Chartists, Fundamentalists, and Trading in the Foreign Exchange Market



Similar documents
This chapter seeks to explain the factors that underlie currency movements. These factors include market fundamentals and market expectations.

To appear as an entry in the Concise Encyclopedia of Economics, Liberty Fund, Inc., edited by David Henderson.

Is the Forward Exchange Rate a Useful Indicator of the Future Exchange Rate?

Theories of Exchange rate determination

Exchange Rate Changes and Net Positions of Speculators in the Futures Market

The Need for Futures Markets in Currencies Milton Friedman

INFLATION, INTEREST RATE, AND EXCHANGE RATE: WHAT IS THE RELATIONSHIP?

2 Stock Price. Figure S1.1 Profit from long position in Problem 1.13


Why has FX trading surged? Explaining the 2004 triennial survey 1

Exchange Rates and Foreign Direct Investment

CHAPTER 12 CHAPTER 12 FOREIGN EXCHANGE

Online appendix to paper Downside Market Risk of Carry Trades

Chapter 9. Forecasting Exchange Rates. Lecture Outline. Why Firms Forecast Exchange Rates

Global Currency Hedging

The relationship between exchange rates, interest rates. In this lecture we will learn how exchange rates accommodate equilibrium in

Implied Volatility Skews in the Foreign Exchange Market. Empirical Evidence from JPY and GBP:

Ch. 38 Practice MC 1. In international financial transactions, what are the only two things that individuals and firms can exchange? A.

Assignment 10 (Chapter 11)

The Foreign Exchange Market. Role of Foreign Exchange Markets

Relationships among Inflation, Interest Rates, and Exchange Rates. J. Gaspar: Adapted from Jeff Madura, International Financial Management

What Determines Exchange Rates? In the Short Run In the Long Run

Vanguard research July 2014

Sentiment in Foreign Exchange Market Yanyan Yang Claremont Graduate University

How Well Do Foreign Exchange Markets Function: Might a Tobin Tax Help?

Changes in the Relationship between Currencies and Commodities

Expert Forecasts of Bond Yields and Exchange Rates

Chapter 11. International Economics II: International Finance

General Forex Glossary

CHAPTER 7 FUTURES AND OPTIONS ON FOREIGN EXCHANGE SUGGESTED ANSWERS AND SOLUTIONS TO END-OF-CHAPTER QUESTIONS AND PROBLEMS

University of Lethbridge Department of Economics ECON 1012 Introduction to Macroeconomics Instructor: Michael G. Lanyi

Factors that influence the krone exchange rate

Recent Trends in Japanese Foreign-Exchange Margin Trading

Thank You for Attention

Chapter 17. Preview. Introduction. Fixed Exchange Rates and Foreign Exchange Intervention

Part A: Use the income identities to find what U.S. private business investment, I, was in Show your work.

THE US DOLLAR, THE EURO, THE JAPANESE YEN AND THE CHINESE YUAN IN THE FOREIGN EXCHANGE MARKET A COMPARATIVE ANALYSIS

Currency Options and Swaps: Hedging Currency Risk

COMPARISON OF CURRENCY CO-MOVEMENT BEFORE AND AFTER OCTOBER 2008

International Economic Relations

Forward exchange rates

Foreign Exchange Market: Chapter 7. Chapter Objectives & Lecture Notes FINA 5500

Introduction to Foreign Exchange. Andrew Wilkinson

Currency Option Markets and Exchange Rates: A Case Study of the U.S. Dollar in March 1995 Allan M. Malz

Currency Options.

International Economic Relations

Going Back to the Basics Rethinking Market Efficiency

Chapter 3.4. Forex Options

6. Foreign Currency Options

Using Currency Futures to Hedge Currency Risk

CHAPTER 8 SUGGESTED ANSWERS TO CHAPTER 8 QUESTIONS

The Market for Foreign Exchange

Chapter 5. The Foreign Exchange Market. Foreign Exchange Markets: Learning Objectives. Foreign Exchange Markets. Foreign Exchange Markets

Agenda. Exchange Rates, Business Cycles, and Macroeconomic Policy in the Open Economy, Part 1. Exchange Rates. Exchange Rates.

