Economía y Sociedad ISSN: 1870-414X economíaysociedad@fevaq.net. Universidad Michoacana de San Nicolás de Hidalgo. México



Similar documents
Session 55 PD, Actuaries and the International Market. Moderator/Presenter: Ian G. Duncan, FSA, FIA, FCIA, MAAA

ANNEX Sociodemographic characteristics of SMNG affiliates*

OECD Reviews of Health Systems Mexico

Informality and the Expansion of Social Protection Programs: Evidence from Mexico 1

Population Aging Research Center. University of Pennsylvania. Mexican Migration to the US and Access to Health Care

The Risk of Losing Health Insurance Over a Decade: New Findings from Longitudinal Data. Executive Summary

Public private interactions in health: Three Mexican examples INSP CISS. Gustavo Nigenda López, PhD Luz Maria Gonzalez Michael Reich Jose Arturo Ruiz

Rethinking the Cultural Context of Schooling Decisions in Disadvantaged Neighborhoods: From Deviant Subculture to Cultural Heterogeneity

B3 REFORM OF THE MEXICAN HEALTHCARE SYSTEM: THE UNTOLD STORY

DIABETES AND HYPERTENSION OUTCOMES IN REPEATED-CROSS-SECTION EVALUATION IN MEXICO

11. Analysis of Case-control Studies Logistic Regression

Health Insurance as Social Protection in Latin America

The Impact of Health Insurance in Low- and Middle-Income Countries

Mexican Healthcare Model Reform, by Act. Eduardo Lara di Lauro. 1. The Mexican Health Care Model.

A STUDY OF WHETHER HAVING A PROFESSIONAL STAFF WITH ADVANCED DEGREES INCREASES STUDENT ACHIEVEMENT MEGAN M. MOSSER. Submitted to

Profiles and Data Analysis. 5.1 Introduction

Predicting the Performance of a First Year Graduate Student

Demand for Life Insurance in Malaysia

1. The parameters to be estimated in the simple linear regression model Y=α+βx+ε ε~n(0,σ) are: a) α, β, σ b) α, β, ε c) a, b, s d) ε, 0, σ

THE IMPACT OF CHILDHOOD HEALTH AND COGNITION ON PORTFOLIO CHOICE

Colombia REACHING THE POOR WITH HEALTH SERVICES. Using Proxy-Means Testing to Expand Health Insurance for the Poor. Differences between Rich and Poor

National Findings on Access to Health Care and Service Use for Non-elderly Adults Enrolled in Medicaid

Students' Opinion about Universities: The Faculty of Economics and Political Science (Case Study)

Health Economics Program

The Effect of Social and Demographic Factors on Life Insurance Demand in Croatia

DHCFP. Barriers to Obtaining Health Care among Insured Massachusetts Residents. Sharon K. Long and Lokendra Phadera Urban Institute.

Long-term Health Spending Persistence among the Privately Insured: Exploring Dynamic Panel Estimation Approaches

Factors affecting online sales

The Effect of China s New Cooperative Medical Scheme. on Rural Utilization of Preventive Medical Care. and Rural Households Health Status

Human Capital and Ethnic Self-Identification of Migrants

Policyholder s Satisfaction of Private Life Insurance Companies With Reference To Tirupur District, Tamilnadu

The Household Level Impact of Public Health Insurance. Evidence from the Urban Resident Basic Medical Insurance in China. University of Michigan

A DISCUSSION OF FEDERAL ELDER RIGHTS LAW IN MEXICO

Education and Wage Differential by Race: Convergence or Divergence? *

CHAPTER IV FINDINGS AND CONCURRENT DISCUSSIONS

Calculating the Probability of Returning a Loan with Binary Probability Models

SOUTH-WEST EUROPE 21

An Analysis of the Effect of Income on Life Insurance. Justin Bryan Austin Proctor Kathryn Stoklosa

Brand Loyalty in Insurance Companies

The relationship between insurance coverage and access to a regular source of health care

Case Study in Data Analysis Does a drug prevent cardiomegaly in heart failure?

