Measuring Pro-Poor Growth in Non-Income Dimensions

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Measuring Pro-Poor Growth in Non-Income Dimensions"

Transcription

1 World Development Vol. 36, No. 6, pp. 7, 8 Ó 8 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved 35-75X/$ - see front matter doi:.6/j.worlddev.7..9 Measuring Pro-Poor Growth in Non-Income Dimensions MELANIE GROSSE, KENNETH HARTTGEN and STEPHAN KLASEN * University of Göttingen, Germany Summary. Current concepts and measures of pro-poor growth are entirely focused on the income dimension of well-being. This neglects non-income dimensions of poverty as well as the multidimensionality of poverty and well-being. In this paper, we extend the pro-poor growth toolbox to individual and composite measures of non-income achievements. In particular, we apply growth incidence curves, the Ravallion Chen pro-poor growth rate and the poverty-equivalent growth rate to a range of non-income indicators such as education, mortality, vaccinations, stunting, and a multidimensional well-being measure. We are thereby able to study improvements in these dimensions of well-being at various points of the distribution of those indicators as well as at various points of the income distribution. This way we can determine whether improvements in non-income indicators were pro-poor in an absolute or relative sense, and whether they benefited the income poor more than others. We illustrate this empirically for Bolivia during Ó 8 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved. Key words pro-poor growth, multidimensionality of poverty, growth incidence curve, povertyequivalent growth rate, Bolivia. INTRODUCTION Pro-poor growth has recently become a central issue for researchers and policy makers, especially in the context of reaching the millennium development goals (MDGs). The various proposals to measure pro-poor growth have also allowed a much more detailed assessment of progress on reducing poverty as they explicitly examine growth along the entire income distribution. However, a central shortcoming of current pro-poor growth concepts and measures is that to date they have been completely focused on the income dimension of poverty, thus ignoring critical non-income aspects of well-being which are also central to the MDGs. As is well known, however, a reduction in income poverty does not guarantee a reduction in non-income dimensions of poverty, such as education or health. In this context, Kakwani and Pernia () note that it would be futile if one operationalizes poverty reduction via pro-poor growth using just one single indicator because poverty is a multidimensional phenomenon, and thus pro-poor growth should also be understood as a multidimensional phenomenon. While non-income indicators of well-being and the multidimensionality of poverty have recently received more and more attention in poverty measurement no attempts have been made to date to measure pro-poor growth using non-income indicators. The aim of this paper is to extend the toolbox of pro-poor growth measurement to individual non-income dimensions and composite measures of well-being, including central capabilities in the areas of health, education, and nutrition which, following Sen (988), are central outcomes of well-being and also included in the MDGs. We do this by extending the growth incidence curve (GIC) by Ravallion and Chen (3) * The authors would like to thank Amartya Sen, Ravi Kanbur, Sonia Bhalotra, and Walter Zucchini and the participants at workshops in Göttingen and sessions at the Spring Meeting for Young Economists in Geneva, the Society for the Study of Economic Inequality in Palma, the Research Committee on Development Economics in Kiel, and the WIDER Project Meeting of A- ssessing and Forecasting Progress in MDGs in Helsinki for helpful comments and discussion. Final revision accepted: October 5, 7.

2 WORLD DEVELOPMENT and related pro-poor growth measures to nonincome indicators and call our approach non-income growth incidence curves (NIGICs). We illustrate this approach using micro-survey data for Bolivia during We distinguish between relating growth in non-income achievements to the distribution of achievement in that non-income indicator and relating growth in non-income achievements to the distribution of income. While the former will allow us to study the distributional pattern of improvements in the non-income dimension, the latter provides insights about how far the income poor have benefited from improvements in non-income dimensions of well-being, thus complementing standard incidence analyses. In addition to investigating growth rates, we also investigate absolute changes of the non-income indicators. For our Bolivian illustration, we find that growth was relatively pro-poor both in the income and in the non-income dimension, but results are much less clear when absolute changes are considered and when changes in non-income achievement are related to the income distribution. The paper is organized as follows. In Section, we describe pro-poor growth measurement and in Section 3 our extension to non-income dimensions. The empirical illustration for Bolivia is contained in Section, and we conclude in Section 5.. METHODOLOGY (a) Defining pro-poor growth Categorizing the different definitions of propoor growth, we use three definitions of propoor growth in this paper: weak absolute pro-poor growth, relative pro-poor growth, and strong absolute pro-poor growth (see also Klasen, 8a). 3 Pro-poor growth in the weak absolute sense means that the growth rates are above for the poor. Pro-poor growth in the relative sense means that the growth rates of the poor are higher than the average growth rates; thus relative inequality falls (i.e., some indicator considering the relative gap between the rich and the poor falls). Pro-poor growth in the strong absolute sense requires that absolute increases of the poor are larger than the average, thus implying that absolute inequality falls (i.e., some measures considering the absolute gap between the rich and the poor falls; see, e.g., Klasen, 8a). Note that these definitions are sensitive to the definition of the poor, that is they depend on the poverty line. In the empirical illustration, we will use the poverty lines used in Bolivia. Also note that here we gloss over an aggregation issue as it may be the case that, for example, for only some of the poor growth is above, while for others it is not. Thus, there may be cases where we are unable to classify the episodes of growth using these definitions. The pro-poor growth measures described below, however, implicitly deal with these aggregation issues and come to a definitive judgment about the pro-poorness of a particular growth episode. They do so, however, in different ways, which has been the subject of some discussion. 5 The absolute definition is obviously the strictest definition of pro-poor growth and the hardest to be met as shown empirically by White and Anderson (). This is why most empirical and policy research has focused on the weak absolute and relative definition (OECD, 6). But this ignores that decreases in relative inequality might be and often are accompanied by increases in absolute inequality which is seen as undesirable by many and can be an important source of social tension (e.g., Atkinson & Brandolini, ; Duclos & Wodon, ; Klasen, ). Conversely, growth that is associated with falling absolute inequality would be particularly pro-poor and, therefore, it is useful to consider this strong absolute concept as well. As we argue in the following section, this is particularly important when examining pro-poor growth in the non-income dimension of poverty where even pro-poor growth in the relative definition might not be seen as sufficiently pro-poor. (b) The GIC A nice way to illustrate the definitions is to use growth incidence curves (GICs), which are also a useful visual tool for the assessment of the distributional pattern of growth. The GIC (Ravallion & Chen, 3) shows the mean growth rate g t in achievements (here incomes y) at each centile p of the distribution between two points in time, t and t. The GIC links the growth rates of different percentiles and is given by GIC ¼ g t ðpþ ¼ y tðpþ y t ðpþ : ðþ By comparing the two periods, the GIC plots the population centiles (from to ranked by income) against the annual per capita