The Business Theory of Forex Trading - Part 1

Chapter 1 Currency Exchange Rates

Chapter 14 Foreign Exchange Markets and Exchange Rates

Monetary policy rules and their application in Russia. Economics Education and Research Consortium Working Paper Series ISSN

Chapter Review and Self-Test Problems

Hedging Foreign Exchange Rate Risk with CME FX Futures Canadian Dollar vs. U.S. Dollar

Learning Objectives. Chapter 17. Trading Currencies in Foreign Exchange Markets. Trading Currencies in Foreign Exchange Markets (cont.

CHAPTER 15 INTERNATIONAL PORTFOLIO INVESTMENT SUGGESTED ANSWERS AND SOLUTIONS TO END-OF-CHAPTER QUESTIONS AND PROBLEMS

Solutions: Sample Exam 2: FINA 5500

This act of setting a price today for a transaction in the future, hedging. hedge currency exposure, short long long hedge short hedge Hedgers

Public attitudes to inflation and interest rates

Sector Rotation Strategies

Interpreting Market Responses to Economic Data

FLEXIBLE EXCHANGE RATES

A New Effective Exchange Rate Index for the Canadian Dollar

CHAPTER 19 CURRENCIES AND FOREIGN EXCHANGE

Interest rate volatility in historical perspective

2. Discuss the implications of the interest rate parity for the exchange rate determination.

Purer return and reduced volatility: Hedging currency risk in international-equity portfolios

Macroeconomics, 10e, Global Edition (Parkin) Chapter 26 The Exchange Rate and the Balance of Payments

What you will learn: UNIT 3. Traditional Flow Model. Determinants of the Exchange Rate

Condensed Interim Consolidated Financial Statements of. Canada Pension Plan Investment Board

FORECASTING DEPOSIT GROWTH: Forecasting BIF and SAIF Assessable and Insured Deposits

Statement by Dean Baker, Co-Director of the Center for Economic and Policy Research (

Currency Derivatives Guide

Derivative Users Traders of derivatives can be categorized as hedgers, speculators, or arbitrageurs.

11.2 Monetary Policy and the Term Structure of Interest Rates

AN INTRODUCTION TO THE FOREIGN EXCHANGE MARKET

Midterm Exam I: Answer Sheet

The European Central Bank s Minimum Bid Rate and Its Effect on Major Currency Pairs

Research Division Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Working Paper Series

CHAPTER 9 SUGGESTED ANSWERS TO CHAPTER 9 QUESTIONS

Australian Dollars Exchange Rate and Gold Prices: An Interval Method Analysis

Introduction to Exchange Rates and the Foreign Exchange Market

How To Calculate The Price Of A Dollar

Kiwi drivers the New Zealand dollar experience AN 2012/ 02

Introduction, Forwards and Futures

The Greek Implied Volatility Index: Construction and. Properties *

How To Get A Long Euro Forward Position On Eurodollar From A Short Euro Position On A Short Currency

Seminar. Global Foreign Exchange Markets Chapter 9. Copyright 2013 Pearson Education. 20 Kasım 13 Çarşamba

Spike Trading: Spot FX Vs Futures

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

The Foreign Exchange Market Not As Liquid As You May Think

2.5 Monetary policy: Interest rates

KENNETH KASA. Macroeconomics and International Finance

Transcription:

revised January 4, 1990 (<3,000 wds.) October 5, 1992 revised for On Exchange Rates: paragraphs on Granger-causality replaced with more extensive explanation. Chartists, Fundamentalists, and Trading in the Foreign Exchange Market Jeffrey A. Frankel Department of Economics University of California Berkeley, CA 94720 Kenneth A. Froot Graduate School of Business Harvard University, Soldiers Field Boston, MA 02163

