Asset Management Contracts and Equilibrium Prices



Similar documents
THE GREAT RISK/RETURN INVERSION - WHO LOSES OUT?

CFA Examination PORTFOLIO MANAGEMENT Page 1 of 6

The CAPM (Capital Asset Pricing Model) NPV Dependent on Discount Rate Schedule

Broker-Dealer Leverage and the Cross-Section of Stock Returns 1

Chapter 5 Risk and Return ANSWERS TO SELECTED END-OF-CHAPTER QUESTIONS

International Stock Market Integration: A Dynamic General Equilibrium Approach

B.3. Robustness: alternative betas estimation

Annuity Decisions with Systematic Longevity Risk. Ralph Stevens

The Risk-Free Rate s Impact on Stock Returns with Representative Fund Managers

Portfolio Performance Measures

Chap 3 CAPM, Arbitrage, and Linear Factor Models

Futures Price d,f $ 0.65 = (1.05) (1.04)

The Conversion of Cooperatives to Publicly Held Corporations: A Financial Analysis of Limited Evidence

A Behavioral Economics Exploration into the Volatility Anomaly *

Applied Economics For Managers Recitation 5 Tuesday July 6th 2004

On the Efficiency of Competitive Stock Markets Where Traders Have Diverse Information

Cost of Capital, Valuation and Strategic Financial Decision Making

Margin Calls, Trading Costs and Asset Prices in Emerging Markets: The Financial Mechanics of the Sudden Stop Phenomenon

Betting Against Beta

Dynamic Equilibrium in an Economy with an Illiquid Stock Market

Foundations of Asset Management Goal-based Investing the Next Trend

Investment Philosophies: Introduction

CONTENTS OF VOLUME IB

SAMPLE MID-TERM QUESTIONS

AFM 472. Midterm Examination. Monday Oct. 24, A. Huang

Tilted Portfolios, Hedge Funds, and Portable Alpha

DOES IT PAY TO HAVE FAT TAILS? EXAMINING KURTOSIS AND THE CROSS-SECTION OF STOCK RETURNS

Jorge Cruz Lopez - Bus 316: Derivative Securities. Week 11. The Black-Scholes Model: Hull, Ch. 13.

News Trading and Speed

Chapter 9. The Valuation of Common Stock. 1.The Expected Return (Copied from Unit02, slide 39)

END OF CHAPTER EXERCISES - ANSWERS. Chapter 14 : Stock Valuation and the EMH

Computing the optimal portfolio policy of an investor facing capital gains tax is a challenging problem:

CHAPTER 11: ARBITRAGE PRICING THEORY

CHAPTER 10 RISK AND RETURN: THE CAPITAL ASSET PRICING MODEL (CAPM)

Finance Theory

Asset Prices And Asset Quantities

Transaction Costs and Asset Prices: A Dynamic Equilibrium Model

Option Value of Cash. Jialin Yu Columbia Business School. April 20, 2010

Chapter 11, Risk and Return

A Review of Cross Sectional Regression for Financial Data You should already know this material from previous study

FINANCIAL ECONOMICS OPTION PRICING

CHAPTER 6. Topics in Chapter. What are investment returns? Risk, Return, and the Capital Asset Pricing Model

Online Appendix for Demand for Crash Insurance, Intermediary Constraints, and Risk Premia in Financial Markets

CAPM, Arbitrage, and Linear Factor Models

Market Efficiency and Behavioral Finance. Chapter 12

Answers to Concepts in Review

Economics of Insurance

Practical aspects of implementing MiFID requirementsin GIPS compositereports

OULU BUSINESS SCHOOL. Jesse Väisänen EMBEDDED LEVERAGE AND PERFORMANCE OF HEDGE FUND SHARE CLASSES

Chapter 9. The Valuation of Common Stock. 1.The Expected Return (Copied from Unit02, slide 36)

Two-State Options. John Norstad. January 12, 1999 Updated: November 3, 2011.