3 MEASURING PRO-POOR GROWTH IN NON-INCOME DIMENSIONS 3 growth rate in income of the respective centiles. If the GIC is above for all poor centiles (g t (p) > for all p), then it indicates weak absolute pro-poor growth. If the GIC is negatively sloped throughout it indicates relative pro-poor growth. 6 Starting from the GIC, Ravallion and Chen (3) define the pro-poor growth rate (PPGR) as the area under the GIC up to the headcount ratio H, which has a direct relation to poverty reduction if one uses the Watts index as the relevant poverty measure. The PPGR is formally expressed by PPGR ¼ g p t ¼ Z H t g H t ðpþdp; t ðþ which is equivalent to the mean of the growth rates of the poor up to the headcount. In order to determine whether growth was pro-poor according to the relative definition, one compares the PPGR with the growth rate in mean (GRIM). The GRIM is defined by GRIM ¼ c t ¼ l t ; ð3þ l t where l is mean income. If the PPGR exceeds the GRIM, growth is declared to be pro-poor in the relative sense. Examining pro-poor growth in the strong absolute sense one has to concentrate on the absolute changes in the income of the population centiles between the two periods. We define the absolute GIC by GIC absolute ¼ c t ðpþ ¼y t ðpþ y t ðpþ; ðþ which shows the absolute changes for each centile. By comparing the two periods, the absolute GIC plots the population centiles against the per capita change in income of the respective centile. If the absolute GIC is negatively sloped it indicates strong absolute pro-poor growth. Starting from the absolute GIC we define pro-poor change (PPCH) as the area under the absolute GIC up to the headcount H. The PPCH is formally expressed by PPCH ¼ c p t ¼ X H t c t ðpþ; ð5þ H t which is equivalent to the mean of the changes of the poor up to the headcount. We compare the PPCH with the change in mean (CHIM), which is defined by CHIM ¼ d t ¼ l t l t : ð6þ If the PPCH exceeds the CHIM, growth is declared to be pro-poor in the strong absolute sense. An alternative measure of pro-poor growth is the poverty-equivalent growth rate (PEGR) proposed by Kakwani and Son (6). The PEGR is the growth rate that would have delivered the same poverty reduction if income distribution had remained unchanged. It can be calculated for all the FGT poverty measures (headcount, depth, and severity). Applied to the poverty headcount it is calculated as PEGR ¼ PEH GEH GRIM; ð7þ where PEH is the total poverty elasticity of poverty headcount H with respect to a particular growth episode and GEH is the pure growth elasticity of poverty headcount H with respect to that growth episode (i.e., holding inequality constant), averaged over the two time paths (i.e., a forward headcount in the second year if all incomes had grown by the average income growth rate from the first to the second year and a backward headcount in the first year if all incomes had shrunk by the same rate from the second to the first year) 7 multiplied with the annualized growth rate (GRIM). If the PEGR is higher than the GRIM, growth was pro-poor in the relative definition PRO-POOR GROWTH IN NON-IN- COME DIMENSIONS (a) Concept We begin by extending the GIC to non-income dimensions. The calculation of the NI- GICs broadly follows the concept of the GIC. Instead of income (y) we apply formulas () (7) to selected non-income indicators to measure pro-poor growth directly via outcomebased welfare indicators. Thus, the NIGIC measures pro-poor growth in a non-income sense, for example, the improvement of the health status or the educational level between two periods for each centile of the distribution. We calculate the NIGIC in two different ways. We call the first way the unconditional NIGIC, in which we rank the individuals by each respective non-income variable and generate the population centiles based on this ranking. For example, using average years of

4 WORLD DEVELOPMENT schooling of adult household members, the poorest centile is now the education-poorest one with the lowest average household educational attainment. We call the second way conditional NIGIC, in which we rank the individuals by income and calculate the growth of non-income achievements for these income percentiles. Since the income-poorest group might not be the education-poorest group at the same time, these two ways of studying pro-poor growth will likely yield different results (see below). Conceptually, both ways of calculating the NIGIC are of relevance for policy making. The unconditional NIGIC shows the non-income distributional pattern of improvements of non-income dimensions of well-being. This is central for monitoring progress in non-income dimensions of well-being. It allows answers to questions such as: Have the education poor benefited disproportionately from improvements in education? Have those who were most lacking in nutrition been able to improve their nutritional status the most? In contrast, the conditional NIGIC allows an assessment of the income distributional pattern of improvements in non-income dimensions of well-being. This is a very useful supplement to standard benefit incidence analysis, commonly undertaken as part of public expenditure reviews and poverty assessments in developing countries. Standard benefit incidence studies typically analyze the impact of public spending by calculating shares of the total spending going to each centile and comparing the shares of the income poorest with the income-richest centile (see, e.g., Lanjouw & Ravallion, 998; Roberts, 3; Van de Walle, 998; Van de Walle & Nead, 995). With the conditional NI- GIC it is now possible to analyze how progress in a particular aspect of human welfare (e.g. health or education) is distributed across the income distribution. For example, it provides an instrument to assess if public social spending programs have reached the targeted incomepoorest population groups and if the public resources are effectively allocated and used. In this respect, the conditional NIGIC can be referred to as an outcome-oriented incidence analysis. As with the income measure, we generate GICs not only for relative improvements, but also for absolute improvements. In fact, we believe that tracking absolute improvements is particularly relevant in non-income dimensions for two reasons: First, it appears more usual and intuitive to consider absolute gaps in achievements (e.g. the literature on longevity and education gaps between the rich and poor usually reports absolute not relative gaps). Consequently, it seems harder to argue that a % growth in education for the education poor compared to 5% education growth for the education rich was pro-poor if the poor started with year of education (i.e. now have. years) and the rich with (i.e. now have.5). This is also related to the more ordinal character of some of the non-income indicators which make relative changes hard to interpret (see below). Second, the importance of absolute progress in non-income achievements would also be consistent with Sen s capability approach. As he emphasizes in Sen (98), poverty in the capability space should be considered using absolute achievements while often the means to achieve it (such as incomes) can be considered in a relative dimension. After constructing the GICs which track absolute and relative progress, we can then calculate the rates of pro-poor growth (PPGR) using the relative NIGICs, the PEGR, and PPCHs using the absolute NIGICs and compare each to the GRIM or CHIM. (b) Specification of the non-income indicators We calculate the unconditional and conditional NIGIC for education, health, nutrition, and for a composite welfare index (CWI) as described below. We are working with DHS data for Bolivia from the years 989 and 998 that do not contain information on income or consumption due to its focus on demographics, health, and fertility. However, in our DHS data set, we use simulated incomes based on a dynamic cross-survey micro-simulation methodology proposed by Grosse, Klasen, and Spatz (5). 9 The basic idea of this simulation methodology is the following. The authors use two kinds of surveys: first, the DHS (of 989 and 998) and, second, the Bolivian household surveys (the nd EIH of 989 and the ECH of 999). Then they estimate an income correlation in the household survey, apply the coefficients to the DHS, and predict, that is, simulate, incomes in the DHS. For each non-income indicator, we identify alternative variables to capture particular aspects of the non-income dimension in question. For education, we specify eight different vari-