Factors Affecting Students Academic Performance: A case study in Agartala Municipal Council Area

Distributional Incidence of Social, Infrastructure, and Telecommunication Services in Latin America. Mariana Marchionni y Pablo Glüzmann

Can National Health Insurance Programs Improve Health Outcomes? Re-Examining the Case of the New Cooperative Medical Scheme in Rural China

HEALTH CARE REFORM DOCUMENT FROM THE WEBSITE OF BLUE CROSS BLUE SHIELD OF NORTH DAKOTA

What Does Performance in Graduate School Predict? Graduate Economics Education and Student Outcomes. Susan Athey Harvard University

Using Insurance Before You Lose It: Health Care Consumption at the End of Coverage

National Money as a Barrier to International Trade: The Real Case for Currency Union Andrew K. Rose and Eric van Wincoop*

D.P. Abeysooriya a, P.A.P. Samantha Kumara b a Faculty of Information Technology, ICBT Campus, Sri Lanka. deloosha@icbtcampus.edu.lk.

Chapter II. Coverage and Type of Health Insurance

DEPARTMENT OF PSYCHOLOGY UNIVERSITY OF LANCASTER MSC IN PSYCHOLOGICAL RESEARCH METHODS ANALYSING AND INTERPRETING DATA 2 PART 1 WEEK 9

ACADEMIC EXPERIENCE 2003-Present, Assistant Professor of Economics and Statistics, California State University, Los Angeles

An Analysis of the Health Insurance Coverage of Young Adults

Does access to free health insurance crowd-out private transfers? Evidence from Mexico s Seguro Popular

An Introduction to Statistical Tests for the SAS Programmer Sara Beck, Fred Hutchinson Cancer Research Center, Seattle, WA

Do Taxes Really Affect the Consumption of Cigarettes?

The effects of Michigan s weakened motorcycle helmet use law on insurance losses

The Life-Cycle Motive and Money Demand: Further Evidence. Abstract

Poverty and income growth: Measuring pro-poor growth in the case of Romania

WORKING PAPER SERIES FINANCING OBSTACLES AMONG EURO AREA FIRMS WHO SUFFERS THE MOST? NO 1293 / FEBRUARY 2011

Predicting Successful Completion of the Nursing Program: An Analysis of Prerequisites and Demographic Variables

HEALTHCARE FINANCING REFORM: THE CASE in TURKEY. Prof. Ahmet Burcin YERELI. Department of Public Finance,

WHY DID DISABILITY ALLOWANCE RATES RISE IN THE GREAT RECESSION?

Documento de Trabajo. Trade Liberalization and Wage Inequality. Time Series Evidence from Chile.

The update mode study of residents electronic health records

Health Care in Rural America

Americans Experiences in the Health Insurance Marketplaces: Results from the First Month

HEALTH INSURANCE COVERAGE AND ADVERSE SELECTION

Tele-care and tele-alarms for the elderly: preliminary experiences in Mexico

DIMENSIONS OF SUSTAINABLE DEVELOPMENT Vol. I - Human Capital for Sustainable Economic Develpment - G. Edward Schuh

Health & Government Module 5 i2p Expedition India

The Impact of the Medicare Rural Hospital Flexibility Program on Patient Choice

User Behaviour on Google Search Engine

Credit Card Usage among White, African American and Hispanic Households

Are tax subsidies for private medical insurance self-financing? Evidence from a microsimulation model for outpatient and inpatient episodes

Файл скачан с сайта

How To Understand Medical Service Regulation In Japanese

Equity of access to health care for older adults in four major Latin American cities

Supplementary webappendix

seasonal causality in the energy commodities

Introduction to Quantitative Methods

Violent crime total. Problem Set 1

Evaluating Mode Effects in the Medicare CAHPS Fee-For-Service Survey

The Impact of Broadband Deployment on Recreational and Seasonal Property Values- A Hedonic Model

The Wage Return to Education: What Hides Behind the Least Squares Bias?

Dynamic Inefficiencies in Insurance Markets: Evidence from long-term care insurance *

HEALTH INSURANCE COVERAGE FOR FAMILIES WITH CHILDREN: FINDINGS FROM THE CONSUMER EXPENDITURE SURVEY

Reasons for the Coexistence of Different Distribution Channels: An Empirical Test for the German Insurance Market

Labor informality and the incentive effects of social security Evidence from a health reform in Uruguay

Key Features of the Affordable Care Act, By Year

Personal Retirement Accounts and Saving Emma Aguila. Web Appendix (Not for Publication)

PREDICTING SUCCESS IN THE COMPUTER SCIENCE DEGREE USING ROC ANALYSIS

Negros Women For Tomorrow Foundation (NWTF): Progress out of Poverty Index (PPI ) Case Study Series

HOW DO ONLINE STUDENTS DIFFER FROM LECTURE STUDENTS?

