A Game Theory Approach to Consumer Incentives for Solar Energy



Similar documents
Laser Safety Audit and Inventory System Database

Dynamic Vulnerability Assessment

IDC Reengineering Phase 2 & 3 US Industry Standard Cost Estimate Summary

Wind Forecasting stlljectives for Utility Schedule and Energy Traders

Early Fuel Cell Market Deployments: ARRA and Combined (IAA, DLA, ARRA)

A New Empirical Relationship between Thrust Coefficient and Induction Factor for the Turbulent Windmill State

Penetration Testing of Industrial Control Systems

Small PV Systems Performance Evaluation at NREL's Outdoor Test Facility Using the PVUSA Power Rating Method

Optical Blade Position Tracking System Test

The Value of RECs in Renewable Project Financing

Measurement of BET Surface Area on Silica Nanosprings

Regional Field Verification Operational Results from Four Small Wind Turbines in the Pacific Northwest

Second Line of Defense Virtual Private Network Guidance for Deployed and New CAS Systems

Elastomer Compatibility Testing of Renewable Diesel Fuels

Situated Usability Testing for Security Systems

Energy Systems Integration

HyDIVE (Hydrogen Dynamic Infrastructure and Vehicle Evolution) model analysis. Cory Welch. Hydrogen Analysis Workshop, August 9-10 Washington, D.C.

Government Program Briefing: Smart Metering

Improving a Gripper End Effector

Nuclear Engineering Enrollments and Degrees Survey, 2013 Data

Rate Analysis of Two Photovoltaic Systems in San Diego

Nuclear Engineering Enrollments and Degrees Survey, 2014 Data

Derived Intervention Levels for Tritium Based on Food and Drug Administration Methodology Using ICRP 56 Dose Coefficients (U)

S.L. Chang, S.A. Lottes, C.Q. Zhou,** B. Golchert, and M. Petrick

2-DFINITE ELEMENT CABLE & BOX IEMP ANALYSIS

SERI{fP UC Category 234 DE Solar Detoxificati Technology: Using Energy froni;!'the Sun to Destroy Hazardou Waste

The Cost of Superconducting Magnets as a Function of Stored Energy and Design Magnetic Induction times the Field Volume

Economic Impact of Extending the Section 1603 Treasury Program

Automated Transportation Management System

Sensitive Unclassified Data Encryption and Networking Applications

Microgrids. EEI TDM Meeting Charleston, South Carolina October 7, Neal Bartek Smart Grid Projects Manager

Computer Simulations of Edge Effects in a Small-Area Mesa N-P Junction Diode

Process for Selecting Engineering Tools Applied to Selecting a SysML Tool

Isolation of Battery Chargers Integrated Into Printed Circuit Boards

How Does Your Data Center Measure Up? Energy Efficiency Metrics and Benchmarks for Data Center Infrastructure Systems

WinMagic Encryption Software Installation and Configuration

LIMITATIONS ON HIGH DATA RATE OPTICAL FIBER TRAN-SMISSION SYSTEMS DUE TO TRANSMISSION IMPAIRMENT

Building Analytics. Managed Services. Better Building Alliance Department of Energy April 17, 2015

Shock Response of Diamond Crystals

Internet-Based Calibration of a Multifunction Calibrator

WET BULB GLOBE TEMPERATURE MEASUREMENT AT THE Y-12 NATIONAL SECURITY COMPLEX

Technical Support for ENERGY STAR Windows Version 6.0 Specification Revision. Gregory K. Homan, Christian Kohler, Emily Zachery* and Dariush Arasteh

PARALLEL IMPLEMENTATION OF THE TOPAZ OPACITY CODE: ISSUES IN LOAD-BALANCING

Food Service Technology Center

Integrated Tools for Multifamily Green Asset Management. Energy Upgrade CA Web Portal Funding Finder Compass Portfolio Tracker Webinar May 22, 2012

NEAMS Software Licensing, Release, and Distribution: Implications for FY2013 Work Package Planning

CASE STUDIES OF STATE SUPPORT

SUNPOWER CORPORATION Document # Rev *B Title: Page 1 of 8 Initial release: 17-Aug-09