5 MEASURING PRO-POOR GROWTH IN NON-INCOME DIMENSIONS 5 ables. We calculate average years of schooling for all adult household members and for males and females separately. Age plays an important role when analyzing changes in nonincome indicators, especially for education. In particular, not much improvement in education can be expected among the adult population beyond usual school-going age (e.g. the education of 3 -year olds in 989 should not be very different from the education of 5-year olds in 999). To avoid misleading conclusion from potential low improvements, we therefore also restrict the sample to women aged between and 3 as only this age group is likely to have experienced a change in their educational achievement (the 3-year olds in 999 represent a new cohort of women who were educated later than the other cohorts). In addition, we calculate the maximal education per household (instead of the average) for all adults, males, females, and females aged between and 3. The idea here is that it might be sufficient that one household member is well educated to generate income for the whole household and to invest in education of other household members (i.e., intra-household externalities) (Basu & Foster, 998). For health, we specified three different variables. We calculate infant survival rates of children aged under 5 years and also for children aged under year. Furthermore, we take the average vaccinations of children aged between and 5 per household, with a maximum of eight possible vaccinations for each child. 3 The vaccination rate is a variable that represents access to health care and preventive medicines. A similar variable has, for example, been used in the monitoring of the health sector reform project in Bolivia in 999 (Montes, 3). For nutrition, we use stunting z-scores as the variable that measures chronic undernutrition for children aged between and 5 years. The stunting z-scores are defined as the difference of height at a certain age and the median of the reference population for height at that age divided by the standard deviation of the reference population. It takes values between approximately 6 and 6, where values below are considered as being moderately undernourished and below 3 as being severely undernourished (see, e.g., Klasen, 8b). Problematic might be that the z-score contains a lot of genetic noise in the sense that, for example, a low z-score interpreted as being undernourished might simply appear because the parents are genetically short but the child is small but well nourished and vice versa. Apart from studying individual non-income achievements, we also want to study progress in multidimensional non-income achievements using a CWI. Here, we follow the methodology of the human development index (HDI) to address the problem of difference scales of the variables (UN, 3). Each variable that enters the index is normalized to be between and in subtracting the individual value from the minimum value observed in the data set divided by the range X n CWI ¼ individual n min : ð8þ n max min i¼ The CWI is constructed by simply averaging the selected variable scores. It includes four of the above explained variables: average education of all adult household members, stunting z-scores, under 5 survival, and average vaccinations. As not all variables are available for all households (e.g., health and nutrition variables are only available for households who have children in the required age group), we calculate the CWI for two different samples. The first sample, called small sample, is the one for which all variables are available for all households. This reduces the sample size enormously (in 989, e.g., from 6,53 to,36 households) and, more importantly, in a non-random fashion. 5 The second sample, called big sample, includes all households, but the index is averaged over fewer variables for those households which do not have data for nutrition and/or health variables. The advantage of creating the CWI based on the big sample is the higher number of observations but the disadvantage is that the results for some centiles are driven by very few or only one variable. The smaller sample has fewer observations but contains for all households the same number of variables. For both the small and the big sample, we in addition augment the indices by also including simulated income as a fourth indicator. (c) Limitations of the indicators While we show below that these indicators yield important insights, we want to highlight a number of conceptual and empirical limitations of, and potential objections to, extending pro-poor growth measurement to non-income dimensions of well-being.

6 6 WORLD DEVELOPMENT The first limitation relates to the interpretation of the growth rates using the NIGIC, where we interpret an ordinal relation in a cardinal fashion. Examining an ordinally scaled variable such as years of schooling, one can say that 6 years of schooling is better than 3 years but one cannot be sure that the household is twice as well-educated. 6 This ordinal scaling leads to two different kinds of interpretation problems. First, averaging an ordinally scaled variable across household members leads to the problem that such averages can be misleading. 7 In order to partially address this issue, we additionally consider the individual educational attainment (instead of only the average of the household) and the gender gap in education within households. Second, concerning increases in the years of schooling, just comparing growth rates might be misleading. For example, Table shows for average education an increase of 8% for the nd decile compared to 6% of the 9th decile which might be overstating the improvement for the poor because the years of schooling of the poor increase from.3 to.37 years of schooling and those of the non-poor from.73 to.3. We try to address this problem in calculating absolute NIGIC and PPCHs. However, even when we use absolute changes which equal approximately, a further question remains open. An increase of.6 years of schooling of the nd decile might be less beneficial, because perhaps the persons are still more or less illiterate, compared to the increase of.7 years of schooling in the 9th decile, which might mean completing secondary schooling and getting a degree. Third, many of the non-income indicators are bounded above, that is, there are firm or likely upper limits on such achievements. One hundred percent survival in the first year is the upper limit for health, more than 8 or 9 years of education is very rare, more than eight vaccinations is not recommended, done, or measured, etc. This generates the problem (and indeed is the case in Bolivia) that some households have reached the upper limit and further growth is not possible or very hard to achieve. It generates the further problem that inequality in such indicators is typically low when a significant share of households has reached the upper limit. This may generate the misleading impression that there is no longer any inequality to be concerned about. One way to address this issue would be to transform our achievement variables in a way that reflects the greater difficulty to achieve further improvements as one approaches the upper bound, such as a percentage reduction of the absolute gap to the upper bound or an improvement index proposed by Kakwani (993). But as we are solely interested in the distributional pattern of welfare and welfare improvements, not in the difficulty of achieving them, we are refraining from making such adjustments here. If, due to the fact that the education- or income-rich already have close to the maximum possible education and thus any further growth in education is bound to reduce inequality in years of schooling, we believe that it is proper from a well-being assessment to report this decline in inequality in years of schooling. This does not, of course, mean that there are no further educational inequalities to consider. Our indicator purely focuses on the quantity of education and it may well be that educational quality continues to differ greatly, an issue that we cannot address here due to the lack of data on the quality of education. 8 The fourth type of problem in comparing relative changes relates to the stunting z-score. In our data sets, it ranges roughly from 6 to6. Relative changes in the stunting z-score cannot be calculated because of the coexistence of negative, positive and values in the variable range. For example, how to compare the relative improvement from to with an improvement from to from the year 989 to 998? We reduce this problem by transforming the z-score in such a way that all values are positive, that means by adding the minimum value of both data sets (in our case 5.89) to each z-score to get a range of only positive numbers. Another limitation is the problem of weighting which we illustrate with the example of child mortality. 9 For example, comparing two households A and B where A has one child and B has children the households should be weighted differently when in both households one child dies. Household A has a child mortality rate of % whereas B of only %, but one may argue that both deaths are equally lamentable and should be considered equally important. But any weighting would, however, be quite arbitrary and induce difficulties in justifying it with economic or welfare-theoretical judgments. Keeping this critical issue in mind we use unweighted child survival rates. Another limitation calculating the NIGIC in some contexts is that some non-income indicators do not vary much between households. This holds especially for under 5 and under

7 Table. Non-income indicators and related variables (unconditional, Bolivia, 989 and 998) Mean : Gini Mean of deciles (unconditional), 989 Income Education Average education Average education of respondents n.d..5 Average education of respondents ( 3) Average education of partners n.d.. Maximum education Maximum education of respondents n.d..5 Maximum education of respondents ( 3) Maximum education of partners n.d.. Individual education n.d..7 Health Under 5 child survival rate (%) Under child survival rate (%) Average vaccination per child (age P ) Nutrition Stunting z-score n.d..9 (continued on next page) MEASURING PRO-POOR GROWTH IN NON-INCOME DIMENSIONS 7

8 Table (continued) Mean : Gini Mean of deciles (unconditional), 998 Income Education Average education Average education of respondents n.d.. Average education of respondents ( 3) Average education of partners Maximum education Maximum education of respondents n.d.. Maximum education of respondents ( 3) Maximum education of partners Individual education Health Under 5 child survival rate (%) Under child survival rate (%) Average vaccination per child (age P ) Nutrition Stunting z-score n.d..6 Notes: The explanation for the variables is the following. Income: Real household income per capita in Bolivianos per month (CPI of 995 = ). Education: All variables for education are measured in average single years per adult married household members. Respondents and partners are only couples, for which the respondent knows the education of her partner. Health: Under 5 () survival are estimated with life table estimations and we take the sample of children born (5) years prior to the sample. Survival rates are averaged over the household. Vaccinations: Average vaccinations of the children in the household older than, where the possible vaccinations are three against polio, three against DPT, one against measles, and one against BCG. Nutrition: Stunting z-score of the last born child of each respondent (averaged over the household) with a child defined to be stunted if her z-score is below. Source: Own calculations. 8 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