The Mexican Social Protection System in Health

WORK DISABILITY AND HEALTH OVER THE LIFE COURSE

Timeline: Key Feature Implementations of the Affordable Care Act

Mexico 2000: Survey Information

What It s Worth: Field of Training and Economic Status in 2009

Elementary Statistics Sample Exam #3

Transcription:

Economía y Sociedad ISSN: 1870-414X economíaysociedad@fevaq.net Universidad Michoacana de San Nicolás de Hidalgo México Bonilla Zarrazaga, Miguel Ángel; Lara Álvarez, Jorge Cost effect in the choice of healthcare provider in a mixed system: the case of Mexico Economía y Sociedad, vol. XIX, núm. 32, enero-junio, 2015, pp. 41-52 Universidad Michoacana de San Nicolás de Hidalgo Morelia, México Available in: http://www.redalyc.org/articulo.oa?id=51040665003 How to cite Complete issue More information about this article Journal's homepage in redalyc.org Scientific Information System Network of Scientific Journals from Latin America, the Caribbean, Spain and Portugal Non-profit academic project, developed under the open access initiative

E C O N O M Í A Y S O C I E D A D ENERO-JUNIO 32 Cost effect in the choice of healthcare provider in a mixed system The case of Mexico Miguel Ángel Bonilla Zarrazaga* Gerald R. Ford School of Public Policy, University of Michigan mbonilla@umich.edu Jorge Lara Álvarez* FIRA jlara@fira.gob.mx Abstract This paper shows that, in Mexico, the decision of attending to a private health facility versus a public one is mainly determined by the time of transportation. In our study, we analyzed data from the National Survey of Health and Nutrition (2012) in Mexico to estimate the likelihood of attending to a private clinic using a Linear Probability Model. Another remarkable finding is that consultation cost is not a Fecha de recepción: 04-marzo-2015 Fecha de aprobación: 23-mayo-2015 * These authors contributed equally to this work. None of the authors have any competing interests in the manuscript. The authors wish to thank the Journal referees for their very useful comments on earlier drafts of this paper. All errors are our own. 41

COST EFFECT IN THE CHOICE OF HEALTHCARE PROVIDER IN A MIXED SYSTEM: THE CASE OF MEXICO determinant factor due the low economic cost of receiving medical attention by private doctors in pharmacies. Our results also suggest that a health reform should focus on improving the physical availability (proximity) of public health care centers. Keywords: public versus private health care, health care reform in Mexico. JEL Clasification: I13 Health Insurance, Public and Private; J18 Public Policy I. Introduction In developing countries, public healthcare is a fundamental tool to guarantee that the whole population has access to a fundamental right, such as health. Therefore, it is important to understand what kind of incentives make agents to choose attend to a private health facility when a public one is available, and almost free (monetary cost). This research will analyze the likelihood of choosing a private healthcare provider in Mexico, based on the effective economic cost paid per medical consultation. This study is especially relevant in a country with both public and private health care systems. Mexico has a mixed healthcare system. Presumably, some part of the population is able to choose between paying a fee per a consultation and getting a consultation for free in the public health facility. But, how much is the people willing to pay for medical attention? It would be reasonable that the price of the health service influences the decision of going to the private or the public system. To study this decision, we will use data from the Mexican National Healthcare and Nutrition Survey 2012. The central question of this research is: how relevant is the economic cost in the decision making process between a private and a public clinic in Mexico? For this aim, we will consider cost measured both as time and money spent in commuting as well as money per consultation. The central hypothesis is that if there are no restrictions to affiliation and quality is distributed similarly between public and private systems; most of the people will prefer the free service, unless the public system is not free. For instance, in the public system, the waiting time can be long, the clinic can be very far, or it can be costly to arrive. Then, by studying this decision, this research will help to realize whether a structural health reform is needed and on what it shall focus. The paper is organized as follows. First, there will be a brief description about the Mexican Healthcare system. Then, a brief review of the literature about how the system works will be presented. In the third part, the data will be described. In the following section, the results will be discussed. Finally, some of the policy implications of these findings will be addressed. II. The Mexican Healthcare system Mexico has health systems provided by both public and private sectors. The public one divided itself into branches and those branches are mutually exclusive among 42

