energy Information Administration; Table 17 2 Coeb stands for crude oil equivalent barrel, a unit of energy equal to the average energy content in a barrel of crude oil. Energy flows are often expressed in coeb to place flows of oil, natural gas, coal, and other energy sources on a consistent basis. 3 AEO 25, Tables 11 and 13 June 3, 25 1

mandate volume. In general, at the higher mandate volumes considered, gasoline producers in the Midwest, along with foreign suppliers, would be net sellers of ethanol credits; gasoline producers in other regions would be net buyers of ethanol credits. The findings reported here come from a detailed technical and economic analysis, originally conducted and recently updated by MathPro Inc., of the effects of an RFS on the refining economics of U.S. gasoline supply. EFFECTS ON FOSSIL ENERGY SAVINGS, IMPORTS, AND ENERGY USE An RFS would provide savings in U.S. fossil energy use ranging (in energy-equivalent terms) from about 75 13 thousand coeb/day at 1 bgy and 85 17 thousand coeb/day at 12 bgy with corresponding reductions in U.S. fossil fuel imports (combined imports of crude oil, petroleum products, and natural gas). (Figure 1) The indicated total energy savings at these RFS levels would lead to import reductions amounting to less than 1% of projected net U.S. oil and natural gas imports of 17 million coeb/day in 212. 6 5 Figure 1: Energy Savings from an RFS in 212 Extra Ethanol Use (K b/d) Total Energy Savings (K coeb/d) Domestic Energy Savings (K coeb/d) 4 K b/d 3 2 1 1 12 RFS Volume (bgy) The lower number in each range is the net domestic savings in fossil energy use resulting from the indicated level of ethanol use; the higher number in each range is the total savings in fossil energy use, including both domestic and foreign producers of U.S. gasoline. Both U.S. producers and foreign producers of U.S. gasoline would increase their production of gasoline base blends for ethanol blending in response to an RFS. To the extent foreign refineries do so, some the total energy savings produced by an RFS would actually be June 3, 25 2

realized in the countries of origin instead of in the U.S. On the other hand, the costs of ethanol production including energy inputs would be incurred in the U.S., regardless of where the gasoline base blend was produced. The savings in fossil fuel use and the corresponding import displacements due to additional ethanol use result from a complex set of interactions among the various energy effects of additional ethanol use. The total energy input to corn ethanol production mainly from oil and natural gas is about 7% 75% of ethanol s energy content. 4 Ethanol has energy content (and fuel economy) about 66% that of gasoline. Hence, adding a gallon of ethanol to the gasoline pool displaces about.66 gallon of gasoline. Putting ethanol into low-emission gasolines such as RFG and low-rvp gasoline requires taking out some other gasoline components, in order to maintain volatility standards. Energy use for transporting ethanol via rail, truck, or barge to gasoline blending sites would increase. Refineries would accommodate additional ethanol volumes in U.S. gasoline by reducing crude oil and other inputs, refined product outputs, and energy use. The natural gas needed for additional ethanol production would be imported from sources outside North America the marginal sources of supply for both oil and natural gas. Because our analysis accounts for these and other energy effects of increased ethanol use, the total energy savings shown in Figure 1 exceed ethanol s net energy value alone. Figure 2 illustrates the net effect on total fossil energy use of the various energy effects of ethanol use. The total energy savings of additional ethanol use indicated by the portion of the bar above the zero line in Figure 2 is the sum of (1) the net energy contribution of ethanol (its total energy content minus the fossil energy inputs to produce it) plus (2) the net of energy savings in refining from reducing crude oil and other inputs, refined product outputs, and refinery energy use and energy loss in distribution of increasing volumes of ethanol to end-use sites out of the Midwest. 5 4 The Energy Balance of Corn Ethanol: An Update; U.S. Department of Agriculture; AER-814; July 22. The previous analysis (5, 6, and 8 bgy mandate volumes) used a value of 73%, equal to the DoA estimate for the volume-weighted average of all ethanol plants wet mill and dry mill adjusted for the energy use in ethanol distribution, which we estimated independently. The current analysis (1 bgy and 12 bgy mandate volumes) used a value of 71%, equal to the DoA estimate for dry mill plants only (again adjusted for energy use in ethanol distribution), reflecting the assumption that dry milling is the process of choice for new ethanol plants. 5 In Figure 2, the part of the bar above the zero line for a given mandate volume, indicating the total energy savings of additional ethanol use, corresponds directly to the middle bar in Figure 1, for the same mandate volume. June 3, 25 3