9 Table. Non-income indicators and related variables (conditional, Bolivia, 989 and 998) Mean : Mean of the deciles (conditional), 989 Income Education Average education Average education of respondents Average education of respondents ( 3) Average education of partners Maximum education Maximum education of respondents Maximum education of respondents ( 3) Maximum education of partners Individual education Health Under 5 child survival rate (%) Under child survival rate (%) Average vaccination per child (age P ) Nutrition Stunting z-score n.d. (continued on next page) MEASURING PRO-POOR GROWTH IN NON-INCOME DIMENSIONS 9

10 Table (continued) Mean : Mean of the deciles (conditional), 998 Income Education Average education Average education of respondents Average education of respondents ( 3) Average education of partners Maximum education Maximum education of respondents Maximum education of respondents ( 3) Maximum education of partners Individual education Health Under 5 child survival rate (%) Under child survival rate (%) Average vaccination per child (age P ) Nutrition Stunting z-score n.d. Notes: The explanation for the variables is the following. Income: Real household income per capita in Bolivianos per month (CPI of 995 = ). Education: All variables for education are measured in average single years per adult married household members. Respondents and partners are only couples, for which the respondent knows the education of her partner. Health: Under 5 () survival are estimated with life table estimations and we take the sample of children born (5) years prior to the sample. Survival rates are averaged over the household. Vaccinations: Average vaccinations of the children in the household older than, where the possible vaccinations are three against polio, three against DPT, one against measles, and one against BCG. Nutrition: Stunting z-score of the last born child of each respondent (averaged over the household) with a child defined to be stunted if her z-score is below. Source: Own calculations. 3 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

11 MEASURING PRO-POOR GROWTH IN NON-INCOME DIMENSIONS 3 survival which is very low in Bolivia at the household level. For both years, Table shows that from the 3rd or th decile upward, the maximum value % survival is already reached in both years, so that no improvement is possible any more. This translates into growth rates of, so that the unconditional NI- GIC becomes flat and takes the value of from the 3rd or th decile onward. The problem of flat curves always arises when the variable values are bounded above (as, e.g., a maximum of 9 years of schooling or eight vaccinations). In these cases, it is more interesting to examine the conditional NIGIC, in which we link the survival rates and vaccination to income. Here, low or variation is less problematic than for the unconditional NIGIC because the variables are ranked by income. As Table and all figures show there is no flat part any more. Now we generate interesting information regarding the changes on the non-income indicators when ranked according to their income situation and how improvements are distributed.. EMPIRICAL ILLUSTRATION (a) Inequality in non-income dimensions of wellbeing Bolivia is one of the countries with a very unequal income distribution in Latin America. We find high and persisting income inequality as measured with the Gini coefficient that falls from.56 in 989 to.5 in 998 (Table ). This high inequality is also reflected in the high and only slightly falling : ratio, that is mean incomes in the th, divided by mean incomes in the st decile. Turning from inequality to growth we find that all deciles increased their incomes. Especially in the 99s, Bolivia experienced relatively high growth rates (which also were pro-poor in urban and rural areas). However, Bolivia was and is one of the poorest countries of the region, and the positive economic trend has reversed since 999 combined with some episodes of social and political turmoil. For social indicators such as life expectancy or literacy, Bolivia used to show much worse outcomes compared to other countries in the region. However, there have been notable and sustained improvements in many social indicators since the late 98s which continued to improve during the recent economic slowdown (Klasen et al., 7). Tables and show achievements in income and non-income dimensions of well-being in Bolivia for 989 and 998 sorting households by the respective non-income achievement in Table, and by incomes in Table. We also calculate Gini coefficients and : decile ratios. Table 3 does the same for the composite indicator and Table reports the respective pro-poor growth measures. Table 3. Deciles of the composite welfare index (Bolivia, 989 and 998) Mean : Gini Mean of the deciles (unconditional), 989 Composite welfare index Small sample Big sample Mean of the deciles (unconditional), 998 Composite welfare index Small sample Big sample Mean of the deciles (conditional), 989 Composite welfare index Small sample Big sample Mean of the deciles (conditional), 998 Composite welfare index Small sample Big sample Notes: The composite welfare index includes average education of married household members, under 5 survival rate, average vaccination per child, and stunting. Source: Own calculations.

12 Table. Mean growth rates, mean absolute changes, pro-poor growth rates, poverty equivalent growth rates, and absolute pro-poor changes (Bolivia, 989 and 998) NIGIC Poverty equivalent NIGIC Unconditional Conditional Growth rate Unconditional Condtional GRIM PPGR moderate PPGR extreme PPGR moderate PPGR extreme PEGR moderate PEGR extreme CHIM PPCH moderate PPCH extreme PPCH moderate PPCH extreme Income Education Average education Average education of all respondents Average education of respondents ( 3) Average education of partners Maximal education Maximum education of all respondents Maximum education of respondents ( 3) Maximum education of partners Individual education Health Under 5 child survival rate (%) Under child survival rate (%) Average vaccination per child (age P ) Nutrition Stunting z-score Composite welfare index (CWI) Small sample Big sample Notes: For the explanation of the variables, see Table. We are using two poverty lines. The moderate poverty line leads to an income headcount of 77 and the extreme poverty line to an income headcount of 56, which we also use for the non-income indicators. GRIM: Growth rate in mean. PPGR: Pro-poor growth rate. PEGR: Poverty equivalent growth rate. CHIM: Change in mean. PPCH: Pro-poor change. Changes are for the entire period and not annualized. Source: Own calculations. 3 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

13 MEASURING PRO-POOR GROWTH IN NON-INCOME DIMENSIONS 33 The Ginis for education variables are all in the range of. and fall between 989 and 998. As shown in Table, this is related to the fact that the education rich already are quite close to the upper bound so that inequality in the years of schooling is bound to be smaller and falling over time, as the poor are catching up. As shown by Thomas, Wang, and Fan (), educational Ginis are much larger in African countries (in fact larger than typical income Ginis) where the majority of people have close to no education, and only the better off are benefitting from educational expansion (see also below). Interesting to note is that the highest Ginis exist for the group of all (female) respondents, both for average and maximal education indicating larger educational gaps among females than males. These findings are also reflected in the : ratio. The conditional deciles in Table also show that the level of schooling increases with increasing income for all educational variables, but the : ratio is much lower than in the unconditional case. This suggests an imperfect correlation between education and income poverty. We also find that there has been an improvement for all educational variables in all deciles for both the unconditional and the conditional cases during , a rather encouraging finding (Tables and ). The extremely low Ginis for the under and under 5 survival rates can be explained by the low overall incidence of child mortality in Bolivia at the household level. For both age groups, child mortality is about %. The conditional deciles in Table indicate that the risk of child mortality is higher for the income-poor compared to the income-rich. For vaccination, we find only little improvements over time for the lower deciles and also for the higher deciles, which is also due to the fact that the best-vaccinated deciles had only limited room for improvements. The inequality of the stunting z-score is relatively low and falls slightly. Malnutrition decreases with an increasing position in the income distribution, but the differences for the income deciles are lower but clearly existing. The CWI reflects the findings from above where the Gini coefficients decrease for the selected variables (Table 3). For the CWI, the Gini coefficient is higher for the big sample than for the small sample. (b) GICs and pro-poor growth Figure shows the relative and absolute GIC for income. The relative GIC plots the annual Percentile GIC (lhs) 95% CI upper bound (lhs) 95% CI lower bound (lhs) Absolute GIC 95% CI upper bound abs. 95% CI lower bound abs. Figure. GIC (relative and absolute). Source: Own calculations.