MIGUEL ÁNGEL BONILLA ZARRAZAGA JORGE LARA ÁLVAREZ them, and most of the time, they can be used only by registered people. The largest are IMSS, for affiliated workers of private companies, and ISSSTE for government workers; but there are also local public health branches. In order to provide an idea of how big they are, in 2013, IMSS reached 58 million people and ISSSTE 12 million people (Presidency of Mexico, 2013). As a matter of fact, in Mexico, during the last thirty years the informal market in the country grew faster than the formal one. In order to reduce costs, some companies hired personal without social security. As a response, in 2004, the Federal Government launched the Popular Insurance (Seguro Popular), with the objective to provide health insurance to 50 million children and adults that were in families with non-formal workers members. These factors incited that Mexico achieved universal social security in 2012, according to Federal Government. Despite the fact that the coverage has been extended nationwide, the public system still has a lack of customer-based service. Complains about the lack of quality in the attention as well as paper work load are commons. Thus, many companies offer exclusive private insurances for their employees to receive attention in private clinics. Another situation is that poor and rich people face different problems paying for their health. In 2005, for instance, the catastrophic expenses (more than 20% of the income is spent in health) among the lowest income sectors were explained by the cost of medicines, but for rich people the main cause was hospitalization (Perez-Rico et al, 2005). The bad service in the public system also deals with the expansion of cheap options in the market. For instance, in 2002, the cost of a basic private consultation was around 30 USD. In that year, the private company Farmacias Similares expanded its operations opening thousands of pharmacies all over the country, providing low rates medications and medical consultations per 2 USD. This dropped the prices of primary health services in Mexico. In 2007, Farmacias Similares gave 4.5 million consultations while the IMSS provided 8 million. Nowadays, there are at least six companies providing consultation from no rate to three dollars. (Chu et al, 2007). Even though the private system has expanded recently, the best hospitals still belong to the public system. The Army, for instance, manages several hospitals where the Presidents, the officials and registered public receive a high quality attention. The healthcare system, where many subsystems exist is peculiar in the OECD countries. As the OECD reports, the public sector serves different part of the population and with little connection between them. Poorer households are less well covered by social insurance than richer households and a larger share of the poor also face catastrophic and poverty-creating health-care expenditures. With voluntary enrolment in the Seguro Popular, states have an incentive to affiliate as many families as possible and this should also encourage them to provide more and better quality services (OECD, 2005). As the next section will present, there are a few researchers that have tried to know more about how this system works and what should be done to improve it. 43

COST EFFECT IN THE CHOICE OF HEALTHCARE PROVIDER IN A MIXED SYSTEM: THE CASE OF MEXICO III. Literature Review The decision making process within the coexistence of two health systems has been analyzed in cross-national data. For example, Bastida (1998) documented that a free healthcare system is related with more people accessing to health services, at least for border residents of the US who preferred to commute to be attended in Mexico before the expansion of Medicare. This study also found that in cities close to the border, Mexican-American families (who presumably could choose between the public sector in Mexico, and private sector in the US) were more likely to have no insurance. Also, those household incomes between 7000 and 30000 were more likely to visit a doctor in Mexico than in the US. In a study about the Mexican systems and subsystems, Laurel (2007) mentioned that the public and private sectors are very different, those with a formal job and their families (about 50 percent of the population) have free health services offered by the social security institutes at their own integrated health facilities with salaried staff and a geographic distribution fairly congruent with the number of insured persons. This contrasts sharply with the conditions of access for the uninsured population that faces a variety of obstacles to accede to required health care. The main one is economical since it has to pay for almost all medical services and drugs which frequently mean that necessary care is postponed among the poor. In another study, Puig (2009) analyzed the differences in perceived quality among public and private institutions with survey data of 2006. The author examined how the users of each system perceived the quality, finding that quality was more related with assistance to private sector. Respondents who received health care services at IMSS and ISSSTE facilities were less likely to rate the quality of health care obtained as good or very good than those attended at private facilities. Other researchers in Mexico have also addressed the quality. For instance, Barber (2008) found that patients receiving care from private providers and non-medical personnel received lower quality prenatal care than what is recommended in clinical guidelines. However, those models did not include any variable related with the amount of money paid for the medical attention, even though that a higher education achievement (a proxy of income) was associated with the use of private providers. What is the relevance of the way people choose the system into the public policies discussion? Levy (2005) argues that the healthcare system is a fundamental column of the Mexican welfare policy, where such other programs as Conditional cash transfers. Also, that the system by itself is related with the mobility of the society. The worth of maintaining such a system with so many subsystems has been a recent public discussion. For instance, Levy (2010) argued that the public system based on quotas should disappear because it promotes the informal work. Besides the subsystems should be integrated into a single institution financed with a consumption tax. Eventually, this will drop the attendance to the private sector. Finally, the idea of getting universal coverage has also been criticized by some authors. For instance, Leal (2011) argues that 44