1 Chartists, Fundamentalists, and Trading in the Foreign Exchange Market By Jeffrey A. Frankel and Kenneth A. Froot* The overshooting theory of exchange rates seems ideally designed to explain some important aspects of the movement of the dollar in recent years. Over the period 1981-1984, for example, when real interest rates in the United States rose above those among trading partners (presumably due to shifts in the monetary/fiscal policy mix), the dollar appreciated strongly. It was the higher rates of return that made U.S. assets more attractive to international investors and caused the dollar to appreciate. The overshooting theory would say that, as of 1984 for example, the value of the dollar was so far above its long-run equilibrium that expectations of future depreciation were sufficient to offset the higher nominal interest rate in the minds of international investors. (Figure 1 shows the correlation of the real interest differential with the real value of the dollar, since exchange rates began to float in 1973.) * Department of Economics, University of California, Berkeley, CA 94720, and Graduate School of Business, Harvard

2 University, Boston, MA 02163. The authors would like to thank MMS International for data and Lu Cordova and Joseph Mullally for valuable research assistance. I. Bubble Episodes At times, however, the path of the dollar has departed from what would be expected on the basis of macroeconomic fundamentals. The most dramatic episode is the period from June 1984 to February 1985. The dollar appreciated another 20 per cent over this interval, even though the real interest differential had already begun to fall. The other observable factors that are suggested in standard macroeconomic models -- money growth rates, real growth rates, the trade deficit -- at this time were also moving in the wrong direction to explain the dollar rise. It is now widely accepted that standard observable macroeconomic variables are not capable of explaining, much less predicting ex ante, the majority of short-term changes in the exchange rate. But economists divide into two camps on what this means. One view is that the unexplained short-term changes must be rational revisions in the market's perception of the equilibrium exchange rate due to shifts in "tastes and technologies," even if the shifts are not observable to macroeconomists in the form of standard measurable fundamentals. A major difficulty with this interpretation is that it is difficult to believe that there could have been an

3 increase in the world demand for U.S. goods (or in U.S. productivity) sufficient to increase the equilibrium real exchange rate by more than 20 per cent over a 9-month period, and that such a shift would then be reversed over the subsequent 9 months.

4 Figure 1 Notes: The CPI-adjusted dollar is a weighted-average index of the exchange value of the dollar against the currenices of the foreign G-10 countries plus Switzerland, where nominal exchange rates are multiplied by relative levels of CPI's. Weights are proportional to each foreign country's share in world exports plus imports from 1978 through 1983. The longterm real interest differential is the U.S. rate minus the weighted average of foreign-country weights. Source: Peter Hooper and Catherine Mann, Federal Reserve

Board. 5

6 This brings us to the second view, which is that the appreciation may have been an example of a speculative bubble: that it was not determined by fundamentals, but rather was the outcome of self-confirming market expectations. The dollar in 1985 "overshot the overshooting equilibrium." Some have suggested that the appreciation of 1988-89, on a smaller scale, may also have been of this nature. There exist elegant theories of "rational speculative bubbles," in which all participants know the correct model. Some observers have suggested that 1984-85 may best be described as a bubble that was not characterized by rational expectations. 1 We have suggested that such episodes may best be described by models of bubbles in which market participants do not agree on the model for forecasting the exchange rate. 2 While the conventional approach in the literature, theoretical as well as empirical, is to assume that there is such a thing as "the" market expectation of the future exchange rate, there is evidence that investors have heterogeneous expectations. For one thing, surveys of the forecasts of participants in the foreign exchange market show wide dispersion at any point in time. One conducted by the Financial Report (affiliated with the Economist) reports a high-low range of six-month forecasts that averages 15.2 per cent. Data in a survey conducted by MMS International show a dispersion of opinion (as measured by the standard deviation