2 1 Figure 2: Effects on Energy Use of an RFS in 212, K coeb/d Net energy savings in refining less energy loss in distibution K coeb/d -1 1 12 RFS Volume (bgy) Net ethanol energy contribution Energy used in corn production & transport -2-3 Energy used in ethanol conversion less by-product credit The net energy contribution of ethanol changes in direct proportion to ethanol volume. But, the net energy savings in refining and distribution can change in relative terms as ethanol volume increases, because the distribution of ethanol use by region and gasoline type and other technical factors can change with ethanol volume. At all mandate volumes, some of the net energy savings in the refining industry will accrue to foreign suppliers of gasoline for ethanol blending, accounting for the difference between total energy savings and domestic energy savings. COST OF ENERGY SAVINGS The energy savings shown in Figure 1 would cost about $12-$23/coeb at 1 bgy and $13- $27/coeb at 12 bgy, net after realizing the savings in the U.S. cost of oil imports. 6 (Figure 3) The higher cost number at each mandate volume applies to the net U.S. savings in fossil energy use resulting from the indicated level of ethanol use; the lower number to the total savings in 6 A simple numerical example involving two refining scenarios may clarify the meaning of this statement. In the Baseline scenario, assume that the refining sector uses 1 barrels/day of crude oil, meets gasoline demand (with some ethanol use), and incurs total costs of $1,/day, including the purchase cost of the 1 barrels of crude. In the Ethanol Mandate scenario, assume that the refining sector uses 99 barrels/day of crude, meets gasoline demand (with additional ethanol use), and incurs total costs of $1,2/day, including the purchase cost of the 99 barrels of crude and the full production cost of the additional ethanol. The savings in crude oil resulting from the ethanol mandate comes at a cost $2 per barrel, net after realizing the saving in the purchase cost of crude oil. June 3, 25 4

fossil energy use, including those accruing to both domestic and foreign producers of U.S. gasoline. 3 Figure 3: Average Cost of RFS Energy Savings in 212 ($/coeb) 25 $/coeb 2 15 Upper Bound Cost (domestic energy savings) Lower Bound Cost (total energy savings) 1 9 1 11 12 13 Ethanol Use (bgy) These costs are the total national cost of the additional ethanol use at a given mandate volume (discussed below) divided by the estimated savings in fossil energy use, expressed in coeb. NATIONAL COSTS INCURRED IN GASOLINE PRODUCTION The additional ethanol use mandated by an RFS would increase the national costs of gasoline production by about $6 billion/year at 1 bgy and $8.5 billion/year at 12 bgy. (Figure 4) The national cost of an RFS is the net loss in U.S. economic resources resulting from the additional ethanol use mandated by the RFS: the amount by which the full cost of meeting U.S. gasoline demand with an RFS exceeded the full cost without an RFS. These costs would fall on U.S. consumers (through higher costs of gasoline production) and taxpayers (through increased subsidies for ethanol production). Ethanol use raises the cost of producing gasoline because ethanol s value as a gasoline component is less than the full cost of producing and delivering it. Furthermore, ethanol s refining value decreases and its production cost increases as the volume of ethanol use increases. Hence, the larger the RFS volume, the larger the national cost in terms of both total dollars per year and /gal of ethanol. June 3, 25 5

1 Figure 4: National Costs of an RFS in 212 ($ Billion/Year) 8 $ billion/year 6 4 2 1 12 RFS Volume (bgy) REGIONAL PATTERN OF ETHANOL USE The additional ethanol use mandated by an RFS would be concentrated in the Midwest, to minimize costs, but would extend into the East Coast and Gulf Coast as well. At both 1 bgy and 12 bgy, ethanol use in PADD 2 would be at its maximum. Ethanol use in all other regions would increase with increasing RFS mandate volume. (Figure 5) K b/d 35 3 25 2 15 Figure 5: Regional Ethanol Use with an RFS in 212 (K barrels/d) Baseliine 1 bgy 12 bgy 1 5 PADD 1 PADD 2 PADD 3 PADDs 4&5 Calif. Region PADD 1 (New England, Mid-Atlantic, Southeast) Local ethanol use would increase by 12 K bbl/day at 1 bgy and 18 K bbl/day at 12 bgy, relative to the baseline. The additional June 3, 25 6