14 3 WORLD DEVELOPMENT growth rates in monthly household per capita income for each household of the distribution. The absolute GIC plots absolute increases in real Bolivianos for the whole period for each percentile. Included are (also in all other figures) the bootstraped 95% confidence intervals and the moderate and extreme poverty headcounts for 989 of 77% and 56%, respectively. As can be seen from the position and slope of the GIC, income growth was pro-poor in the weak absolute and relative sense since the curve is above for all and negatively sloped for nearly all percentiles. However, as expected, we do not find strong absolute pro-poor growth since the absolute GIC is positively sloped meaning that absolute increases in income were much higher for the non-poor than for the poor. The confidence intervals are extremely tight so that we can be quite confident about the statistical validity of our findings. Figure a shows the relative and absolute unconditional NIGIC for average education per household. Figure b shows for this variable the relative and absolute conditional (smoothed ) NIGIC. Whereas for the unconditional NIGIC the growth rates and absolute changes are shown in percentiles ( ), for the conditional NI- GIC the growth rates and absolute changes are shown in vintiles (, each comprising 5%). The reason for using vintiles instead for percentiles for the conditional NIGIC is to get a higher number of observations for each group when households are ranked by income. Even with income vintiles, the confidence intervals are much larger, due to the high heterogeneity of non-income achievements and growth rates thereof within each income vintile. For the unconditional NIGIC, we find pronounced weak absolute as well as relative propoor growth. 3 The relative pro-poorness of average education is also reflected by comparing the PPGR with the GRIM where the PPGR for moderate poverty is 3.89% and the PPGR for extreme poverty is.88, both much higher than the GRIM of.8% (Table ). The PEGR by Kakwani and Son (6) applied to education is also larger than the GRIM for all education indicators, when the extreme poverty line is used, supporting a relatively pro-poor pattern of expansion of education. For some of the education indicators, this is not the case when the moderate poverty line is used, suggesting that differences in the aggregation procedure inherent in these two pro-poor growth measures have some effects on the finding of pro-poor growth. The conditional NIGIC is more volatile than the unconditional NIGIC and also shows weak Percentile NIGIC unconditional (lhs) 95% CI upper b. (lhs) 95% CI lower b. (lhs) NIGIC uncon. abs. 95% CI upper b. abs. 95% CI lower b. abs. Figure a. Unconditional NIGIC for average education (relative and absolute). Source: Own calculations.

15 MEASURING PRO-POOR GROWTH IN NON-INCOME DIMENSIONS Vintile NIGIC conditional (lhs) 95% CI upper b. (lhs) 95% CI lower b. (lhs) NIGIC con. abs. 95% CI upper b. abs. 95% CI lower b. abs. Figure b. Conditional NIGIC for average education (relative and absolute). Source: Own calculations. absolute and relative pro-poor growth but to a lower extent. Thus, the conditional NIGIC shows that the income-poor have experienced slightly higher educational growth than the average. This is also reflected in the higher PPGR (.% for moderate and.% for extreme poverty) compared to the GRIM (.8%). However, the wide confidence interval raises some doubts about the statistical significance of these findings. We do not find strong absolute pro-poor growth for the absolute unconditional NIGIC for education as the slope of the absolute curves in Figures and 3 are not negative, but even positive for the poorest deciles. This is quite interesting, because it puts the findings of the unconditional NIGIC in Figure a in perspective where we have found high relative pro-poor growth for the first three deciles. This seemingly contradictory finding is due to the fact that the high percentage growth rates for the lower deciles are due to the very low base in 989. The absolute conditional NIGIC is virtually flat, meaning that the income-poor have not been able to improve their educational attainment by more than the average. These findings are also reflected in comparing the PPCH with the CHIM. As Table shows, the unconditional PPCH is still larger than the CHIM, however, only slightly: the average years of schooling only increased by.8 years in the mean, by.3 years for the moderately poor, and.3 for the extremely poor. For the absolute conditional changes and for both poverty lines, the CHIM is higher than the PPCH of.. To take into account also possible intrahousehold inequalities Figures 3a and 3b show the unconditional and conditional NIGIC for individual education in single years. Both figures reflect the picture that was found for average education per household showing relative pro-poor growth both for the unconditional and for the conditional case. Another way to look at intra-household inequalities is to look at the gender gaps in education within households. For this purpose, we calculate the female minus male education in the households (in years of education). Ranking the households by the gap, we plot in Figure the unconditional and conditional absolute change in the gender gap. We find that the intra-household gender gaps were reduced for nearly all household except those between the th and the th percentile. Again, especially households in the middle of the distribution showed the strongest reductions. When looking at the conditional NIGIC, we find no clear trend meaning that the reduction in

16 36 WORLD DEVELOPMENT Percentile NIGIC unconditional (lhs) 95% CI upper b. (lhs) 95% CI lower b. (lhs) NIGIC uncon. abs. 95% CI upper b. abs. 95% CI lower b. abs. Figure 3a. Unconditional NIGIC for individual education (relative and absolute). Source: Own calculations Vintile NIGIC conditional (lhs) 95% CI upper b. (lhs) 95% CI lower b. (lhs) NIGIC con. abs. 95% CI upper b. 95% CI lower b. Figure 3b. Conditional NIGIC for individual education (relative and absolute). Source: Own calculations. gender gaps is equally distributed across all income groups (Figure b). Figures 5a and 5b show the results for average vaccination. The unconditional NIGIC shows pro-poor growth in the weak absolute and is also slightly negatively sloped. Table confirms the pro-poorness in the relative sense. Here, both PPGR exceed the GRIM and also

17 MEASURING PRO-POOR GROWTH IN NON-INCOME DIMENSIONS 37 Change in Absolute Gap Percentile NIGIC uncon. abs. 95% CI upper b., uncon. abs. 95% CI lower b., uncon. abs. Figure a. Unconditional absolute gender gap in education. Source: Own calculations. Change in Absolute Gap Vintile NIGIC conditional 95% CI upper b., con. 95% CI lower b., con. Figure b. Conditional absolute gender gap in education. Source: Own calculations. the PEGR is larger when the extreme poverty line is used. However, improvements are relatively low which was also shown in Table. The conditional NIGIC shows no clear propoor growth trend, also visible in the wide confidence intervals. In addition, the PPGR are lower than the GRIM and for some deciles we even find deterioration. The same findings also hold for the absolute curves which show very small improvements over the time period. When examining the high relative growth in the unconditional NIGIC for education and