ANALYSIS AND MANAGEMENT

We are motivated to test

Optimal Consumption and Investment with Asymmetric Long-term/Short-term Capital Gains Taxes

Chapter 7 Risk, Return, and the Capital Asset Pricing Model

The Rational Gambler

Financial Market Microstructure Theory

Life Cycle Asset Allocation A Suitable Approach for Defined Contribution Pension Plans

The Cost of Financial Frictions for Life Insurers

Chapter 11. Topics Covered. Chapter 11 Objectives. Risk, Return, and Capital Budgeting

Computational Finance Options

The Real Business Cycle model

Black Scholes Merton Approach To Modelling Financial Derivatives Prices Tomas Sinkariovas Words: 3441

Market Access ** Helmut Laux/Robert M. Gillenkirch/Matthias M. Schabel*

Portfolio Management for institutional investors

Wel Dlp Portfolio And Risk Management

Review for Exam 2. Instructions: Please read carefully

Asymmetric Correlations and Tail Dependence in Financial Asset Returns (Asymmetrische Korrelationen und Tail-Dependence in Finanzmarktrenditen)

The Equity Premium in India

A Model of Trading Volume with Tax-Induced Heterogeneous Valuation and Transaction Costs*

Current Accounts in Open Economies Obstfeld and Rogoff, Chapter 2

Holding Period Return. Return, Risk, and Risk Aversion. Percentage Return or Dollar Return? An Example. Percentage Return or Dollar Return? 10% or 10?

Adaptive Arrival Price

Chapter 6 The Tradeoff Between Risk and Return

Capital Structure II

This paper is not to be removed from the Examination Halls

FIN FINANCIAL INSTRUMENTS SPRING 2008

Chapter 13 Composition of the Market Portfolio 1. Capital markets in Flatland exhibit trade in four securities, the stocks X, Y and Z,

Lecture 15: Final Topics on CAPM

Practice Set #4 and Solutions.

International Finance Discussion Papers Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. A Model of Anomaly Discovery K.7

Investing in Foreign Currency is like Betting on your Intertemporal Marginal Rate of Substitution.

Derivative Users Traders of derivatives can be categorized as hedgers, speculators, or arbitrageurs.

Review of Basic Options Concepts and Terminology

Choice under Uncertainty

Understanding Closed-End Fund Puzzles A Stochastic Turnover Perspective

A Panel Data Analysis of Corporate Attributes and Stock Prices for Indian Manufacturing Sector

Introduction to Equity Derivatives

Unit06 Sample Homework Problems CHAPTER 10. INVESTMENT RETURNS AND AGGREGATE MEASURES OF STOCK MARKETS

ECON20310 LECTURE SYNOPSIS REAL BUSINESS CYCLE

Defensive equity. A defensive strategy to Canadian equity investing

M.I.T. Spring 1999 Sloan School of Management First Half Summary

Best Styles: Harvesting Risk Premium in Equity Investing

Portfolio Choice under Probability Distortion

Momentum Traders in the Housing Market: Survey Evidence and a Search Model

High-frequency trading in a limit order book

How To Model The Yield Curve

Life-insurance-specific optimal investment: the impact of stochastic interest rate and shortfall constraint

Transcription:

Asset Management Contracts and Equilibrium Prices ANDREA M. BUFFA DIMITRI VAYANOS PAUL WOOLLEY Boston University London School of Economics London School of Economics September, 2013

Abstract We study the joint determination of fund managers contracts and equilibrium asset prices. Because of agency frictions, fund investors make managers fees more sensitive to performance and benchmark performance against a market index. In equilibrium, managers underweight expensive stocks that are in high demand by other traders and have endogenously high market betas, and overweight low-demand stocks. Since benchmarking makes it risky for managers to deviate from the index, it exacerbates cross-sectional differences in alphas and the negative relationship between alpha and beta. Moreover, because underweighting the expensive stocks is riskier than overweighting the cheaper ones, benchmarking raises the price of the aggregate stock market and can increase its volatility. Socially optimal contracts involve less benchmarking than privately optimal ones and attenuate the asset-pricing effects of agency frictions.