ethanol would be blended into conventional gasoline and federal RFG, using base blends produced in PADD 1 refineries as well as in PADD 3 and foreign refineries. PADD 2 (Midwest) Local ethanol use would increase by 18 K bbl/day at both 1 bgy and 12 bgy. At these mandate volumes, all gasoline sold in PADD 2 would be ethanol-blended. PADD 3 (Gulf Coast) Local ethanol use would increase by 9 K bbl/day at 1 bgy and 16 K bbl/day at 12 bgy. The additional ethanol would be blended into conventional gasolines. PADD 3 refineries also would produce progressively increasing volumes of base blends for ethanol blending in PADDs 1 and 2. PADDs 4& 5, ex California (Mountain States and Northwest) and California Local ethanol use would increase by about 2 K bbl/day at 1 bgy and 3 K bbl/day at 12 bgy. INTER-REGIONAL CREDIT TRADING Every gasoline producer would have to comply with an RFS, either through physical ethanol blending or the use of ethanol credits. The credit-trading program associated with an RFS would allow producers who use more than their pro-rata share of ethanol to earn excess ethanol credits that could be sold; producers who use less than their pro-rata share would buy ethanol credits to make up the shortfall. A credit trading system reduces the national cost of an RFS, because it concentrates ethanol use where it is least costly. At mandate volumes of 1 and 12 bgy, domestic gasoline suppliers in PADD 2 and PADD 1 (at 1 bgy) and foreign suppliers would use more than their pro-rata share of ethanol and therefore would have excess ethanol credits that would be sold to buyers in the rest of the country. The sale and purchase of ethanol credits would lead to inter-regional monetary flows, and those interregional monetary flows would increase with increasing RFS mandate volume. 7 (Figure 6) Gasoline suppliers in PADD 2 could realize net revenues from trading in the range of about $64 million per year at 1 bgy and $47 million/year at 12 bgy. Foreign suppliers could realize net revenues from trading in the range of $7 million per year at 1 bgy and $26 million/year at 12 bgy. Suppliers in PADD 1 could realize net revenues from trading in the range of $7 million per year at 1 bgy, but would have a small revenue outflow from trading at 12 bgy. Suppliers in PADD 3, PADDs 4 & 5 (ex California), and California would be net credit buyers at 1 bgy and 12 bgy, and so would experience revenue outflows from trading. Suppliers in PADD 3 could experience revenue outflows of about $38 million per year at 1 bgy and $6 million/year at 12 bgy. Suppliers in California could experience revenue outflows of about $22 million per year at 1 bgy and $4 million/year at 12 bgy. Suppliers in PADDs 4 & 5 7 To estimate the revenue flows shown in Figure 6, we assumed that (1) surplus credits would be earned in the regions producing gasoline for ethanol blending and (2) the value of ethanol credit would reflect the difference between ethanol s purchase cost and its refining value as a gasoline component. June 3, 25 7

(ex California) could experience revenue outflows of about $18 million per year at 1 bgy and $25 million/year at 12 bgy. 8 Figure 6: Revenue Flows from Ethanol Credit Trading under an RFS in 212 ($ million/yr) 6 $ million/yr 4 2-2 1 12 RFS Volume (bgy) PADD 1 PADD 2 PADD 3 PADDs 4&5 ex CA California Foreign -4-6 The pattern of estimated revenue flows at each mandate volume reflects the estimated regional distribution of ethanol use (and credit generation) at the given mandate volume. Refining economics cause these patterns to be different for different mandate volumes, accounting for the differences in regional net revenue flows at different mandate volumes. BASIS FOR THE FINDINGS REPORTED HERE The findings reported here come from a detailed technical and economic analysis, originally conducted and recently updated by MathPro Inc., of the effects of an RFS on the refining economics of U.S. gasoline supply. The analysis Reflects baseline ethanol use of 3.8 bgy, corresponding to DoE s projection of ethanol use in 212, without an RFS. Used (1) Department of Agriculture (DoA) estimates of the net energy inputs to ethanol production (net of by-product credits); (2) Department of Energy forecasts of crude oil and natural gas prices, U.S. gasoline demand, and domestic gasoline production; and (3) Global Insight forecasts of corn prices and by-product values at different levels of ethanol use. Assumed continuation of (1) the federal excise tax credit for ethanol blending (currently at 51 /gal) after its scheduled expiration in 21, (2) the 1 psi RVP waiver for ethanol-blended conventional gasoline and (in the Midwest) low-rvp gasoline, (3) existing state tax subsidy June 3, 25 8

programs for ethanol blending (e.g., Illinois, Iowa), (4) existing state ethanol mandates (e.g., Minnesota, Arizona (winter)), and (5) existing state credits for ethanol production. All prices are in 23 US$. All ethanol volumes are annual averages. June 3, 25 9