NREL Job Task Analysis: Crew Leader

Method to Calculate Uncertainties in Measuring Shortwave Solar Irradiance Using Thermopile and Semiconductor Solar Radiometers

Florida Solar Financing Action Plan: A Menu of Options

How To Find Out If The Winds From The Oak Ridge Site Are Calm

COMPARISON OF INDIRECT COST MULTIPLIERS FOR VEHICLE MANUFACTURING

Configuring Outlook 2010 for Windows

W. C. Reinig. Savannah River Laboratory E. I. du Pent de Nemours and Company Aiken, South Carolina 298o1

This document was prepared in conjunction with work accomplished under Contract No. DE-AC09-96SR18500 with the U. S. Department of Energy.

Configuring Apple Mail for Mac OS X (Mountain Lion)

A. F. Fossum and D. E. Munson * i A i l ' **-^ Sandia National Laboratories 1, Albuquerque, NM ~ ^ ^

Time Domain Reflectometry for Evaluating Detonator Cable Assemblies in the NEP

OG&E Demand Response

LLNL-TR SAVANT Status Report. Arden Dougan. November 6, 2009

Configuring Outlook 2011 for Mac with Google Mail

DOE Award Number: TITLE PAGE. Phase I Topical Report. Don L. Hanosh

Panel Session #4 Smart Grid Workforce Training and Education: Identifying the Industry Perspective

Requesting Nodes, Processors, and Tasks in Moab

Configuring Outlook 2013 for Windows

Drupal Automated Testing: Using Behat and Gherkin

Food Service Technology Center

Cost and Performance Metrics Used to Assess Carbon Utilization and Storage Technologies

An Estimate of Energy Use in Laboratories, Cleanrooms, and Data Centers in New York

Solar America Board for Codes and Standards

Mikroekonomia B by Mikolaj Czajkowski. MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

How to Build a Small Wind Energy Business: Lessons from California

This document was prepared in conjunction with work accomplished under Contract No. DE-AC09-96SR18500 with the U. S. Department of Energy.

Analysis of Costs-Benefits Tradeoffs of Complex Security Systems. M. J. Hicks Security Systems Analysis and Development Department, 5845.

Asynchronous data change notification between database server and accelerator control systems

Configuring Apple Mail for Mac OS X (Snow Leopard)

The vertical differentiation model in the insurance market: costs structure and equilibria analysis

Configuring Outlook 2016 for Windows

Using Virtualization to Help Move a Data Center

Developing an Online Database of National and Sub-national Clean Energy Policies

Advances in Oxide-Confined Vertical Cavity Lasers. Photonics Research Department. Albuquerque, NM (505) phone (505) FAX

Testing of Kaonetics Devices at BNL

ANALYSIS OF POTENTIAL RADIATION-INDUCED GENETIC AND SOMATIC EFFECTS TO HAN FROM MILLING OF URANIUM

Amorphous Transparent Conducting Oxides (TCOs) Deposited at T 100 C

User Guide. The Business Energy Dashboard

LEADERSHIP DEVELOPMENT STUDY

Estimating customer electricity savings from

Science Goals for the ARM Recovery Act Radars

AUDIT REPORT. Follow-up on the Department of Energy's Acquisition and Maintenance of Software Licenses

Risk D&D Rapid Prototype: Scenario Documentation and Analysis Tool

RENEWABLE CITIES Case Studies

Presented July 16, :45 PM Solar Breakout Session. Exploring Community Solar. Shannon Fulton StraightUp Solar

User Guide. The Business Energy Dashboard

Nuclear War and the Climatic Consequences

Public Service Co. of New Mexico (PNM) - Smoothing and Peak Shifting. DOE Peer Review Steve Willard, P.E. September 26, 2012

Systems Engineering Management Plans

System Advisor Model, SAM : General Description

Up to $750 (or 30% of the project cost, whichever is less), for

DARK CURRENT-VOLTAGE MEASUREMENTS ON PHOTOVOLTAIC MODULES AS A DIAGNOSTIC OR MANUFACTURING TOOL

Transcription:

SANDIA REPORT SAND81-1618 Unlimited Release UC-62 Printed November 1981 A Game Theory Approach to Consumer Incentives for Solar Energy John K. Sharp Prepared by Sandia National Laboratories Albuquerque New Mexico 87185 and Livermore California 94550 for the United States Department of Energy under Contract DE-AC04-76DPOO789 When printing a copy of any digitized SAND Report you are required to update the markings to current standards. SF2900Q(S-S1 )

Issued by Sandia National Laboratories operated for the United States Department of Energy by Sandia Corporation. NOTICE: This report was prepared as an account of work sponsored by an agency of the United States Government. Neither the United States Government nor any agency thereof nor any of their employees nor any of their contractors subcontractors or their employees makes any warranty express or implied or assumes any legal liability or responsibility for the accuracy completeness or usefulness of any information apparatus product or process disclosed or represents that its use would not infringe privately owned rights. Reference herein to any specific commercial product process or service by trade name trademark manufacturer or otherwise does not necessarily constitute or imply its endorsement recommendation or favoring by the United States Government any agency thereof or any of their contractors or subcontractors. The views and opinions expressed herein do not necessarily state or reflect those of the United States Government any agency thereof or any of their contractors or subcontractors. Printed in the United States of America Available from National Technical Information Service U.S. Department of Commerce 5285 Port Royal Road Springfield VA 22161 NTIS price co4lls... Printed copy: :;; ':1 0 0 Microfiche copy: A01

SANDBl-161B Unlimited Release Printed November 19B1 Distribution Category uc - 60 A GAME THEORY APPROACH TO CONSUMER INCENTIVES FOR SOLAR ENERGY John K. Sharp Photovoltaic Systems Development Division 4723 Sandia National Laboratories Albuquerque New Mexico ABSTRACT Solar energy is currently not competitive with fossil fuels. Fossil fuel price increases may eventually allow solar to compete but incentives can change the relative price between fossil fuel and solar energy and make solar compete sooner. This paper develops examples of a new type of competitive game using solar energy incentives. Compet itive games must have players with individual controls and conflicting objectives but recent work also includes incentives offered by one of the players to the others. In the incentive game presented here the Government acts as the leader and offers incentives to consumers who act as followers. The Government incentives offered in this leaderfollower (Stackelberg) game reduce the cost of solar energy to the consumer. Both the Government and consumers define their own objectives with the Government determining an incentive (either in the form of a subsidy or tax) that satisfies its objective. The two hypothetical examples developed show how the Government can achieve a stated solar utilization rate with the proper incentives. In the first example the consumer's utility function guarantees some purchases of solar energy. In the second example~ the consumer's utility function allows for no solar purchases because utility is derived only from the amount of energy used and not from the source of the energy. The two examples discuss both subsidy ~nd tax incentives with the best control over solar use coming from fossil fuel taxes dependent upon the amount of solar energy used. Future work will expand this static analysis to develop time varying incentives along a time and quantity dependent learning curve for the solar lndustry. This work was supported by the U. S. Department of Energy 3

A GAME THEORY APPROACH TO CONSUMER INCENTIVES FOR SOLAR ENERGY Introduction Solar energy incentives can improve the relative economics between solar and fossil fuel. Presently solar energy is not economical when compared to fossil fuel but with future fossil fuel price increases and solar energy price decreases solar may become competitive in certain locations. Government incentives can help make solar energy competitive sooner by stimulating and developing the solar industry. The result~ng solar production increases will lower system costs. Determining the proper incentive mi~ for the Government to offer is a major problem because consumers' and suppliers' reactions to the incentives must be considered. The economic problems associated with initial overstimulation and/or discontinuous stimulation can be avoided with the proper incentive prog~am. The Government acting as a leader can offer incentives which encourage consumers to purchase more solar energy. By calling the Government a leader and the consumers followers a generalized problem can be developed where the leader has his own objectives and he is trying to influence purchases of the followers who have their own objectives. In the literature this type of leaderfollower game is called a Stackelberg game l Solar incentives will now be analyzed using Stackelberg game theory. system. 2 Game theory is the study of players who can a6t upon and change a Players attempt to make favorable changes in their individual cost or objective functions. Games are either cooperative or competitive with the players acting accordingly. competitive and contain two types of players: Stackelberg games 3 4 are a leader and followers. The leader in a Stackelberg game knows how the followers react to him and he uses this information to choose his most desirable action. theory has recently been used to investigate incentives in public decisionmaking 5 ; incentives have also been used with Stackelberg games to investigate duopolies. 6 Game Solar Incentives Using Stackelberg Games Incentive theory for solar energy can be developed using Stackelberg games. The ultimate goal of an incentive program is to make solar energy competitive with other energy forms. If this goal is not 4