MIGUEL ÁNGEL BONILLA ZARRAZAGA JORGE LARA ÁLVAREZ universal coverage is more associated with inefficiency rather than with real changes to the social welfare schemes. These studies prove that understanding how people choose going to the private system is important, especially to know what are the challenges of healthcare public policies. In the next section, the data for this study will be described in order to present how reliable is the information analyzed. IV. Data Since the late 80 s, the Mexican government has implemented the National Survey of Nutrition and Health (ENSANUT). The last edition available was done in 2012, and it provide us with the data to test the hypothesis of our research. 2012 is the first edition since it was announced that universal healthcare insurance was achieved in Mexico. The ENSANUT looks to quantify the frequency, distribution and tendencies of the conditions and determinants regarding the health and nutrition in Mexico. These include the coverage and quality of the health services. The sample is a randomized survey with national representativeness, for both rural and urban areas. Questionnaires were collected between October 2011 and May 2012 and data was released in December 2013. The survey interviewed one person in each home that belong to the following age groups: 0-4; 5-9; 10-19; >20; and, recent users of the health services. Information collected includes weight, size, hemoglobin levels and arterial rate (among selected individual), also, blood samples were used to measure nutriments, antibodies and health conditions in adults. Therefore, questions are asked at an individual level. The size of the sample is 96,031 questionnaires answered in 50,528 houses. The 50,528 houses represent the more than 29 million of houses in Mexico. As average, 3.89 individuals habit each house in the sample, a similar average than the 2010 Census (3.91 individuals). For this study, a sample of 14,104 users of health services was considered. This subsample consist of people who recently used health services. Then we can focus on: general respondents and their probability to go to private or public sector; users that have gone to private or public sector, and, characteristics that determine assisting with each provider. V. Results Descriptive statistics and construction of variables The survey asked if respondents received medical consultation in the previous two weeks. As it can be seen on Table 1, the information of this variable determines the subsample considered for the further steps. In total, from the 14,104 respondents of this subsample, 13,187 answered that they needed to receive medical attention. Also, the same reference provides the total number of people that effectively received attention, which represents more than 13 thousands of individuals. 45

COST EFFECT IN THE CHOICE OF HEALTHCARE PROVIDER IN A MIXED SYSTEM: THE CASE OF MEXICO Table 1. Subsample Question / Answer Total With missing Without missing U101. Excluding hospitalization, in the last two weeks, did you require or receive medical consultation Yes 13,187 93.50% 93.52% No 913 6.47% 6.48% NS/NR 4 0.03% Total 14,104 100% 100.00% U302. Did you receive attention? Yes 13,059 92.59% 99.05% No 125 0.89% 0.95% NS/NR 3 0.02% Blank 917 6.50% Total 14,104 100.00% 100.00% Source. Elaborated by the authors with information from ENSANUT 2012 In our study, as we are attempting to understand the probability of going to the private sector, we constructed a dependent variable with a dummy that equals one if people went with a private doctor. For this purpose, we used the information provided in Question u401 of the questionnaire: Where did you go to the doctor? The descriptive statistics of this question are on Table 2 and Graph 1. In the ENSANUT, most of the answers were coded as categorical variables, according to each institution that could provide attention to any person in the sample. The categories Pharmacy and Private Doctor were both coded as Private. We threated the Other category as missing values (Table 2 & Graph 1). As a result, to construct our dependent variable, we assigned a value of 1 to Pharmacy and Private; and a value of 0 (Public sector) to IMSS/ISSSTE/Local ISSSTE/ Pemex/ Defense/ Marine/ Secretary of Healthcare/ IMSS Oportunidades. The distribution of attendance to public and private sector is presented in Graph 2 and Table 3. Data Analysis. T-tests A first approach to analyze the difference between the public and private sector was to understand if they were effectively different. We perform a t-test to see if the mean price of the public sector was different from zero. The results are presented in Table 4. However, as the p-value is 0.00, the null hypothesis that people paid no money for the consultation even in the public clinics is rejected. So our result suggest that people might have paid a fee for the consultation, but the average cost in public clinics is 11 Mexican pesos (less than one dollar). As a second step, we analyzed if there was any statistical difference between the 46

