Price Discrimination: Part 2. Sotiris Georganas



Similar documents
3 Price Discrimination

Lecture 6: Price discrimination II (Nonlinear Pricing)

Second degree price discrimination

ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS (TUTORIAL)

Problem Set 9 Solutions

SECOND-DEGREE PRICE DISCRIMINATION

2.2 Price Discrimination

Conditions for Efficiency in Package Pricing

Chapter 11 Pricing Strategies for Firms with Market Power

1.4 Hidden Information and Price Discrimination 1

PRICE DISCRIMINATION Industrial Organization B

First degree price discrimination ECON 171

Part IV. Pricing strategies and market segmentation

2.4 Multiproduct Monopoly. 2.4 Multiproduct Monopoly

2. Price Discrimination

KEELE UNIVERSITY MID-TERM TEST, 2007 BA BUSINESS ECONOMICS BA FINANCE AND ECONOMICS BA MANAGEMENT SCIENCE ECO MANAGERIAL ECONOMICS II

A Detailed Price Discrimination Example

Market Power and Efficiency in Card Payment Systems: A Comment on Rochet and Tirole

p, we suppress the wealth arguments in the aggregate demand function. We can thus state the monopolist s problem as follows: max pq (p) c (q (p)).

MICROECONOMICS II PROBLEM SET III: MONOPOLY

Economics 431 Fall st midterm Answer Key

Part IV. Pricing strategies and market segmentation. Chapter 8. Group pricing and personalized pricing

Sustainable Energy Systems

Solution to Homework Set 7

Lecture 2: Consumer Theory

All these models were characterized by constant returns to scale technologies and perfectly competitive markets.

Figure 1, A Monopolistically Competitive Firm

Managerial Economics Prof. Trupti Mishra S.J.M. School of Management Indian Institute of Technology, Bombay. Lecture - 13 Consumer Behaviour (Contd )

1. Supply and demand are the most important concepts in economics.

1. Briefly explain what an indifference curve is and how it can be graphically derived.

-1- Worked Solutions 5. Lectures 9 and 10. Question Lecture 1. L9 2. L9 3. L9 4. L9 5. L9 6. L9 7. L9 8. L9 9. L9 10. L9 11. L9 12.

Lecture Notes. 1 What is Asymmetric Information and why it matters for Economics?

A. a change in demand. B. a change in quantity demanded. C. a change in quantity supplied. D. unit elasticity. E. a change in average variable cost.

How To Price Bundle On Cable Television


2. Information Economics

ANOTHER PERVERSE EFFECT OF MONOPOLY POWER

Marginal cost. Average cost. Marginal revenue

Chapter 15: Monopoly WHY MONOPOLIES ARISE HOW MONOPOLIES MAKE PRODUCTION AND PRICING DECISIONS

Examples on Monopoly and Third Degree Price Discrimination

Lecture 9: Price Discrimination

Business Ethics Concepts & Cases

Answers to Chapter 6 Exercises

Advertising. Sotiris Georganas. February Sotiris Georganas () Advertising February / 32

Problem Set #5-Key. Economics 305-Intermediate Microeconomic Theory

Why do merchants accept payment cards?

Price Dispersion. Ed Hopkins Economics University of Edinburgh Edinburgh EH8 9JY, UK. November, Abstract

Name. Final Exam, Economics 210A, December 2011 Here are some remarks to help you with answering the questions.

Pricing to Mass Markets. Simple Monopoly Pricing, Price Discrimination and the Losses from Monopoly

INTRODUCTORY MICROECONOMICS

Product Differentiation In homogeneous goods markets, price competition leads to perfectly competitive outcome, even with two firms Price competition

SUPPLY AND DEMAND : HOW MARKETS WORK

Economics 2020a / HBS 4010 / HKS API-111 FALL 2010 Solutions to Practice Problems for Lectures 1 to 4

Economics 335, Spring 1999 Problem Set #7

Price Discrimination and Two Part Tariff

Chapter 21: Consumer Behavior and Utility Maximization

Competition between Apple and Samsung in the smartphone market introduction into some key concepts in managerial economics

Economics of Insurance

Do not open this exam until told to do so.

Chapter 21: The Discounted Utility Model

Oligopoly and Strategic Pricing

Pricing and Persuasive Advertising in a Differentiated Market

Pricing in a Competitive Market with a Common Network Resource

Using Revenue Management in Multiproduct Production/Inventory Systems: A Survey Study

Why is Insurance Good? An Example Jon Bakija, Williams College (Revised October 2013)

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

Common in European countries government runs telephone, water, electric companies.