achieved then incentives must be continued after the solar industry has matured. This time varying problem can be treated as static if intermediate targets are set for the solar industry. The Government acting as a leader has a specific short-term target it hopes to achieve with incentives while consumers acting as followers have their own objectives. The Government's short-term objective could be a production target while the consumers' opjectives are to maximize their wellbeing (commonly referred to as utility in economics) subject to the funds they have available with which to purchase energy. Using the single consumer case these conditions can be expressed analytically as: Leader (Government) Objective: achieve a stated goal J Follower (Consumer) Objective: maximize utility U Subject to: (3 ) where: ql = units of fossil energy q2 units of solar energy Pl = price per unit of fossil fuel P2 = price per unit of solar fuel I total consumer budget for energy products The model described by (1) ~ (3) does not include Government incentives. In this model the consumer maximizes his utility subject to the budget constraint to determine his purchases ql* and q2* (with q* denoting the optimal purchases). These values determine the deviation from the Government's objective. The three types of Government incentives available to change the consumers' energy mix are: 1. Solar energy subsidy 2. Fossil energy tax 3. Rationing and/or regulating energy purchases A solar energy subsidy allows the consumer to purchase more solar energy with the same amount of funds. Fossil fuel taxes decrease the amount of fossil fuel that can be purchased and encourage the use of 5

solar energy by reducing the relative price between solar and fossil energy. Rationing fossil energy forces consumers to switch to solar for additional energy and regulating or requiring more solar usage increases the demand for solar. The budget constraint (3) modified to account for subsidy and tax incentives is: (4) where: t per unit fossil fuel tax s = per unit solar Ratioring or regulating is where both sand t are zero and the Government determines the value of ql or q2. The subsidy or tax must ensure that when the consumer acts in his own best interest the Government's objective is realized. The Government can achieve this by first characterizing the consumers' reaction to various taxes and/or subsidies. This information is then used as a constraint when the Government tries to achieve its objective. Two hypothetical examples are presented which show how the Government can determine the necessary incentives to achieve a targeted production level of solar energy. Stackelberg Example 1 The two examples differ only in the utility derived by the consumer from energy. In both examples the Government's objective is to achieve a targeted solar production level. This production level lsassumed to be a point along a learning curve for the solar industry. The first example assumes a standard consumer utility function which is the fossil fuel usage times the solar energy usage. The competitive game occurs when the consumer tries to maximize his utility subject to his budget constraintwhlle th~ to achi eve the targeted level of solar energy usage. functions and budget constraint for this example are: Leader's (Government's) Goal: J Government tries The objective minimize the target solar production error 2 (q2-0.4) (5) 6

~ D -~ 0::8 ~... z ~ 0:: <~ ~cs 0 Ul ~o 01C1 00 0 E-t... Z ~~ II cs C\J ~8 d 0.0. \. \ \ \. \ \ t=-7 5qz+3. " " ~~- -~- 1.0 2.0 3.0 4.0 ql UNI TS OF FOSS I L FUEL ~~~ -... -- ---------------- 5.0 6.0 Figure 1. Impact of Incentives on The Consumer ' s Energy Use Assuming a Stanaard Utility Function --.J