MIGUEL ÁNGEL BONILLA ZARRAZAGA JORGE LARA ÁLVAREZ Table 2 & Graph 1. Distribution of health providers U401. Where did you receive medical attention? 32.35% Pharmacy 1,627 11.54% Defense 19 0.13% IMSS- 259 1.84% Oportunidades ISSSTE 413 2.93% Local ISSSTE 204 1.45% Marine 17 0.12% Private doctor 2,612 18.52% Other 389 2.76% Pemex 35 0.25% IMSS 2,921 20.71% (blank) 1,046 7.42% Total 14,104 100.00% IMSS 34% Pemex 1% Other 5% Private doctor 31% Pharmacy 19% Defense 0% IMSS- Oportunida des 3% ISSSTE 5% Local ISSSTE 2% Marine 0% Source. Elaborated by the authors with information from ENSANUT 2012 Graph 2 & Table 3. Private and public sector 10,000 8,000 6,000 4,000 2,000 0 People Attended By Sector 4,239 Private 8,430 Public Attention in private clinic Private 4,239 Public 8,430 Other 389 Blank 1,046 14,104 Source: Elaborated by the authors with information from ENSANUT 2012 amounts paid in private and public clinics. This is relevant because if the values were the same, this research would lose its explanatory power. Nevertheless, as Table 5 shows, the means were different. The average paid in a private clinic is larger than the one in the public clinics: 189 pesos (14 USD) for private clinic and 11 pesos (0.8 USD) for a public one (Table 5.). Data Analysis. Model To understand why people might go to a private clinic instead of a public one (that is cheaper, at least monetary speaking), we will use the indicator variable for the use of private sector as dependent. As it is a dummy, the econometric model can be a Linear 47

COST EFFECT IN THE CHOICE OF HEALTHCARE PROVIDER IN A MIXED SYSTEM: THE CASE OF MEXICO Table 5. Test of the difference in means The people in public and private sector paid the same amount for the consultation? Private sample size (n1) 4239 mean (µ 1) 189.476 SD (S1) 492.529 Public sample size (n2) 8430 mean (µ2) 11.299 SD (S2) 18.465 Results Variance (Pooled) 81388.398 SE (Pooled) 285.287 t (cal) -33.170 degrees of freedom 12667 p-value 0.000 Source: Elaborated by the authors with information from ENSANUT 2012 Probability Model (LPM). We are aware that given the size of the sample, it could be accurate to use logit/probit models, however this is the easiest way to estimate the effects. In addition, as it will be shown in Table 7, the value of the predicted probabilities are very likely to fall between 0 and 1. Besides, the unit of observation is an individual but the sample includes individuals that belong to the same household, and the probit/ logit model assumes that the observations are independent. In our model, we included the cost paid by consultation as a predictor of the private or public sector. The most intuitive approach is that people would avoid really expensive private providers if a free consultation were available. Therefore, a variable that needs to be included is the total amount of money that was paid per consultation (public and private). However, there are more costs associated with going to consultation. Presumably, some people would have preferred to pay the cost of a private provider if commuting to a public clinic is expensive. To control this effect, a variable that asks for the money invested in transportation will be used. Finally, in some areas the time should be more valuable than the money. For instance, the Metro Station of Mexico city has a cost of 5 pesos (less than 0.40 USD) and one person can virtually cross the city using it, but some people spend up to three hours in a one-way trip. Thus, a variable of the amount of time that was used to commute was also included. As control, we included variables as age, gender and type of zone (Table 6). The results of our model are presented in Table 7. As it can be seen, almost all the variables are significant. The main finding is that our intuition is correct, private choice of health care is influenced by its costs associated. However, and perhaps surprisingly, on average, the decision to attend to a private clinic is almost not affected neither by 48