Answers to Text Questions and Problems. Chapter 22. Answers to Review Questions

Module 7: Debt Contracts & Credit Rationing

Frequent flyer programs and dynamic contracting with limited commitment

Monopolistic Competition

Monopoly. E. Glen Weyl. Lecture 8 Price Theory and Market Design Fall University of Chicago

Moral Hazard. Itay Goldstein. Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania

ECON 312: Oligopolisitic Competition 1. Industrial Organization Oligopolistic Competition

Lecture 10 Monopoly Power and Pricing Strategies

1) If the government sets a price ceiling below the monopoly price, will this reduce deadweight loss in a monopolized market?

Labor Economics, Lecture 3: Education, Selection, and Signaling

Pricing with Perfect Competition. Business Economics Advanced Pricing Strategies. Pricing with Market Power. Markup Pricing

Optimal Income Taxation with Multidimensional Types

CHAPTER 4 Consumer Choice

Exercises for Industrial Organization Master de Economía Industrial Matilde Pinto Machado

Chapter 11. T he economy that we. The World of Oligopoly: Preliminaries to Successful Entry Production in a Nonnatural Monopoly Situation

LECTURE #15: MICROECONOMICS CHAPTER 17

CHAPTER 8 PROFIT MAXIMIZATION AND COMPETITIVE SUPPLY

A.2 The Prevalence of Transfer Pricing in International Trade

Health Economics. University of Linz & Physicians. Gerald J. Pruckner. Lecture Notes, Summer Term Gerald J. Pruckner Physicians 1 / 22

Durable Goods Monopoly with Network Externalities with Application to the PC Operating Systems Market 1

Monopoly and Monopsony Labor Market Behavior

Chapter 7: The Costs of Production QUESTIONS FOR REVIEW

Prices versus Exams as Strategic Instruments for Competing Universities

CHAPTER 10 MARKET POWER: MONOPOLY AND MONOPSONY

Economics 1011a: Intermediate Microeconomics

Capital Structure II

Imperfect information Up to now, consider only firms and consumers who are perfectly informed about market conditions: 1. prices, range of products

The Analysis of the Article Microsoft's Aggressive New Pricing Strategy Using. Microeconomic Theory

Exercises Lecture 8: Trade policies

Problem Set #3 Answer Key

Technology platforms, such as Microsoft Windows, are the hubs of technology industries. We develop a

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES BEST PRICES: PRICE DISCRIMINATION AND CONSUMER SUBSTITUTION. Judith A. Chevalier Anil K Kashyap

Transcription:

Price Discrimination: Part 2 Sotiris Georganas

1 More pricing techniques We will look at some further pricing techniques... 1. Non-linear pricing (2nd degree price discrimination) 2. Bundling

2 Non-linear pricing Definition 1 With a non-linear price a consumer s total expenditure on a good does not increase linearly (proportionately) with the number of unit purchased. Useful when 1. a monopolist faces unobserved heterogeneity in demand, and 2. the monopolist can prevent resale (no arbitrage) Think of the monopolist as designing offers (or bundles ) each consisting of a quantity and a total payment for each type of consumer.

2.1 A Graphical Representation Consider a monopolist who sells to two types of consumers: highwillingness-to-pay consumers and low-willingness-to-pay consumers. Assume: one consumer of each type. the monopolist cannot tell the consumers apart he does not know who is the high- and the low-willingness-to-pay consumer respectively. the monopolist s marginal cost is zero (for simplicity): the monopolist maximizes his revenue. The demands for both consumers are displayed in Fig 1.

If the monopolist could observe who is who, he could price discriminate perfectly: he would then sell q1 0 to person 1 (the low-demander) at price A, and q2 0 to person 2 (the high-demander) at price A + B + C. No consumer surplus for the consumers. However, this will not work if the monopolist cannot observe the demand type for each consumer. The high-willingness-to-pay consumer will have an incentive to pretend to be a low-willingness-to-pay consumer; by buying q 0 1 at price A, he can obtain a surplus equal to B.

What can the monopolist do then? Design price-quantity packages targeted at each type. Making sure that each consumer chooses the package intended for her. In other words: the consumer are induced to self-select: each consumer must prefer the bundle designed for her over that designed for the other type. The perfect price discrimination solution does not induce self-selection (it is not in high-willingness-to-pay consumer s interest to choose q 0 2 at price A + B + C).

