Forward Risk-Hedging Products PC_2012_E_13



Similar documents
Consultation on Forward Risk-Hedging Products and Harmonisation of Long-Term Capacity Allocation Rules

How To Create A Power Market In European Power Markets

ACER consultation on Forward Risk-Hedging Products and Harmonisation of Long-Term Capacity Allocation Rules EFET RESPONSE

Dual Purpose Transmission Rights

Final Draft Framework Guidelines on Capacity Allocation and Congestion Management for Electricity Ref: E10-ENM February 2011

Feedback from Nordenergi on PCG target model and roadmap propositions

EURELECTRIC presentation. EURELECTRIC contribution to a reference model for European capacity markets. DG COMP workshop 30 June 2015

Financial Transmission Rights in the Nordic Electricity Market

CAPACITY MECHANISMS IN EU POWER MARKETS

Options for coordinating different capacity mechanisms

Reliability Options in Ireland and Northern Ireland Obligations and Penalties

A report to the Commission for Energy Regulation and the Utility Regulator. February 2011 DAY-AHEAD MARKET COUPLING OPTIONS FOR THE SEM

Regional resource adequacy Cross-border trade of capacity. From implicit to explicit cross-border participation in capacity mechanisms

DECENTRALISED RELIABILITY OPTIONS Securing European electricity markets Florence Forum, 5 June 2014 Stephen Woodhouse, Director

A new electricity market for Northern Ireland and Ireland from Integrated Single Electricity Market (I-SEM)

Hedging with FTRs and CCfDs Introduction

POLICYbrief. A Gas Target Model for the European Union: Contrasting MECOS and EURAM Proposal. Highlights

Mark Pearce National Grid Interconnectors Business National Grid House Warwick Technology Park Gallows Hill Warwick CV34 6DA 23 June 2006

Regional intraday trade model for the Central West region

The Liberalized Electricity Market

PRINCIPLES OF REGULATION ON HARMONIZED RULES FOR CROSS-BORDER TRADE AND REGULATORY COOPERATION FOR MARKET INTEGRATION IN THE BLACK SEA

Specific amendments to the Capacity Allocation and Congestion Management Network Code

ACER. oj L 211, , p J L 211, , p RECOMMENDATION Of THE AGENCY FOR THE COOPERATION OF ENERGY REGULATORS No 02/2014

Harmonisation of electricity generation transmission tariffs. A EURELECTRIC contribution to ACER s scoping exercise

January Eurogas Views on the Energy Union and Enhancing Supply Security

Second Political Declaration of the Pentalateral Energy Forum of 8 June 2015

Business Area Markets

VALUING FLEXIBILITY 20 May 2014 Florence Forum Stephen Woodhouse, Director, Pöyry Management Consulting

ACER scoping document for Rules for Trading

Future Trading Arrangements 3 rd Forum. Giuseppina Squicciarini 18/11/13

Eni Gas &Power s response to ERGEG s consultation - ERGEG principles: Capacity allocation and congestion management in natural gas transmission

PROPOSAL FOR THE OVERSUBSCRIPTION AND BUY-BACK SCHEME. -EDP comments-

Harmonised Model for Supplier Switching. Report 4/2013

Power market integration. Geir-Arne Mo Team Lead Nordic Spot Trading Bergen Energi AS

POLITICAL DECLARATION OF THE PENTALATERAL ENERGY FORUM

The Nordic Electricity Exchange and The Nordic Model for a Liberalized Electricity Market

European Distribution System Operators for Smart Grids

Completion of the Internal Energy Market. Transport, Telecommunications and ENERGY Council meeting Brussels, 9 December 2014

Network Code on Forward Capacity Allocation Explanatory Document of Changes in the Resubmitted Version 2 April 2014

NATIONAL CAPACITY MECHANISMS IN THE EUROPEAN INTERNAL ENERGY MARKET: OPENING THE DOORS TO NEIGHBOURS

Evolution of Transmission Rights in the European Electricity Market

European Commission Public Consultation on GENERATION ADEQUACY, CAPACITY MECHANISMS AND THE INTERNAL MARKET IN ELECTRICITY

Finnish Energy Industries draft answer to CEER public consultation The future role of DSOs

June Position Paper Contribution to the debate on electricity market design and capacity markets