MIGUEL ÁNGEL BONILLA ZARRAZAGA JORGE LARA ÁLVAREZ Table 6. Variables used Type of variable Dependent Independent Control Description Attendance to a private clinic Moneydoctor. Moneyarrive MinutesTransport Age Gender Location Categorization 1= Attendance in private clinic 0= Attendance in public clinic Value in pesos. How much did you pay for the medical consultation? Value in pesos. How much did you pay to arrive to the place where you received medical attention? Value in minutes. How many minutes did you spend to arrive to the place where you received medical attention? Measured in years. Dummy. Male Metro/Urban/Rural Source: Elaborated by the authors with information from ENSANUT 2012a the consultation cost nor by the money invested in transportation but by the time that it takes to arrive to the health facility. Unfortunately, a limitation of our data is there are not variables to control by socioeconomic characteristics. Then, we cannot distinguish whether the effect is heterogeneous by income level, for example. This limitation might be addressed in future studies with a more complete dataset. Nevertheless, we consider that the small value of the coefficients of consultation cost and money invested to commute might be related with the fact that many pharmacies provided low cost consultations, as we mentioned before. The fact that the coefficient of commuting time (MinutesTransport) is negative suggests that when people does not have a nearby private option (for example, a pharmacy) available, they are more likely to attend to a public clinic. Also, the fact that people in rural areas are less likely to attend to a private health care it might be due the lack of availability of private facilities in those areas (Table 7.). It can be argued that money invested to arrive is very small due to the following: if people needs to expend some money in transportation to arrive to a private facility, probably they will also need to expend (even more) money to commute to a public health center. Therefore, people might consider that transportation is a fixed cost, and almost irrelevant to their decision. There might be other factors that explain the decision we are studying. For instance, the quality factor presented in the literature review. Under that setting, people that went to the private sector would be more likely to pay a big cost in order to avoid the presumably bad attention of the public clinics. However, we think that, due to the 49

COST EFFECT IN THE CHOICE OF HEALTHCARE PROVIDER IN A MIXED SYSTEM: THE CASE OF MEXICO Table 7. Results of the model Coefficients S.E. t Stat P-value Intercept 0.405098 0.011909 34.014745 0.000000 MinutesTransport -0.001669 0.000350-4.768422 0.000002 MoneyArrive 0.000065 0.000025 2.555867 0.010604 Money_doctor 0.000340 0.000012 28.751606 0.000000 Age -0.002918 0.000158-18.527420 0.000000 Male 0.036587 0.008221 4.450235 0.000009 Metro 0.074030 0.010399 7.118690 0.000000 Rural -0.073244 0.011089-6.605160 0.000000 Multiple R 0.328193064 R Square 0.107710687 Adjusted R Square 0.107138376 Standard Error 0.45854515 Observations 12669 Source: Elaborated by the authors with information from ENSANUT 2012. huge amount of variance in the quality of the public health care system, and the usually people in the public system cannot choose their doctors, quality should not been a relevant factor. On the other hand, an important limitation of our study is the lack of a variable related with income. Presumably, people with higher income will have greater opportunities to decide which service they prefer. Nevertheless, we do believe that the fact that money is not relevant for attending to a private clinic for the whole sample, suggest that it will be even less relevant for only the richer people. Finally, our approach might be flawed in the composition of the dependent variable. Perhaps, it will be more informative to divide the different subsystems; for instance, we could create a categorical dependent variable with different values if the individual went to the IMSS or ISSSTE. However, as we suggested above, a probit (or ordered probit) is not recommended due to the lack of independence between observations. VI. Conclusion and implications Although a free public healthcare systems in a development country seems important, empirical analyses of whether it satisfies the needs of their users are rather scarce. First, we establish some hypothesis of why people might choose to pay for private attention when public healthcare is available. We argue that the increase of private facilities, mainly by chain pharmacies, helped to reduce the cost of medical consultation. The main conclusion of our research is that cost (in time) affects negatively the probability of choosing a private healthcare provider in Mexico. However, the impact is extremely low, and presumably other factors influence more the decision of avoiding the visit to a public and free clinic. An unexpected result of our empirical analysis is that 50