A first attempt One possibility is to: Offer to sell q 0 1 at price A, and q0 2 at price A + C. The consumers then self-select (the low-willingness-to-pay consumer strictly prefers the low-quantity package; the high-willingnessto-pay consumer is indifferent between the two packages, gaining a surplus of B from each package). Total revenues are 2A + C (A from type 1 and A + C from type 2) But the monopolist can do even better than that!!!

The solution The monopolist can reduce the quantity intended for the low-willingnessto-pay consumer from q1 0, at the same time reducing the price. This reduces the profit on the low-willingness-to-pay consumer by the small black triangle. Fig 2. However, it also makes the low-quantity package less attractive for the high-willingness-to-pay consumer. The monopolist can then charge more for the high quantity q 0 2 : the area C has grown. At the optimum, 2A + C is maximized. Fig. 3.

Properties of the solution The low-willingness-to-pay consumer obtains zero surplus The high-willingness-to-pay consumer obtains a positive surplus The quantity sold to the low-willingness-to-pay consumer is lower than the efficient level q 0 1. The monopolist offers quantity discounts: the average price paid for q 0 1 is higher than that for q0 2.

2.2 Formal Analysis A monopoly firm produces a single good. Constant average (and marginal) cost of production: c. There is a set consumers, each with the following utility: θv (q) T when buying a quantity q > 0 and paying T. V ( ) is a differentiable function, with V (q) > 0, V (q) < 0 and V (0) = 0.

Hence if I don t buy anything (q = 0) and don t pay anything (T = 0), my utility is zero. θ is a taste parameter the strenght of preferences for the good. A given consumer s taste parameter θ is either high or low: θ {θ 1, θ 2 }, with 0 < θ 1 < θ 2. Assumption 1 Asymmetric information: The consumer knows his own θ, but the firm does not know it. The firm only knows that a fraction λ of all consumers are of type θ 1, and the others (a fraction 1 λ) are of type θ 2.

The firm offers two price-quantity bundles to the consumers: (q 1, T 1 ) is directed to the type-θ 1 consumers. (q 2, T 2 ) is directed to the type-θ 2 consumers. We assume that the parameters are such that it is optimal for the firm to sell to both consumer types, rather than focusing on only the high valuation consumers.

Analysis The firm chooses q 1, q 2, T 1, and T 2 so as to maximize its profit, Π m = λ (T 1 cq 1 ) + (1 λ) (T 2 cq 2 ), subject to four constraints: Two individual rationality constraints and two incentive compatibility constraints. Type-θ 1 consumers must prefer their bundle to not trading at all: θ 1 V (q 1 ) T 1 0. (IR-1) Type-θ 2 consumers must prefer their bundle to not trading at all: θ 2 V (q 2 ) T 2 0. (IR-2)

Type-θ 1 consumers must prefer their bundle to the bundle directed to the type-θ 2 consumers: θ 1 V (q 1 ) T 1 θ 1 V (q 2 ) T 2. (IC-1) Type-θ 2 consumers must prefer their bundle to the bundle directed to the type-θ 1 consumers: θ 2 V (q 2 ) T 2 θ 2 V (q 1 ) T 1. (IC-2)

We can simplify the problem by making two observations: If IR-1 and IC-2 are satisfied, so is IR-2. We can therefore ignore IR-2. To see this, note that By IC-2: θ 2 V (q 2 ) T 2 θ 2 V (q 1 ) T 1 By θ 2 > θ 1 : θ 2 V (q 1 ) T 1 θ 1 V (q 1 ) T 1 By IR-1: θ 1 V (q 1 ) T 1 0 Hence, completing the chain: θ 2 V (q 2 ) T 2 0, i.e. IR-2 is satisfied.

At the optimum, IC-1 is not binding. We can t ignore IC-1 just like that: we must prove that it is not binding. One can do this as follows: 1. Ignore IC-1 and solve for the solution. 2. Check whether IC-1 is satisfied at this solution. 3. If it is satisfied, we can conclude that the solution we found must solve also the problem with the constraint IC-1.

The simplified problem: choose q 1, q 2, T 1, and T 2 so as to maximize subject to Π m = λ (T 1 cq 1 ) + (1 λ) (T 2 cq 2 ), (1) θ 1 V (q 1 ) T 1 0 (IR-1) and θ 2 V (q 2 ) T 2 θ 2 V (q 1 ) T 1. (IC-2)

Note that since Π m is increasing in T 1 and T 2, both constraints must bind at the optimum. We thus have and T 1 = θ 1 V (q 1 ) (2) T 2 = θ 2 V (q 2 ) θ 2 V (q 1 ) + T 1 = θ 2 V (q 2 ) θ 2 V (q 1 ) + θ 1 V (q 1 ) = θ 2 V (q 2 ) (θ 2 θ 1 ) V (q 1 ). (3) We can now simplify the problem further, transforming it into an unconstrained problem by substituting in the objective function.