ESRI Research Note. The Irish Electricity Market: New Regulation to Preserve Competition Valeria di Cosmo and Muireann Á. Lynch

Different types of electricity markets modelled using PLEXOS Integrated Energy Model The UK Balancing Market example

SOUTH EAST EUROPE WHOLESALE MARKET OPENING Final report April 2010

International Experience in Pipeline Capacity Trading

Nordic Balance Settlement (NBS)

Operational Security Network Code

PJM Overview and Wholesale Power Markets. John Gdowik PJM Member Relations

Response by NIE Energy (PPB)

OF WESTERN BALKAN 6 ON REGIONAL ELECTRICITY MARKET DEVELOPMENT AND ESTABLISHING A FRAMEWORK FOR OTHER FUTURE COLLABORATION

EU Harmonisation of Capacity Adequacy Policies: Free trade of capacity rights is not a relevant issue.

The Materials Contained Are Property of GP Renewables & Trading, LLC and are considered proprietary. This is not for distribution.

Impediments to Electricity Trading in Central and Eastern Europe (CEE)

ESB NATIONAL GRID RESPONSE TO CER/03/266 INTERCONNECTOR TRADING PRINCIPLES IN THE MAE

Call for comments to ACER on the Network Code Emergency and Restoration. EURELECTRIC and VGB PowerTech comments

CEER s Response to the European Commission s Consultation on a new Renewable Energy Directive for the period after 2020

FI/RU electricity exchange area setup

Market Coupling in Gas?

a reference model for european capacity markets

Power Exchanges and Market Coupling tools for mitigating energy costs favoring EU competitiveness

The pivotal role of TSOs in European energy market integration

POWER TRADING FORUM 20 March Andy Kelly

market design policy paper

Poland must fully transpose the Third Energy Package Directives without further delay to liberalise the electricity and gas markets.

SCOPING TOWARDS POTENTIAL HARMONISATION OF ELECTRICITY

EAI Response to ISEM Draft Decision

How To Make A Successful Energy Community

NordREG Common Nordic end-user market

Convergence Bidding Tutorial & Panel Discussion

Rights and obligations of DSOs and suppliers in the customer interface

The EU energy market: policy & regulation

Access to gas transportation

I. GENERAL FUNCTIONING OF THE RETAIL MARKET AND CONSUMER PARTICIPATION

European Power Exchanges Challenges for market integration

Energy Trading. Jonas Abrahamsson Senior Vice President Trading. E.ON Capital Market Day Nordic Stockholm, July 3, 2006

Electricity Exchanges in South Asia The Indian Energy Exchange Model

Single Electricity Market (SEM) and interaction with EMIR. Central Bank of Ireland

The Nordic financial electricity market

Customers and Other Interested Parties Direct Dial:

Overview of points that must be included to get a useful Guidelines for. Good TPA Practice

National Capacity Mechanisms in the European IEM: Opening the Doors to Neighbours. Paolo Mastropietro, Pablo Rodilla, Carlos Batlle

European Distribution System Operators for Smart Grids. Position paper on Electric Vehicles Charging Infrastructure

Power Trading and Retail System. empowering. smarter trading. across the energy value chain. Smart energy. Powering progress

Security of electricity supply

SINGLE ELECTRICITY MARKET COMMITTEE

European Distribution System Operators for Smart Grids. Flexibility: The role of DSOs in tomorrow s electricity market

Engineering, Economics & Regulation of the Electric Power Sector. Generation & wholesale markets Wholesale market design

Main variations of business models for Flexible Industrial Demand combined with Variable Renewable Energy

2. Executive Summary. Emissions Trading Systems in Europe and Elsewhere

Investing in the Infrastructure for Energy Markets

Note No. 137 March Countries in Asia, Europe, and North and South America are introducing reforms to boost

Competition in EU Electricity Markets The Role of Antitrust Policy

Key Points. Ref.:EBF_007865E. Brussels, 09 May 2014

An Overview of the Midwest ISO Market Design. Michael Robinson 31 March 2009

EcoGrid EU NEWSLETTER No 1

CAPACITY REMUNERATION MECHANISMS AND THE INTERNAL MARKET FOR ELECTRICITY

Energy Union and 2030 Energy & Climate Governance. A EURELECTRIC position paper

Transcription:

Answer to public consultation Petteri Haveri 26.10.2012 1(5) Agency for the cooperation of energy regulators consultation2012r08@acer.europa.eu Forward Risk-Hedging Products PC_2012_E_13 The Finnish Energy Industries (EC Register ID number 68861821910-84) is a trade organisation for producers, suppliers, transmission, distributors and sales of electricity, for district heating and district cooling, and for design, implementation, operation, maintenance and construction of networks and power plants. General comments The Finnish Energy Industries (ET) welcomes the consultation on Forward Risk-Hedging Products and Harmonization of Long-Term Capacity Allocation Rules. Generally the basic need is to hedge power prices. An efficient market design is best supported with a liquid power derivatives market and with products supporting the power derivatives market. Currently, within the Nordic system, the system price in combination with CfDs serves well the Nordic market, where price areas are relatively small. Forward market that is based on financially settled products is open to all interested parties, also market participants that have no physical position in the market area. Nordic market is a good example of this. The power derivatives market is highly competitive and has as members also a number of financial actors, in addition to European energy companies. None of the Nordic day-ahead price zones are large and representative enough to replace the system price as the basis for a liquid forward market, and without the system price, forward liquidity would collapse. Introducing FTRs directly between Nordic price zones is not feasible with the number of zones in the Nordic market. Linking buyers and sellers through long chains of FTRs would not work in practice. On the CWE side market coupling has improved the efficiency of the spot markets. System price type neutral contract structure could be a good addition in CWE areas product category, especially if it proves impossible to maintain current price areas without severely affecting XB transmission. The future of needed XB hedging products depends on how power derivatives markets develop, will they remain separate as today or will they form one market as the Nordic market. FTR products ease to interconnect market areas. Within one market area, such as Nordic market, CfD contracts function better. In fact there are very few market participants in the Nordic market that have shown interest towards FTRs. Generators, retailers and power consumers need CfDs. The forward XB products have to fit to the two local markets that are to be connected. Thus, there is no generic solution that is the best one for all interconnections. There should however be the leading principle, that forward XB products support hedging against volatile electricity wholesale prices and that the XB products don t hinder the use of transmission capacity. When liquid day-ahead and derivatives markets are functioning on both sides of an interconnector, financial XB products are to be preferred for ensuring efficient use of the interconnector, where such products are considered needed. Products enabling physical Register ID number: Finnish Energy Industries 68861821910-84 Fredrikinkatu 51 53 B, FI-00100 Helsinki P.O.Box 100, FI-00101 Helsinki Telephone: +358 9 530 520 Fax: +358 9 5305 2900 www.energia.fi

2(5) reservation of transmission capacity should be abandoned once efficient day-ahead markets exist. The type and need of cross-border products depend what are the needs of market participants on the both sides of the interconnector. In the Nordic market long-term hedging is done with derivatives that have system price as the reference. CfD-products support this market. Nordic and Baltic markets are highly integrated. Answer to the questions 1) Are there other products or options which are not considered in this document that would be worth investigating? Yes. In regions where market participants find transmission capacity products guaranteed by TSOs useful, one option might be seen as a hybrid of two models. This constitutes a market with CfDs and system price derivatives incorporated with synthetic FTR obligations, equivalent to a combination of two CfDs, which are auctioned by the TSO. 2) What will be the importance of the long-term Target Model and specifically the design of the forward market and the structure of long-term hedging products once the Day-Ahead and Intraday Target Models are implemented? Do you think your interest and demand for long-term hedging products will change (either increase or decrease) with the implementation of the Day-Ahead and Intraday Target Models? More specifically, what is your interest in cross-border/zone hedging? The market coupling is likely to give more liquidity for the markets and eventually push OTCtrading increasingly to market places thus improving efficiency. After artificial transmission restrictions (e.g. Physical Transmission Rights) are removed, the need for XB-hedging is likely to decrease, since the XB capacity will be freely available for everyone in the market. The increasing amount of renewable electricity production is likely to increase the volatility on spot-markets and hence the need for electricity forwards. If liquidity for some areas derivatives market is low, one should consider whether to start offering index-price based derivatives contracts. 3) Would long-term hedging markets need to evolve (e.g. in terms of structure, products, liquidity, harmonization, etc.) due to the implementation of: 1) the dayahead market coupling, 2) day-ahead flow-based capacity calculation and 3) occasional redefinition of zones? If so, please describe how these changes would influence your hedging needs and strategy. If no evolution seems necessary, please elaborate why. Can you think of any striking change not considered here? Day ahead market coupling: see previous question. It should be the most important priority. Flow-based capacity calculation: this will not fundamentally change the need for hedging purposes. The basic need to hedge volatile power prices will remain. Redefinition of bidding zones: It is clear that splitting up existing bidding zones in smaller bidding zones would decrease liquidity in forward markets with existing product category and make hedging more difficult. If the grid development lags increasingly the transmission needs there may be a growing need for index price power derivatives and correspondent CfD-type products. These products will however enter the market market-based as proven in the Nordic market. A better approach to the fundamental challenge would be building more transmission capacity. Redefinition of zones should rather aim at merging price areas across national borders to create bigger and more liquid price zones. 4) What is for you the most suitable Long-Term Target Model (combination of energy forwards and transmission products) that would enable efficient and effective long term hedging? What would be the prerequisites (with respect to the e.g. regulatory, financial, technical, operational framework) to enable this market design in Europe? Which criteria would you use to assess the best market design to hedge long-term positions in the market (e.g. operability, implementation costs, liquidity, efficiency )?