Followers' (Consumers') Goal: maximize utility (6 ) Subject to the budget contraint: (7) Solar and fossil energy have the same energy units with the Government's targeted level of solar energy usage being 0.4 unit. The consumers' total budget for energy products is 5 and the unit prices of fossil fuel and solar energy are 1 and 10 respectively. Thus solar energy is assumed to cost ten times as much as fossil energy currently costs. Without incentives the consumer can purchase up to 5 units of fossil energy or 0.5 unit of solar energy. This budget constraint is shown as a straight line between the (5 0) and (0 0.5) points in Figure 1. The consumer's desired place on the budget line is point 1 where his utility is maximized. Solar energy usage is only 0.25 unit which is less than the Government's targeted usage of 0.4 unit. Incentives are needed to encourage the consumer to use more solar energy. At point 2 the Government's target solar level is achieved with either a subsidy or tax and fossil fuel use is not increased: either a subsidy of $3.75 per unit of solar energy or a tax on fossil fuel of -$3.00 q2 + $0.60. The tax on fossil energy is a function of the amount of the consumers' solar energy usage. A straight tax on fossil energy similar to the solar subsidy decreases fossil energy usage but it does not guarantee more solar usage. For the standard utility function the share of income for purchasing solar or fossil energy remains the same; so when the price of fossil fuel is raised through direct taxes the amount of fossil energy consumed is reduced with no effect on solar energy consumption. This is why at point 2 the solar subsidy increased the use of solar energy with no effect on the use of fossil energy; but if either a tax or subsidy is used to move the consumer to point 2 he is better off than he was at point 1. Thus the individual would benefit from the incentive program because the Government must increase the consumers' energy budget to achieve the targeted solar energy level. The targeted solar level is achieved at point 3 but the use of fossil fuel has increased. The necessary tax is -$1.875 q2 per unit of fossil fuel. The budget line including this incentive has end points equal to the initial budget line. The consumer is better off at point 8

3 than at point 1 because he can now purchase more solar energy and more fossil fuel. With this subsidy the consumer is not only paid to increase his use of solar energy but also to increase his use of fossil energy. Point 4 is located on the budget line but since it has less utility than point 1 it was not initially chosen. rhis point would be chosen if the tax were -$7.?0 q2 + $3.00. The net government cost at this point is zero (i.e. taxes equal subsidies) because the point is on the original buqget curve. This point can also be attained by rationing fossil fuel to one unit or by regulating solar energy usage to 0.4 unit. With the proper mix of subsidies and taxes any point in the ql - q2 plane can be made desirable to the consumer providing that ql is less than I/Pl' A major problem with using the standard utility function for solar energy analysis is that both types of energy must b~ used or the utility is zero. In most processes where solar energy is a feasible substitute for fossil fuel the total amount of energy is more important than having some of each type. This suggests that a plausible objective for the consumer may be obtaining the most energy possible within the budget constraint. Stackelberg Example 2 The secon9 example shows how a consumer reacts if he desires to maximize the amount of energy used. This is also equivalent to minimizing the per unit cost of energy. The Government's goal (Eq. (5)) and the consumer's budget coqstraint (Eq. (7)) are the same but the consumer's utility is now: (8) The utility curves are straight lines denoting equal energy usage. The value of a unit of energy is the same to the consumer no matter where it comes from. Subsidies and taxes are again investigated using this new utility function. Point 1 on Figure 2 is the desired energy mix without subsidies or taxes. Since utility is defined as the total amount of energy the optima+ mix is to buy on the cheapest; and in this case fossil fuel. Thus solar is not initially being used so subsidies and taxes must be offered before solar penetrates the market. 9

I-' o :>t 0... ~ ~8 til. z... til ~ <~ ~o 0 00 tl..o 0" 00 0 E-- - Z ::>~ II 0 or ~~ 0 \ t=o t=-9q.+3.6 0.0 1.0 q1 \.... " 2.0 3.0 4.0 UNITS OF FOSSIL FUEL 3 t=-2.13q. +.m. t=-l.99q.... '1 5.0 6.0 Figure 2. Impa'ct of Incentives on the Consumer I s Energy Use Assuming Total Enersy as the Utility Function