Motivation Asset management and benchmarking. Most wealth invested in financial assets is managed professionally. Individual investors held only 21.5% of US stocks in 2007 (French 2008). Asset managers risk and return is measured against benchmarks. Questions. How does delegation of asset management affect equilibrium prices? What are consequences of benchmarking? Example: Dot-com bubble. Benchmarking concerns Fund managers bought tech stocks they considered overvalued Bubble was amplified. 3 / 35

This Paper Study joint determination of asset management contracts and equilibrium prices. Prices clear markets given contracts. Contracts (e.g., extent of benchmarking) are not exogenous, but are optimal, within a parametrized class, given prices. Advantages of endogenizing contracts in equilibrium setting: Sharpen analysis of equilibrium effects of delegation. Tighter link between agency frictions and asset prices, through contracts. Address public policy questions. Are privately optimal contracts socially optimal? Do they generate excessive mispricings or volatility? Is there scope for regulation? Continuous-time, infinite-horizon model with multiple stocks. 4 / 35

Main Results: Positive Contracts. Prices. When agency frictions become more severe: Managers compensation becomes more sensitive to performance. There is more use of benchmarking. Betting-against-beta anomaly arises even without agency frictions. Only assumption: Some investors do not hold market portfolio. When agency frictions become more severe: Betting-against-beta anomaly is exacerbated. Beta of low-beta stocks decreases and their positive alpha increases. Beta of high-beta stocks increases and their negative alpha decreases (becomes more negative). More generally, cross-sectional dispersion in alphas increases. Expected return of aggregate market decreases. Cross-sectional effect is asymmetric. Bubbles. Volatility of aggregate market can increase. 5 / 35

Main Results: Normative Privately optimal contracts are not socially optimal. Socially optimal contracts: Are less sensitive to performance and involve less benchmarking. Attenuate asset-pricing effects of agency frictions. 6 / 35

Related Literature Delegated asset management and equilibrium prices. Benchmarks and tracking error: Roll (1992), Brennan (1993), Cuoco-Kaniel (2011), Basak-Pavlova (2013). Flow-performance: Shleifer-Vishny (1997), Berk-Green (2004), Vayanos (2004), He- Krishnamurthy (2012, 2013), Kaniel-Kondor (2013), Vayanos-Woolley (2013). Reputation concerns: Dasgupta-Prat (2008), Dasgupta-Prat-Verardo (2011), Guerrieri-Kondor (2012), Malliaris-Yan (2012). Alternative explanations for asset bubbles. Differences in beliefs and short-sale constraints: Miller (1977), Harrison-Kreps (1978), Scheinkman-Xiong (2003), Hong-Scheinkman-Xiong (2006). Investor sentiment and limited arbitrage: Shleifer-Vishny (1997), Abreu-Brunnermeier (2002, 2003). Leverage constraints: Allen-Gale (2000). Betting against beta. Differences in beliefs and short-sale constraints: Hong-Sraer (2013). Leverage constraints: Black (1972), Frazzini-Pedersen (2013). 7 / 35

Model

Assets Continuous time, infinite horizon. Riskless asset: Exogenous return r. Risky assets (stocks): Dividend flow D it per share of stock i = 1,.., N at time t [0, ) is D it = b i f t + e it, where df t = κ f ( f ft ) dt + σf ft dw ft, de it = κ i (ē i e it ) dt + σ i eit dw it, and (w ft, w 1t,.., w Nt ) are independent Brownian motions. Systematic and idiosyncratic component. Volatility increases with level. (Key) Share price S it of stock i at time t is endogenous: Excess return per share of stock i at time t is dr it D it dt + ds it rs it dt. 9 / 35

Asset Supply and Market Index Effective supply of stocks: θ (θ 1,.., θ N ) shares. Supply available to fund manager. Market index: η (η 1,.., η N ) shares. Used as benchmark. If θ differs from η: Active fund adds value relative to investing in index. (θ dominates η under equilibrium prices since manager must be induced to hold θ.) Manager s tracking error is non-zero. Interpretations. Buy-and-hold investors. Supply of stocks is η. Exogenous buy-and-hold investors hold η θ. Effective supply left for manager is θ. Non-representative index. Supply of stocks is θ. Index does not have market weights. 10 / 35

Agents Fund investor. Invests his wealth with fund manager. Pays manager flow fee dφ t. Maximizes expected utility of intertemporal consumption [ ] E exp( αc t δt)dt. Fund manager. 0 Invests investor s wealth in riskless asset and in stocks. Stock portfolio: z t (z 1t,.., z Nt ) shares. Receives flow fee dφ t. Can invest personal wealth in riskless asset. Maximizes expected utility of intertemporal consumption [ ] E exp( ᾱ c t δt)dt. 0 11 / 35

Agency Frictions At time t manager can take an action m t that: Lowers fund return by 1 2 m2 t dt, Has private benefit Bm tdt, between t and t + dt. Interpretations (reduced form). Low m t is high effort to find more efficient portfolio. Low m t is high effort to reduce operating (e.g., transaction) costs. 12 / 35