3(5) The leading principle must be, that forward XB products support hedging against volatile electricity wholesale prices and that the possible XB products don t hinder the use of transmission capacity. There is no generic solution that is the best one for all markets and interconnections. When an efficient day-ahead market (DAM) is lacking, the preferred solution would be a PTR UIoLI. When an efficient DAM is introduced, market players can no more trade directly across the borders since capacity is made available to the whole market and optimised in the implicit auction. But other needs and opportunities for forward XB trading may arise. First, if the owners of the interconnector want to hedge their congestion rent, they could sell FTR-obligations some would prefer to call them a PTR UIoSI, but also this contract would act as a financial derivative since the holder will always have the incentive to give all capacity to the DAM. Generators and consumers cannot use only FTRs to hedge their fundamental risk since they are not exposed to volatile congestion rents. Second, generators and consumers may have a need for swaps. If there is a system price in a given region (like in the Nordic), market players may need to swaps a forward on the system price to their local area price to this end they need CfDs. If there is no system price available, market players may need a swap between two local area prices. This will make them able to use the adjacent forward market for hedging purposes, improving competition and market efficiency. These contracts could be called FTR-obligations or CfDs. TSOs cannot use these contracts to hedge congestion rent since it just swaps one price for another. Finally, if two areas have liquid forward markets towards their local area price there is no need for a FXBM. Cross border risk could then be managed by buying one forward and selling the other. 5) What techniques of market manipulation or gaming could be associated with the various market for hedging products? What measures could in your view help prevent such behavior? When Physical Transmission Rights exist there is a risk that one party may reserve transmission capacity in order to hinder transmission. With FTRs or PTRs with UIOSI the risk is more that there will be a limited number of market participants interested in these products and instead of being used for hedging, these products end up being for speculation. If the market is liquid, the FTRs may be used by TSOs to hedge congestion incomes. If the market proves to be illiquid, there s a risk that FTRs get underpriced, hence transfer welfare from TSOs to speculators. 6) Would you like to change, add or delete points in this wish-list? If so, please indicate why and how. The organization of secondary FTR/PTR trading is neither a task for TSOs nor for the auction office. 7) Which aspects of auction rules would be most valuable to be harmonised? Can you provide some concrete examples (what, when, where) of how this could help your commercial operation (e.g. lowering the transaction costs)? The leading principle must be that forward XB products support power derivatives markets. When considering what elements can and should be harmonised, the effects on the power derivatives markets must be evaluated. FTR type contract don t suite the Nordic market structure, and would most probably have a negative effect on the well-functioning Nordic derivatives market. 8) Which elements of auction rules have regional, country specific aspects, which should not be harmonised?