MIGUEL ÁNGEL BONILLA ZARRAZAGA JORGE LARA ÁLVAREZ the cost of consultation and the money invested in commuting are almost not important to decide whether to go to the private or public health facility. An extension of this research will be to study the factors the might determine a switching between public and private healthcare. Is there a person that uses a private facility for some diseases but a public one for others? Do bad experiences contributes to a switch? That it, what is the likelihood that a person that is currently using the public systems change to the private one? Is it the likelihood similar for a private to a public switching? References ANGRIST, Joshua D.; PISCHKE, Jörn-Steffen. Mostly harmless econometrics: An empiricist s companion. Princeton university press, 2008. BASTIDA, E., BROWN III, H. and PAGÁN, J. (2008). Persistent disparities in the use of health care along the US Mexico border: an ecological perspective. American Journal of Public Health, 98(11), 1987. COX, David Roxbee; SNELL, E. Joyce. Analysis of binary data. CRC Press, 1989. CHU, M. and GARCIA, R. Farmacias Similares - Private and public health care for the base of the pyramid in Mexico. Harvard Business school. N2-307-092. March 1, 2007 MEXICO. FEDERAL MEXICAN GOVERNMENT. (2013). Stats of the Country. National Report of the Federal Government 2013. Available in: http://www.presidencia.gob.mx/ informe/ and http://d5d3d27e1f3d539a162f-a00104427ebc661a8d17f062b85c9f9a.r74.cf2. rackcdn.com/1_ig_anexo_estadistico.pdf LEAL, G. (2011). Is it really desirable the universal coverage? (In spanish. Original title: Es realmente deseable la cobertura universal?). Estudios políticos (México), (24), 77-106. http://www.scielo.org.mx/scielo.php?pid=s0185-16162011000300005&script=sci_arttext HARVARD INITIATIVE FOR GLOBAL HEALTH, MEXICO MINISTRY OF HEALTH, and NATIONAL INSTITUTE OF PUBLIC HEALTH (MEX). (2005). Mexico Health Metrics. Cambridge, MA: Harvard Initiative for Global Health. JOHNSTON, John; DINARDO, John. Econometric methods. McGraw-Hill: New York, 1997 LAUREL A. S. (2007). Granting Universal Access to Health Care: The experience of the Mexico City Government. A case study commissioned by the Health Systems Knowledge Network, March 2007 Background to the Health Systems Knowledge Network. http://www. who.int/social_determinants/resources/csdh_media/mexico_universal_access_2007_en.pdf LEVY S. (2007). Productivity, growth and poverty in Mexico. What is next after Progresa- Oportunidades? (In spanish. Original title: Productividad, crecimiento y pobreza en México: qué sigue después de ProgresaOportunidades?). InterAmerican Development Bank.http:// publications.iadb.org/bitstream/handle/11319/2684/productivity%2c%20growth%20 and%20poverty%20in%20mexico.%20what%20follows%20progresa-oportunidades%3f. pdf;jsessionid=137115612d96f6d4aed8b3a701b7daf2?sequence=1 LEVY, S. (2010). Good intentions, bad outcomes: Social policy, informality, and economic 51

COST EFFECT IN THE CHOICE OF HEALTHCARE PROVIDER IN A MIXED SYSTEM: THE CASE OF MEXICO growth in Mexico. Brookings Institution Press. OECD (2005). Reviews of Health System. Mexico. OECD 2005 http://www.borderhealth. org/files/res_839.pdf PÉREZ, R., SESMA, S. and PUENTES, E. Gastos catastróficos por motivos de salud en México: estudio comparativo por grado de marginación. Salud Pública de México, vol. 47, núm. 1, 2005, pp. S47-S53. Instituto Nacional de Salud Pública. México PRESIDENCY OF MEXICO, Anexo Estadístico, Primer Informe de Gobierno 2013. http:// www.presidencia.gob.mx/informe/ PUIG, A., PAGÁN, J. A. and WONG, R. (2009). Assessing Quality across Health Care Subsystems in Mexico. The Journal of ambulatory care management,32(2), 123. 52