18 38 WORLD DEVELOPMENT Percentile NIGIC unconditional (lhs) 95% CI upper b. (lhs) 95% CI lower b. (lhs) NIGIC uncon. abs. 95% CI upper b. abs. 95% CI lower b. abs. Figure 5a. Unconditional NIGIC for average vaccinations (relative and absolute). Source: Own calculations Vintile NIGIC conditional (lhs) 95% CI upper b. (lhs) 95% CI lower b. (lhs) NIGIC con. abs. 95% CI upper b. abs. 95% CI lower b. abs. Figure 5b. Conditional NIGIC for average vaccinations (relative and absolute). Source: Own calculations. vaccinations, Figures 3a and 5a do not report growth rates for the very poor percentiles. This is due to two reasons. First, the very poor began and ended with no education and no vaccinations (see discussion below). Second, a sizable group started with no education or no vaccination and ended up having positive levels of education and vaccinations in the second

19 MEASURING PRO-POOR GROWTH IN NON-INCOME DIMENSIONS 39 period. But in this case the growth rate is not defined and thus not reported. Remember that the very high growth rates that appear on the graphs at the left are thus based on percentiles that have had some small amount of education and vaccinations and even a minute absolute expansion translates into a very high growth rate. Examining the absolute unconditional NI- GICs for education and vaccinations also reveal an important finding regarding the very low tail of the distribution. As Figures a, 3a, and 5a show, the very education-poor and vaccination-poor had no education (vaccinations) in the first period and this continued to be the case in the second period. This is true for the first few percentiles in the education indicator (e.g. the first 8% in Figure 3a) and the entire first decile in the vaccination indicator. Thus, whatever expansion has taken place in non-income improvements, it bypassed a core group of very poor. For all the other educational indicators shown in Tables and, the findings are qualitatively the same. 5 For both survival variables the unconditional NIGIC and the absolute NIGIC are only interpretable for the first few deciles where they show clear improvements in the sense of weak absolute and relative pro-poor growth, but they become flat from the th decile onward in the case of under 5 survival since % survival is already reached as shown in Figures 6a and 6b. Also the conditional NIGIC, which oscillate closely to but always above, reflects the moderate and more or less equally distributed mortality by the income groups. Also, the deciles of Table show only a small income gradient of the mortality risk. Figures 7a and 7b show the NIGIC for stunting. The unconditional NIGIC indicates weak absolute and relative pro-poor growth. For the conditional NIGIC we only find weak absolute but no relative pro-poor growth. 6 These results are also found when looking at the PPGR and the GRIM for the stunting z-score. Both absolute NIGICs show that the absolute changes are distributed nearly equally over the sample. Aggregating the several variables in the CWI (using the small sample), Figures 8a and 8b summarize the development of the social indicators in one single NIGIC. As expected, we find pro-poor growth in the weak absolute and relative sense for the unconditional NIGIC. Looking at Table, we find very high relative pro-poor growth Percentile NIGIC unconditional (lhs) 95% CI upper b. (lhs) 95% CI lower b. (lhs) NIGIC uncon. abs. 95% CI upper b. abs. 95% CI lower b. abs. Figure 6a. Unconditional NIGIC for under 5 survival (relative and absolute). Source: Own calculations.

20 WORLD DEVELOPMENT Vintile NIGIC conditional (lhs) 95% CI upper b. (lhs) 95% CI lower b. (lhs) NIGIC con. abs. 95% CI upper b. abs. 95% CI lower b. abs. Figure 6b. Conditional NIGIC for under 5 survival (relative and absolute). Source: Own calculations Percentile NIGIC unconditional (lhs) 95% CI upper b. (lhs) 95% CI lower b. (lhs) NIGIC uncon. abs. 95% CI upper b. abs. 95% CI lower b. abs. Figure 7a. Unconditional NIGIC for stunting (relative and absolute). Source: Own calculations. as both PPGR clearly exceed the GRIM and also the PEGR is larger than the GRIM, at least for the extreme poverty line. Despite being somewhat more volatile, the conditional NIGIC shows also pro-poor growth in the weak absolute but not in the relative sense.

Measuring Pro-Poor Progress towards the Non-Income Millennium Development Goals Abstract

Measuring Pro-Poor Progress towards the Non-Income Millennium Development Goals Abstract Research Paper No. 2006/38 Measuring Pro-Poor Progress towards the Non-Income Millennium Development Goals Melanie Grosse, Kenneth Harttgen, and Stephan Klasen* April 2006 Abstract In order to track progress

More information

Measuring Pro-Poor Growth with Non-Income Indicators

Measuring Pro-Poor Growth with Non-Income Indicators Measuring Pro-Poor Growth with Non-Income Indicators Melanie Grosse, Kenneth Harttgen, and Stephan Klasen First version: October 31, 2004 / This version: March 10, 2005 Abstract One existing shortcoming

More information

Poverty and income growth: Measuring pro-poor growth in the case of Romania

Poverty and income growth: Measuring pro-poor growth in the case of Romania Poverty and income growth: Measuring pro-poor growth in the case of EVA MILITARU, CRISTINA STROE Social Indicators and Standard of Living Department National Scientific Research Institute for Labour and

More information

Bolivia (Plurinational State of)

Bolivia (Plurinational State of) Human Development Report 2015 Work for human development Briefing note for countries on the 2015 Human Development Report Bolivia (Plurinational Introduction The 2015 Human Development Report (HDR) Work

More information

Brazil. Country coverage and the methodology of the Statistical Annex of the 2015 HDR

Brazil. Country coverage and the methodology of the Statistical Annex of the 2015 HDR Human Development Report 2015 Work for human development Briefing note for countries on the 2015 Human Development Report Brazil Introduction The 2015 Human Development Report (HDR) Work for Human Development

More information

Economic Growth, Inequality and Poverty Reduction in China

Economic Growth, Inequality and Poverty Reduction in China Economic Growth, Inequality and Poverty Reduction in China Sangui Wang Renmin University of China Economic Growth, Poverty and Inequality in China 1 China has achieved remarkable economic growth since

More information

Human Development Index (HDI) and the Role of Women in Development. Eric C. Neubauer, Ph.D. Professor, Social Sciences Department

Human Development Index (HDI) and the Role of Women in Development. Eric C. Neubauer, Ph.D. Professor, Social Sciences Department Human Development Index (HDI) and the Role of Women in Development Eric C. Neubauer, Ph.D. Professor, Social Sciences Department What is Development? Historically, associated with economic development

More information

Briefing note for countries on the 2015 Human Development Report. Philippines

Briefing note for countries on the 2015 Human Development Report. Philippines Human Development Report 2015 Work for human development Briefing note for countries on the 2015 Human Development Report Philippines Introduction The 2015 Human Development Report (HDR) Work for Human

More information

Malawi. Country coverage and the methodology of the Statistical Annex of the 2015 HDR

Malawi. Country coverage and the methodology of the Statistical Annex of the 2015 HDR Human Development Report 2015 Work for human development Briefing note for countries on the 2015 Human Development Report Malawi Introduction The 2015 Human Development Report (HDR) Work for Human Development

More information

India. Country coverage and the methodology of the Statistical Annex of the 2015 HDR

India. Country coverage and the methodology of the Statistical Annex of the 2015 HDR Human Development Report 2015 Work for human development Briefing note for countries on the 2015 Human Development Report India Introduction The 2015 Human Development Report (HDR) Work for Human Development

More information

Economic Growth, Poverty and Inequality in South Africa: The First Decade of Democracy Haroon Bhorat & Carlene van der Westhuizen 1