By plugging (2) and (3) into (1), we get Π m = λ [θ 1 V (q 1 ) cq 1 ] + (1 λ) [θ 2 V (q 2 ) (θ 2 θ 1 ) V (q 1 ) cq 2 ]. The problem now amounts to maximizing this expression for Π m w.r.t. q 1 and q 2 (without having to take any constraints into account). The FOC w.r.t. q 1 : Πm q 1 = λ [ θ 1 V (q 1 ) c ] (1 λ) (θ 2 θ 1 ) V (q 1 ) = 0 or θ 1 V (q 1 ) [ 1 (1 λ) (θ 2 θ 1 ) λ θ 1 ] = c (4)

where the term in brackets is positive but less than one! The FOC w.r.t. q 2 : Π m = (1 λ) [ θ 2 V (q 2 ) c ] = 0 q 2 or θ 2 V (q2 ) = c (5)

Conclusions 1. The high-demand consumers buy the socially optimal quantity: marginal utility/willingness to pay equals marginal cost. [By (5).] Intuition: Suppose e.g. that the monopolist sold a smaller quantity. Then by increasing the quantity q 2 up to the points where type 2 s marginal willingness to pay is equal to c and charging the type s willingness to pay for the additional quantity, lead to higher profits but leaves the consumer s utility unaffected. 2. The low-demand consumers buy less than the socially optimal quantity: marginal utility > marginal cost. [By (4).] Intuition:

The monopolist wants to extract the high-demand consumer s large surplus. An obstacle to this: If the high type gets too little surplus, he can choose the low type bundle instead. To prevent this, the monopolist makes the low-type s bundle less attractive by offering those consumers less. This works because high-demand consumers suffer more from a reduction in consumption than do low-demand consumers. (4) and (5) also imply that q 2 > q 1. 3. Low-demand consumers derive no surplus, while high-demand consumers derive a positive surplus.

4. The relevant personal arbitrage constraint is to prevent high-demand consumers from choosing the low-demand consumers bundle.

3 Commodity bundling A pricing strategy available for a monopolist who is selling more than one product. Definition 2 A monopolist firm is bundling if it offers to sell packages of related goods together. Examples include: (computer software, vacations, films etc.) So why bundle? Less expensive to sell together (cheaper production \ distribution) Complementarities in consumption.

3.1 Bundling to reduce variability in willingness to pay However, we will focus on a third possibility: Claim 1 Bundling may be an optimal pricing strategy when there is a high variability in the willingness to pay for the individual goods, but low variability in the willingness to pay for a package of the goods.

An example (Varian, Intermediate Microeconomics) A monopolist sell two software products: word processor and spreadsheet. Marginal cost is zero (for simplicity): revenues are maximized. Each consumer buys at most one unit of each product. There are two types of consumers: A and B whose willingness to pay are as follows:

Willingness to pay for products Type of consumer Word processor Spreadsheet Type A consumer 120 100 Type B consumer 100 120 Assumption 2 No complementaries in consumption a consumer s willingness to pay for package equals the sum of his willingness to pay for the individual components.

Pricing options 1. Sell each good separately: revenues maximized when each product is sold at $100 (the smallest willingness to pay) total revenues are then $400. 2. Sell a bundle: each consumer is willing to pay $220 for the bundle: set the price for the bundle at $220 Total revenues are $440.

3.2 General rule If the monopolist cannot price discriminate, he has to set the price for each individual product equal to the lowest willingness-to-pay. Thus if there is high variability in the willingness to pay, the price for each individual product will be low. If the variability in the willingness to pay for a bundle is low, then the monopolist can charge a fairly high price for the bundle. In the above case, there was no variability at all in the willingness to pay for the bundle. In this case, the monopolist can actually replicate perfect price discrimination by using the bundling technique.

4 What to remember from this lecture What is a non-linear pricing scheme. When might a monopolist use a non-linear pricing scheme. Properties of an optimal non-linear pricing scheme (that the lowquantity is held back to make it unattractive to the high-willingnessto-pay consumers, that the low-willingness-to-pay consumers obtain no consumer surplus, but the high-willingness-to-pay consumers do, that the solution involves quantity discounts). That a multi-product monopolist may be able to increase its profits by using a bundling strategy when the variability in the willingness to pay for the individual products is high but the variability in the willingness to pay for a bundle is low.