4(5) Once liquid derivatives market exists, rules with regard the products should not be regulated by Network Codes, but let the market deliver the desired products. In the Nordic market the CfD-market and products have entered market-based. 9) Which aspects should be harmonised in binding codes? See answer to question 8. 10) If you are to trade from the Iberian Peninsula to the Nordic region and there existed PTRs with UIOSI, FTR Options or Obligations and CfDs in different regions what obstacles, if any, would you face? How would you deal with them? Transmission rights are based on a rather old-fashioned thinking that one should be able to reserve transmission capacity for his own needs. Reserving this capacity with PTRs causes that this capacity is no longer available for the market. With liquid markets that benefit from implicit auction the need for separate transmission rights vanishes. Let s see two cases: Case 1: Selling electricity from Iberian Peninsula to the Nordic region without hedging. A generator sells its production on spot-market in price area Spain. An electricity buyer buys the electricity from the spot market in respective price area in Nordic region. Case 2: The same with hedging. In addition the generator sells a forward contract for price area Spain and hence hedges its sales with the forward s price. The buyer hedges similarly by buying a forward contract (or as in Nordic countries the main forward market is based on system price contracts, he buys a forward contract for system price and CfD-contract for the respective price area). 11) Would allocating the products at the same time represent an improvement for market players? Why? Where, if not everywhere, and under which conditions? The Nordic Forward market is based on derivatives having system price as underlying and the CfD-contracts supporting the power derivatives market. The allocation of these products is market-based and the product structures evolved based on the market participants needs. 12) How important is it that capacity calculation for the long-term timeframe is compatible and/or consistent with the short-term capacity calculation and that capacity is interdependent and optimised across different borders? 13) Please indicate the importance of availability of different hedging products with respect to their delivery period (e.g. multi-year, year, semester, season) for efficient hedging against price differential between bidding zones. What do you think of multiple-year products in particular? 14) What would be your preferred splitting of available interconnection capacity between the different timeframes of forward hedging products? Which criteria should drive the splitting between timeframes of forward hedging products? 15) While products with planned unavailability cannot be standardised and harmonised throughout Europe, they enable TSOs to offer more long-term capacity on average than standardised and harmonised products would allow. Do you think these products should be kept in the future and, if so, how could they be improved?

5(5) 16) Products for specific hours reflect market participants needs. What should drive the decision to implement such products? How should the available capacity be split between such products and base load ones in the long-term timeframe? 17) Should this possibility (buying back) be investigated and why (please provide pros and cons)? In case you favour this possibility, how should this buyback be organised? 18) With the potential evolution from PTRs with UIOSI to FTR options, does the removal of the nomination process constitute a problem for you? If so, why and on which borders, if not on all of them? 19) How could the potential evolution from PTRs with UIOSI to FTRs on border(s) you are active impact your current long-term hedging strategy? It depends on the status of the relevant markets. It would be a natural development to directly introduce FTRs within a market which is part of NWE-price coupling and where demand for transmission rights already exists. In markets with less liquid spot-market a monitoring of how PTRs are actually used over time will give insight into the moment at which it will be most appropriate to step down from PTRs. In view of significant advantages of FTRs (no nomination deadline reducing also operational risks and costs, no netting needed between TSOs for the nominated rights, etc.), further usage of PTRs will have to be justified by a cost-benefit analysis and subject to ACER s decision after consultation. For Nordic market FTRs are not suitable. Market actors need system price based derivatives and CfD-products. 20) If nomination possibility exists only on some borders (in case of wide FTRs implementation), is it worth for TSOs to work on harmonising the nomination rules and procedures? If so, should this harmonisation consider both the contractual and technical side? How important is such harmonisation for your commercial operation? Which aspects are the most crucial to be harmonised? No answer. 21) Looking at the current features offered by the different auction platforms (e.g. CASC.EU, CAO, individual TSO systems) and financial market platforms in Europe, what are the main advantages and weaknesses of each of them? No answer. 22) How do you think the single auction platform required by the CACM Framework Guidelines should be established and organised? o How do you see the management of a transitional phase from regional platforms to the single EU platform? o Should current regional platforms merge via a voluntary process or should a procurement procedure be organised at European Union level (and by whom)? o Should the Network Code on Forward Markets define a deadline for the establishment of the single European platform? If so, what would be a desirable and realistic date? It is important that the auction office is available for all interested parties. Further information: Petteri Haveri (petteri.haveri@energia.fi, +358 9 5305 2404)