Contracts Manager s fee dφ t at time t can depend on Excess return on fund: z tdr t 1 2 m2 t dt, Excess return on market index: ηdr t, with constant coefficients (chosen at t = 0): dφ t = β (z t dr t 12 ) m2t dt γηdr t + ζdt. Optimal contract within this class Optimal choice of (β, γ, ζ) 13 / 35

Manager s Optimization Problem Objective: Choice variables: Consumption c t. Fund s stock portfolio z t. Action m t. Constraints: Budget constraint [ ] E exp( ᾱ c t δt)dt. 0 d W t = r W tdt + dφ t + Bm tdt c tdt. Fee dφ t = β (z tdr t 12 ) m2t dt γηdr t + ζdt. 14 / 35

Investor s Optimization Problem Objective: Choice variables: Consumption c t. Contract (β, γ, ζ). Constraints: Budget constraint [ ] E exp( αc t δt)dt. 0 d W t = dw t = rw tdt + ( z tdr t 1 ) 2 m2 t dt dφ t c tdt. Fee dφ t = β (z tdr t 12 ) m2t dt γηdr t + ζdt. Incentive compatibility (IC) constraint. (z t, m t) solves manager s optimization problem. Individual rationality (IR) constraint. Manager s CE at t = 0 exceeds W 0 + Π, where Π is outside option. 15 / 35

Equilibrium

Equilibrium Concept Definition: Prices S t (S 1t,.., S Nt ) and contract (β, γ, ζ) form an equilibrium if: (i) Given (β, γ, ζ), S t is such that solution to manager s optimization problem is z t = θ (markets clear). (ii) Given S t, (β, γ, ζ) solves investor s optimization problem. 17 / 35

Asset Prices where S it = a 0i + a 1i f t + a 2i e it, a 0i = 1 r ( a1i κ f f + a2i κ i ē i ), b i a 1i =, (r + κf ) 2 + 2rᾱβ(θ γη)bσf 2 1 a 2i =. (r + κi ) 2 + 2rᾱβ(θ i γη i )σi 2 18 / 35

Contract Without Agency Frictions (B = 0). Optimal risk-sharing: β = No benchmarking: γ = 0. α α+ᾱ. With Agency Frictions (B > 0). Manager s fee becomes more sensitive to performance: β > Incentives for effort. Manager is exposed to more risk. Performance is benchmarked against market index: γ > 0. Insulate manager from risk he cannot control. Used to improve risk-sharing. α α+ᾱ. 19 / 35

Supply Effects: Intuition Price Level Price Volatility Stocks in Large Supply LOW LOW Stocks in Small Supply HIGH HIGH Stocks in large effective supply (high θ i ) are cheap (low S it ). Large risk premium to induce manager to absorb large supply. Stocks in large effective supply have less volatile prices (low Var t (ds it )). Volatility is caused by shocks to dividend flow. Following positive shock: 1. Expected dividends increase Price increases. 2. Dividend volatility increases Large increase in risk premium Attenuates price increase. Key property: Dividend volatility increases with dividend level. With normal distributions, supply (θ i ) does not affect volatility. 20 / 35

Betting Against Beta Betting against beta (Black 1972, Frazzini-Pedersen 2013). Low-beta stocks have positive alpha. High-beta stocks have negative alpha. Arises in our model even without agency (or other) frictions. Intuition: Stocks in large effective supply: Are cheap Positive alpha. Have low price volatility Account for small fraction of market movements Low beta. 21 / 35

Numerical Example Two symmetric stocks (N = 2). Same systematic risk (b 1 = b 2). Same idiosyncratic risk (σ 1 = σ 2, ē 1 = ē 2, κ 1 = κ 2). Market index includes one share of each (η 1 = η 2 = 1). Stock 1 is in larger effective supply (θ 1 = 0.8, θ 2 = 0.2). Manager is 50 times more risk averse than investor (ᾱ/α = 50). Graphs: As a function of the severity of the agency friction (horizontal axis). Stock 1: blue. Stock 2: red. Market index: black. Compute moments of dollar returns by dividing corresponding moments of share returns by average share price. 22 / 35