Economic Growth, Poverty and Inequality in South Africa: The First Decade of Democracy Haroon Bhorat & Carlene van der Westhuizen 1 Economic Growth, Poverty and Inequality in South Africa: The First Decade of Democracy Haroon Bhorat & Carlene van der Westhuizen 1 1 Professor, Development Policy Research Unit, School of Economics, University

More information

CORRELATIONAL ANALYSIS BETWEEN TEENAGE PREGNANCY AND MATERNAL MORTALITY IN MALAWI

CORRELATIONAL ANALYSIS BETWEEN TEENAGE PREGNANCY AND MATERNAL MORTALITY IN MALAWI CORRELATIONAL ANALYSIS BETWEEN TEENAGE PREGNANCY AND MATERNAL MORTALITY IN MALAWI Abiba Longwe-Ngwira and Nissily Mushani African Institute for Development Policy (AFIDEP) P.O. Box 31024, Lilongwe 3 Malawi

More information

Congo (Democratic Republic of the)

Congo (Democratic Republic of the) Human Development Report 2015 Work for human development Briefing note for countries on the 2015 Human Development Report Congo (Democratic Republic of the) Introduction The 2015 Human Development Report

More information

Human Development Index (HDI)

Human Development Index (HDI) Human Development Report 2015 Work for human development Briefing note for countries on the 2015 Human Development Report Iraq Introduction The 2015 Human Development Report (HDR) Work for Human Development

More information

Portugal. Country coverage and the methodology of the Statistical Annex of the 2015 HDR

Portugal. Country coverage and the methodology of the Statistical Annex of the 2015 HDR Human Development Report 2015 Work for human development Briefing note for countries on the 2015 Human Development Report Portugal Introduction The 2015 Human Development Report (HDR) Work for Human Development

More information

Paid and Unpaid Labor in Developing Countries: an inequalities in time use approach

Paid and Unpaid Labor in Developing Countries: an inequalities in time use approach Paid and Unpaid Work inequalities 1 Paid and Unpaid Labor in Developing Countries: an inequalities in time use approach Paid and Unpaid Labor in Developing Countries: an inequalities in time use approach

More information

Briefing note for countries on the 2015 Human Development Report. Burkina Faso

Briefing note for countries on the 2015 Human Development Report. Burkina Faso Human Development Report 2015 Work for human development Briefing note for countries on the 2015 Human Development Report Burkina Faso Introduction The 2015 Human Development Report (HDR) Work for Human

More information

Poverty Indices: Checking for Robustness

Poverty Indices: Checking for Robustness Chapter 5. Poverty Indices: Checking for Robustness Summary There are four main reasons why measures of poverty may not be robust. Sampling error occurs because measures of poverty are based on sample

More information

United Kingdom. Country coverage and the methodology of the Statistical Annex of the 2015 HDR

United Kingdom. Country coverage and the methodology of the Statistical Annex of the 2015 HDR Human Development Report 2015 Work for human development Briefing note for countries on the 2015 Human Development Report United Kingdom Introduction The 2015 Human Development Report (HDR) Work for Human

More information

Nepal. Country coverage and the methodology of the Statistical Annex of the 2015 HDR

Nepal. Country coverage and the methodology of the Statistical Annex of the 2015 HDR Human Development Report 2015 Work for human development Briefing note for countries on the 2015 Human Development Report Nepal Introduction The 2015 Human Development Report (HDR) Work for Human Development

More information

Madagascar. Country coverage and the methodology of the Statistical Annex of the 2015 HDR

Madagascar. Country coverage and the methodology of the Statistical Annex of the 2015 HDR Human Development Report 2015 Work for human development Briefing note for countries on the 2015 Human Development Report Madagascar Introduction The 2015 Human Development Report (HDR) Work for Human

More information

Sierra Leone. Country coverage and the methodology of the Statistical Annex of the 2015 HDR

Sierra Leone. Country coverage and the methodology of the Statistical Annex of the 2015 HDR Human Development Report 2015 Work for human development Briefing note for countries on the 2015 Human Development Report Sierra Leone Introduction The 2015 Human Development Report (HDR) Work for Human

More information

Briefing note for countries on the 2015 Human Development Report. Niger

Briefing note for countries on the 2015 Human Development Report. Niger Human Development Report 2015 Work for human development Briefing note for countries on the 2015 Human Development Report Niger Introduction The 2015 Human Development Report (HDR) Work for Human Development

More information

Explanatory note on the 2014 Human Development Report composite indices. United Kingdom

Explanatory note on the 2014 Human Development Report composite indices. United Kingdom Human Development Report 2014 Sustaining Human Progress: Reducing Vulnerabilities and Building Resilience Explanatory note on the 2014 Human Development Report composite indices United Kingdom HDI values

More information

Thailand. Country coverage and the methodology of the Statistical Annex of the 2015 HDR

Thailand. Country coverage and the methodology of the Statistical Annex of the 2015 HDR Human Development Report 2015 Work for human development Briefing note for countries on the 2015 Human Development Report Thailand Introduction The 2015 Human Development Report (HDR) Work for Human Development

More information

A Comparative Analysis of Income Statistics for the District of Columbia

A Comparative Analysis of Income Statistics for the District of Columbia Occasional Studies A Comparative Analysis of Income Statistics for the District of Columbia ACS Income Estimates vs. DC Individual Income Tax Data Jayron Lashgari Office of Revenue Analysis Office of the

More information

Chapter 1. What is Poverty and Why Measure it?

Chapter 1. What is Poverty and Why Measure it? Chapter 1. What is Poverty and Why Measure it? Summary Poverty is pronounced deprivation in well-being. The conventional view links well-being primarily to command over commodities, so the poor are those

More information

Explanatory note on the 2014 Human Development Report composite indices. Spain. HDI values and rank changes in the 2014 Human Development Report

Explanatory note on the 2014 Human Development Report composite indices. Spain. HDI values and rank changes in the 2014 Human Development Report Human Development Report 2014 Sustaining Human Progress: Reducing Vulnerabilities and Building Resilience Explanatory note on the 2014 Human Development Report composite indices Spain HDI values and rank

More information

Module 3: Measuring (step 2) Poverty Lines

Module 3: Measuring (step 2) Poverty Lines Module 3: Measuring (step 2) Poverty Lines Topics 1. Alternative poverty lines 2. Setting an absolute poverty line 2.1. Cost of basic needs method 2.2. Food energy method 2.3. Subjective method 3. Issues

More information

Briefing note for countries on the 2015 Human Development Report. Mozambique

Briefing note for countries on the 2015 Human Development Report. Mozambique Human Development Report 2015 Work for human development Briefing note for countries on the 2015 Human Development Report Mozambique Introduction The 2015 Human Development Report (HDR) Work for Human

More information

POVERTY, INEQUALITY AND THE NATURE OF ECONOMIC GROWTH IN SOUTH AFRICA

POVERTY, INEQUALITY AND THE NATURE OF ECONOMIC GROWTH IN SOUTH AFRICA POVERTY, INEQUALITY AND THE NATURE OF ECONOMIC GROWTH IN SOUTH AFRICA HAROON BHORAT CARLENE VAN DER WESTHUIZEN DPRU WORKING PAPER 12/151 NOVEMBER 2012 POVERTY, INEQUALITY AND THE NATURE OF ECONOMIC GROWTH

More information

Tanzania (United Republic of)