7 across respondents) at the one-month horizon that averaged 2.2 per cent for the yen/dollar rate. The dispersion was slightly higher for the mark, pound and Swiss franc rates. II. Trading in the Foreign Exchange Market The tremendous volume of foreign exchange trading is another piece of evidence that reinforces the idea of heterogeneous expectations, since it takes differences among market participants to explain why they trade. The Federal Reserve Bank of New York has released its three-yearly count of transactions in the U.S. foreign exchange market. It showed that in April 1989, foreign exchange trading (adjusted for double-counting) totaled $128.9 billion a day, an increase of 120 per cent from March 1986. Simultaneous counts in London and Tokyo reported $187 billion and $115 billion a day, respectively. Thus the worldwide total is over $430 billion of foreign exchange trading a day. Interestingly, the banks in the New York Federal Reserve Bank census reported that only 4.9 per cent of their trading was with a nonfinancial firm, and the nonbanks only 4.4 per cent; in other words, 95 per cent of the trading takes place among the banks and other financial firms, rather than with customers such as importers and exporters. Clearly, trading among themselves is a major economic activity for banks. What is the importance of trading volume (beyond motivating the importance of heterogeneous expectations)?

8 There are three possible hypotheses, with regard to implications for movements in the market price. (1) The higher the liquidity or "depth" of the markets, the more efficiently is news regarding economic fundamentals processed and the smaller is "unnecessary volatility" in the exchange rate. (2) The foreign exchange market is already perfectly efficient, so that trading volume is irrelevant to price movements and therefore uninteresting. (3) Much trading is based on "noise" rather than "news," and leads to excessive volatility. Choosing convincingly among these three hypotheses may be too large a task to accomplish here. But there is evidence that trading volume, exchange rate volatility, and the dispersion of expectations among forecasters are all positively related. We have developed a weekly data set for four currencies (British pound, German mark, Japanese yen, and Swiss franc), covering the period October 1984 to February 1988. Trading volume is measured by the weekly number of futures contracts (nearest-term) traded on the IMM of the Chicago Mercantile Exchange, volatility is measured by the squared percentage 15-minute-changes in the futures price, averaged over the week, and dispersion is measured by the percentage standard deviation of forecasts across respondents in the survey conducted weekly by MMS International. Granger-causality tests on pre-whitened data, reported in

9 Table 1, show that the degree of dispersion has strong effects on the market. Dispersion Granger-causes volume at the 90 per cent level in three currencies out of four, whether dispersion is measured in one-week or one-month forecasts. Dispersion also Granger-causes volatility, in three out of four currencies at the one-week horizon, and four out of four at the one-month horizon. We also find that the contemporaneous correlation between volume and volatility is high:.515 for the pound,.316 for the mark,.412

10 for the Swiss franc, and.417 for the yen. One interpretation of these results is that the existence of conflicting forecasts leads to noise-trading -- the causation runs from dispersion to the volume of trading, and then from trading to volatility -- though there probably exist other interpretations as well. The Granger test does not show statistically-significant causation running directly from volume to volatility. But one would expect any such causality to be purely contemporaneous, and it is important to keep in mind that the Granger test cannot detect this type of causality. It should be noted that the tests in Table 1 also show that volatility Granger-causes dispersion: Volatility Grangercauses one-week dispersion for all four currencies, and onemonth dispersion for three out of four. We think that this apparent effect may be partly spurious: the MMS survey catches different respondents at different times of the day, so their forecasts of the expected future level of the exchange rate will differ more if the level of the spot rate on that day moves around more. On the other hand, it is easy to see how higher lagged volatility could cause higher dispersion of expectations because forecasters use different models to interpret the data. Other results in Table 1 are that volume Granger-causes both one-week and one-month dispersion in only one of four currencies. Lastly, volume and volatility do not appear to be Granger-related in either direction. Granger-causality tests on pre-whitened data show that the degree of dispersion has strong effects on the market. Dispersion Granger-causes volume at the 90 per cent level in three currencies out of four. Dispersion also Granger-causes volatility. We also find that the contemporaneous correlation

11 between volume and volatility is high.