Optimal Contract Sensitivity to Performance Β Benchmarking Γ 0.20 0.25 0.20 0.15 0.15 0.10 0.10 0.05 0.05 0.00 0.00 Manager s fee becomes more sensitive to performance. Performance is benchmarked against market index. 23 / 35

Prices: Level Stock in Large Supply PRICE STOCK 1 40 35 80 75 Stock in Small Supply PRICE STOCK 2 30 70 25 65 20 60 15 55 Benchmarking renders manager less willing to deviate from market index. Supply effects on price levels are amplified. Stock 1, in large effective supply, becomes cheaper. Stock 2, in small effective supply, becomes more expensive. 24 / 35

Prices: Volatility 7 Stock in Large Supply PRICE VOLATILITY STOCK 1 22 Stock in Small Supply PRICE VOLATILITY STOCK 2 6 20 5 18 16 4 14 3 12 10 Supply effects on price volatilities are amplified. Consider positive shock to dividend flow of stock 2, in small effective supply. Dividend volatility increases Manager becomes more eager to buy stock 2 to reduce risk of deviating from market index Large decrease in risk premium Price increase is amplified. 25 / 35

Betting Against Beta CAPM BETA CAPM ALPHA 1.2 1.0 0.8 0.6 20 15 10 0.4 5 0.2 0 0.0 Arises in our model even without agency (or other) frictions. Intuition. Stocks in large effective supply: Are cheap Positive alpha. Have low price volatility Account for small fraction of market movements Low beta. Supply effects on alpha and beta discrepancies are amplified. 26 / 35

Aggregate Market: Price Level PRICE MARKET 4.7 EXCESS RETURN MARKET 96 4.6 95 94 4.5 93 4.4 92 4.3 Benchmarking renders manager less willing to deviate from market index. Stock 1 (large effective supply) becomes cheaper and less volatile. Stock 2 (small effective supply) becomes more expensive and more volatile. Underweighting stocks in small effective supply is riskier for manager than overweighting stocks in large effective supply. Former stocks account for larger fraction of market movements. Aggregate market goes up. (Bubbles) 27 / 35

Aggregate Market: Volatility RETURN VOLATILITY MARKET 22 20 18 16 Volatility of aggregate market increases. However: Result reverses for large levels of systematic risk relative to idiosyncratic risk. 28 / 35

Asset Correlations ASSET CORRELATION 0.25 0.20 0.15 0.10 0.05 Correlation of stock returns decreases. Idiosyncratic shocks become more relevant for asset prices. 29 / 35

Normative Analysis

Social Planner s Problem Are privately optimal contracts socially optimal? Social planner chooses contract (β, γ, ζ ): To maximize sum of certainty equivalents of investor and manager. Internalizing how contract affects prices. Contract chosen by social planner: (β, γ, ζ ) arg max CE 0 ( β, γ, St (β, γ) ) + CE 0 ( β, γ, St (β, γ) ). 31 / 35

Socially Optimal Contract Sensitivity to Performance Β Benchmarking Γ 0.20 0.25 0.20 0.15 0.15 0.10 0.10 0.05 0.05 0.00 0.00 Relatively to privately optimal contracts, socially optimal ones: Are less sensitive to performance. Involve less benchmarking. 32 / 35

Prices: Level, Volatility and Correlation PRICE STOCK 1 PRICE STOCK 2 40 80 35 75 30 70 25 65 20 60 15 55 7 PRICE VOLATILITY STOCK 1 PRICE VOLATILITY STOCK 2 ASSET CORRELATION 22 6 20 0.25 5 4 3 18 16 14 12 0.20 0.15 0.10 10 0.05 Socially optimal contracts attenuate asset-pricing effects of agency frictions. 33 / 35

Aggregate Market: Level and Volatility PRICE MARKET 4.7 EXCESS RETURN MARKET RETURN VOLATILITY MARKET 96 4.6 22 95 94 93 92 4.5 4.4 4.3 20 18 16 Socially optimal contracts attenuate asset-pricing effects of agency frictions. Smaller rise of aggregate market. 34 / 35

Concluding Remarks Study joint determination of asset management contracts and equilibrium prices. New asset-pricing results: Betting against beta. Asymmetric cross-sectional effect of benchmarking Aggregate market. Open door for public-policy analysis of asset management contracts. Do existing contracts have adverse price effects? Should they be improved (e.g., design of benchmarks, risk measures)? Recent proposals by G30, European Commission, etc. 35 / 35