The desired energy mix at point 2 requires a tax of -$2.13 q2 + $0.07. The total energy usage has not increase d (i.e. point 1 and point 2 are on the same utility curve) but 0.4 unit of fossil fuel has been displaced with solar energy. Since the consumer utility has not been reduced the Government must pay for 90 percent of the solar energy used. At point 3 the higher utility means greater energy usage. The tax of -$1.99 q2 is equivalent to a government payment of 98 percent of the solar energy costs. The boundary points on the budget line are the same as the no-tax case so the fossil fuel user is not penalized if he decides against participation in the solar incentive program. Point 4 is on the original budget line so the net cost to the Government is zero but the utility (i.e. energy use) has been severely reduced. This point can also be achieved by regulating or rationing. For a solar subsidy to impact the energy mix it must be set to at least 90 percent of the solar costs because of the ten-to-one price ratio between solar and fossil energy. Unless the 90 percent subsidy is limited large-demand impulses would destabilize the solar sector of our economy. The tax scheme outlined above stimulates interest in partial displacement of fossil energy with solar and provides better government control over solar energy demand. Conclusion The initial theoretical development of leader-follower games involving solar incentives has been presented. The game theory approach forces policymakers to evaluate potential incentives against defined objectives. From this theoretical work Example 2 indicates that incentives in the form of a tax rather than straight solar subsidies may provide for more control of solar demand by the Government. The static results from this analysis can be expanded to develop proper incentives for various points on the solar industry learning curve. The evaluation of how incentives affect multiple consumers a nd/or producers is a straightforward extension of the present analysis. 11

REFERENCES 1. H. von Stackelberg The Theory of the Market Economy (1952) Oxford University Press Oxford England. 2. J. Case "Toward a Theory of Many Player Differential Games" SIAM J. on Control 7 (1969) pp 179-97. 3. M. Simaan and J. B. Cruz Jr. "On the Stackelberg Strategy in Nonzero-Sum Games" JOTA 11 (1973) pp 533-55. 4. M. Simaan and J. B. Cruz Jr. "Additional Aspects of the Stackelberg Strategy in Nonzero-Sum Games" JOTA 11 (1973) pp 613-26. 5. J. Green and J. Laffont Incentives in Public Decision Making (1980) North-Holland Pub. Co. New York NY. 6. M. A. Salmon and J. B. Cruz "An Incentive Model of Duopoly with Government Coordination" Automatica V. 17 Nov. 1981 (to appear). 12

Distribution: Solar Information Center 1536 Cole Blvd. Golden CO 80401 Attn: R. Ortiz Solar Energy Research Inst. (3) 1536 Cole Blvd. Golden CO 80401 Jet Propulsion Laboratory (3) 4800 Oak Grove Drive. Pasadena CA 91103 Attn: J Becker J. Lucas K. Terasawa Office of Technology Asqessment U. S. Congress Washington DC 20510 Attn: R. Rowberg U. S. Dept. of Energy (3) Albuquerque Operations Office P. O. Box 5400 Albuquerque NM 87185 Attn: G. N. Pappas C. B. Quinn J. Weisiger U. S. Dept. of Energy (5) Division of Energy Storage Systems Washington DC 20545 Attn: J. Gahimer U. S. Dept. of Energy (8) Division of Solar Thermal Energy Systems Washington DC 20585 Attn: W. W. Auer G. W. Braun J. E. Greyerbiehl M. U. Gutstein L. Melamed J. E. Rannels F. Wilkin::;; J. Dollard J. Easterling U. S. Dept. of Energy (2) San Francisqo Operations Office 1333 Broadway Wells Fargo Bldg. Oakland CA 94612 Attn: R. W. Hughey 4000 4700 4710 4713 4714 4715 4716 4717 4720 4721 4723 4724 4726 4750 5510 5513 5520 5523 8326 8430 843] 3141 3154-3 3151 6011 4723 A. Narath J. H. Scott G. E. Brandvold J. v. Otts R. P. Stromberg R. H. Braasch J. F. Banas J. A. Leonard D. G. Schueler W. P. Schimmel D. G. Schueler (Actg ) E. C. Boes E. L. Burgess v. L. Dugan D. B. Hayes D. W. Larson T. B. Lane R. C. Reuter c. T. Yokomizo R. C. Wayne P. J. Eicker L. J. Erickson (5 ) C. Dalin (25) for DOE/TIC ' W. L. Garner (3) (Unlimited Release for DOE/TIC) Patents J. K. Sharp 13