12 III. The Rising Importance of Chartists We now turn to the question of how the existence of different forecasting techniques might lead to "excess volatility." It has long been remarked that if there exist traders who tend to forecast by extrapolating recent trends, i.e., who have "bandwagon expectations," then their actions can exacerbate swings in the exchange rate. Many so-called "chartist" forecasters, or technical analysts, are thought to use rules that are extrapolative, such as, "Buy when the oneweek moving average crosses above the twelve-week moving average." How do speculators form expectations in practice? Frankel and Froot (1988) offered evidence from the survey data that, at short horizons, respondents tend to forecast by extrapolating recent trends, while at long horizons they tend to forecast a return to a long-run equilibrium such as PPP. Table 2 reports an update of these estimates. The coefficients reported are to be interpreted as answers to the question, "for every 1 per cent that the dollar appreciates in a given week, what percentage change does the median respondent forecast for the dollar thereafter?" The answer at the 1-week horizon is another.13 per cent in the same direction. At the 4-week horizon, the extrapolation is smaller. Respondents expect that, by the time 3 months have passed, the dollar will be lower than at the day when they are

13 formulating their forecasts, and lower still at 6 months. One year out, they expect the dollar to be.33 percent lower, for every one percent that the dollar has appreciated this week. This leads to the question: which kind of forecasters dominate the market, those who think short-term, and appear to have bandwagon expectations, or those who think long-term and have regressive expectations? Since Milton Friedman (1953), the standard argument against the importance of destabilizing speculators is that they will on average lose money, and be driven out of the market in the long run. A number of special counter-examples to the Friedman argument have been constructed over the years, most involving heterogeneous actors (e.g., "suckers" who lose money and "sharpies" who win). The simplest counter-example would be based on the theory of rational speculative bubbles, where each market participant loses money if he doesn't go along with the herd. The problem with this theory, which identifies speculative bubbles with the unstable paths in a rational-expectations saddle-path problem, is that it has nothing to say about what causes a bubble to start. What, for example, generated a speculative bubble in the period leading up to February 1985, if that is what the dollar surge evident in Figure 1 was? The model of speculative bubbles developed in Frankel and Froot (1988) says that over the period 1981-85, the market shifted weight away from the fundamentalists, and toward the

14 technical analysts or "chartists." This shift was a natural Bayesian response to the inferior forecasting record of the former group, as their forecasts of dollar depreciation continued to be proven wrong month after month. The change in the weighted-average forecast of future dollar depreciation in turn changed the demand for dollars, and therefore its price in the foreign exchange market. Is there any sort of evidence for such a theory? Euromoney magazine runs a yearly August review of between 10 and 27 foreign exchange forecasting services. Summary statistics are reported in Table 3. The trend is very clear. In 1978, 18 forecasting firms described themselves as relying exclusively on economic fundamentals, and only 2 on technical analysis. By 1985, the positions had been reversed: only 1 firm reported relying exclusively on fundamentals, and 12 on technical analysis. 3 In short, it may indeed be the case that shifts over time in the weight that is given to different forecasting techniques are a source of changes in the demand for dollars, and that large exchange rate movements may take place with little basis in macroeconomic fundamentals.

15 References Allen, Helen, and Mark Taylor, 1989, "Chartists, Noise and Fundamentals: A Study of the London Foreign Exchange Market," CEPR Discussion Paper No. 341, September. Engel, Charles, and James Hamilton, 1989, "Long Swings in the Exchange Rate: Are They in the Data and Do Markets Know It?," NBER Working Paper No. 3165. Frankel, Jeffrey, and Kenneth Froot, 1988, "Chartists, Fundamentalists, and the Demand for Dollars," Greek Economic Review 10, no. 1, June. Forthcoming in Policy Issues for Interdependent Economies, edited by A.Courakis and M.Taylor, London. Frankel, Jeffrey and Kenneth Froot, 1990, "Exchange Rate Forecasting Techniques, Survey Data, and Implications for the Foreign Exchange Market," Harvard University and International Monetary Fund, Jan. Friedman, Milton, 1953, "The Case for Flexible Exchange Rates," in his Essays in Positive Economics, Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Froot, Kenneth, and Jeffrey Frankel, 1989, "Forward Discount Bias: Is It an Exchange Risk Premium?" Quarterly Journal of Economics, 104, no.416, issue 1, Feb., pp.139-161.

16 Krugman, Paul, 1985, "Is the Strong Dollar Sustainable?" In The U.S. Dollar -- Recent Developments, Outlook and Policy Options, Federal Reserve Bank of St.Louis, pp.103-133.

17 Table 2: Do Forecasters Extrapolate? OLS Regressions of Expected Future Rate of Depreciation Against Most Recent Actual Depreciation Survey data source Estimate of t-ratio and sample Term of extrapolative (with GMM period forecast parameter s.e.) MMS International 1 week.13 4.32 a Oct.1984- Jan. 1988 4 week.08 1.60 Economist 3 month -.08-2.98 a June 1981- Aug.1988 6 month -.17-4.98 a 12 month -.33-5.59 a a Significant at 99 percent confidence level.

18 Table 3: Techniques Used by Forecasting Services year total chartist fund. both 1978 23 3 19 0 1981 13 1 11 0 1983 11 8 1 1 1984 13 9 0 2 1985 24 15 5 3 1988 31 18 7 6 Source: Euromoney, August issues. Notes: total = number of services surveyed, chartist = number who reported using technical analysis, fund. = number who reported using fundamentals models, and both = number reporting a combination of the two. When a forecasting firm offers more than one service, each is counted separately.

19 Table 2: Do Forecasters Extrapolate? OLS Regressions of Expected Future Rate of Depreciation Against Most Recent Actual Depreciation Survey Data Source MMS International Economist Sample period Oct.1984-Jan.1988 June 1981-Aug.1988 Term of forecast 1-wk. 4-wk. 3-mo. 6-mo. 12-mo. Estimate of extrapolative parameter.13.08 -.08 -.17 -.33 t-ratio (with GMM s.e.) 4.32 a 1.60-2.98 a -4.98 a - 5.59 a a Significant at 99 per cent confidence level. Table 3: Techniques Used by Forecasting Services year # of services # using tech- # using fun- # using surveyed nical models damentals both models 1978 23 3 19 0 1981 13 1 11 0 1983 11 8 1 1 1984 13 9 0 2 1985 24 15 5 3 1988 31 18 7 6 Source: Euromoney, August issues. When a forecasting firm offers more than one service, each is

20 counted separately. Some services did not indicate the nature of their technique.

21 [Endnotes] Paul Krugman (1985) was one of the first to suggest that the market did not appe realize the extent to which the appreciation of the dollar was not sustainabl rles Engel and James Hamilton (1990) find that long-term swings are a gener racteristic of exchange rates, and that they are not adequately reflected in t ward market. Such findings of predictable excess returns are standardly interpret risk premiums. But evidence from survey data on expectations of market participan gests that the prediction errors of the forward market are not due to risk premiu oot and Frankel, 1989). Frankel and Froot (1990a). A number of firms combine the two approaches, or else offer a separate service h kind; in this case, usually technical analysis is used for short-term forecasti fundamentals for long-term forecasting. This pattern matches up well with t ression results from surveys of market participants regarding exchange ra ectations, reported above. The pattern is also confirmed in Taylor and All 92), who report that at short horizons approximately 90 percent of respondents use e chartist input in forming their expectations, and 60 percent judge charts to be ortant as fundamentals, while at the horizon of one-year and longer, nearly cent rely purely on fundamentals, and 85 percent judge fundamentals to be mo ortant than charts.