Tanzania (United Republic of) Human Development Report 2015 Work for human development Briefing note for countries on the 2015 Human Development Report Tanzania (United Introduction The 2015 Human Development Report (HDR) Work for

More information

Module 5: Measuring (step 3) Inequality Measures

Module 5: Measuring (step 3) Inequality Measures Module 5: Measuring (step 3) Inequality Measures Topics 1. Why measure inequality? 2. Basic dispersion measures 1. Charting inequality for basic dispersion measures 2. Basic dispersion measures (dispersion

More information

Distributional Incidence of Social, Infrastructure, and Telecommunication Services in Latin America. Mariana Marchionni y Pablo Glüzmann

Distributional Incidence of Social, Infrastructure, and Telecommunication Services in Latin America. Mariana Marchionni y Pablo Glüzmann C E D L A S Centro de Estudios Distributivos, Laborales y Sociales Maestría en Economía Universidad Nacional de La Plata Distributional Incidence of Social, Infrastructure, and Telecommunication Services

More information

Explanatory note on the 2014 Human Development Report composite indices. Togo. HDI values and rank changes in the 2014 Human Development Report

Explanatory note on the 2014 Human Development Report composite indices. Togo. HDI values and rank changes in the 2014 Human Development Report Human Development Report 2014 Sustaining Human Progress: Reducing Vulnerabilities and Building Resilience Explanatory note on the 2014 Human Development Report composite indices Togo HDI values and rank

More information

Chapter 6. Inequality Measures

Chapter 6. Inequality Measures Chapter 6. Inequality Measures Summary Inequality is a broader concept than poverty in that it is defined over the entire population, and does not only focus on the poor. The simplest measurement of inequality

More information

El Salvador. Country coverage and the methodology of the Statistical Annex of the 2015 HDR

El Salvador. Country coverage and the methodology of the Statistical Annex of the 2015 HDR Human Development Report 2015 Work for human development Briefing note for countries on the 2015 Human Development Report El Salvador Introduction The 2015 Human Development Report (HDR) Work for Human

More information

Statistical Bulletin. The Effects of Taxes and Benefits on Household Income, 2011/12. Key points

Statistical Bulletin. The Effects of Taxes and Benefits on Household Income, 2011/12. Key points Statistical Bulletin The Effects of Taxes and Benefits on Household Income, 2011/12 Coverage: UK Date: 10 July 2013 Geographical Area: UK and GB Theme: Economy Theme: People and Places Key points There

More information

Russian Federation. Country coverage and the methodology of the Statistical Annex of the 2015 HDR

Russian Federation. Country coverage and the methodology of the Statistical Annex of the 2015 HDR Human Development Report 2015 Work for human development Briefing note for countries on the 2015 Human Development Report Russian Federation Introduction The 2015 Human Development Report (HDR) Work for

More information

Briefing note for countries on the 2015 Human Development Report. Palestine, State of

Briefing note for countries on the 2015 Human Development Report. Palestine, State of Human Development Report 2015 Work for human development Briefing note for countries on the 2015 Human Development Report Palestine, State of Introduction The 2015 Human Development Report (HDR) Work for

More information

Distributional Change, Pro-poor Growth and Convergence: An Application to Non-income Dimensions

Distributional Change, Pro-poor Growth and Convergence: An Application to Non-income Dimensions Distributional Change, Pro-poor Growth and Convergence: An Application to Non-income Dimensions Shatakshee Dhongde (Georgia Institute of Technology, USA) Jacques Silber (Bar-Ilan University, Israel) Paper

More information

INDICATOR REGION WORLD

INDICATOR REGION WORLD SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA INDICATOR REGION WORLD Demographic indicators Total population (2005) 713,457,000 6,449,371,000 Population under 18 (2005) 361,301,000 2,183,143,000 Population under 5 (2005) 119,555,000

More information

2. Professor, Department of Risk Management and Insurance, National Chengchi. University, Taipei, Taiwan, R.O.C. 11605; jerry2@nccu.edu.

2. Professor, Department of Risk Management and Insurance, National Chengchi. University, Taipei, Taiwan, R.O.C. 11605; jerry2@nccu.edu. Authors: Jack C. Yue 1 and Hong-Chih Huang 2 1. Professor, Department of Statistics, National Chengchi University, Taipei, Taiwan, R.O.C. 11605; csyue@nccu.edu.tw 2. Professor, Department of Risk Management

More information

ABSTRACT INTRODUCTION MATERIALS AND METHODS

ABSTRACT INTRODUCTION MATERIALS AND METHODS INTERNATIONAL JOURNAL OF AGRICULTURE & BIOLOGY 1560 8530/004/06 3 483 487 http://www.ijab.org Estimation of Food Security Situation at Household Level in Rural Areas of Punjab SHAHZAD AHMAD, M. SIDDIQUE

More information

INDICATOR REGION WORLD

INDICATOR REGION WORLD SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA INDICATOR REGION WORLD Demographic indicators Total population (2006) 748,886,000 6,577,236,000 Population under 18 (2006) 376,047,000 2,212,024,000 Population under 5 (2006) 125,254,000

More information

Social protection and poverty reduction

Social protection and poverty reduction Social protection and poverty reduction Despite the positive economic growth path projected for Africa, the possibility of further global shocks coupled with persistent risks for households make proactive

More information

THE CONCEPT OF POVERTY Principles and Practices

THE CONCEPT OF POVERTY Principles and Practices THE CONCEPT OF POVERTY Principles and Practices Bosnia and Herzegovina Poverty Analysis Workshop September 17-21, 2007 Giovanni Vecchi Universita di Roma Tor Vergata giovanni.vecchi@uniroma2.it POVERTY

More information

Was Economic Growth in Australia Good for the Income-Poor? and for the Multidimensionally-Poor?

Was Economic Growth in Australia Good for the Income-Poor? and for the Multidimensionally-Poor? Working Paper Series Was Economic Growth in Australia Good for the Income-Poor? and for the Multidimensionally-Poor? Francisco Azpitarte ECINEQ WP 2012 278 ECINEQ 2012 278 November 2012 www.ecineq.org

More information

United Kingdom. HDI values and rank changes in the 2013 Human Development Report

United Kingdom. HDI values and rank changes in the 2013 Human Development Report Human Development Report 2013 The Rise of the South: Human Progress in a Diverse World Explanatory note on 2013 HDR composite indices United Kingdom HDI values and rank changes in the 2013 Human Development

More information

Household Energy Expenditure: Measures es off Hardship & Changes in Income

Household Energy Expenditure: Measures es off Hardship & Changes in Income : Measures es off Hardship & Changes in Income By Professor or Sue Richardson Associate Professor or Peter Travers The National Institute of Labour Studies February, 2004 4 Table of Contents HOUSEHOLD

More information

Tunisia s HDI value and rank

Tunisia s HDI value and rank Human Development Report 2013 The Rise of the South: Human Progress in a Diverse World Explanatory note on 2013 HDR composite indices Tunisia HDI values and rank changes in the 2013 Human Development Report

More information

TREND ANALYSIS OF MONETARY POVERTY MEASURES IN THE SLOVAK AND CZECH REPUBLIC

TREND ANALYSIS OF MONETARY POVERTY MEASURES IN THE SLOVAK AND CZECH REPUBLIC TREND ANALYSIS OF MONETARY POVERTY MEASURES IN THE SLOVAK AND CZECH REPUBLIC Iveta Stankovičová Róbert Vlačuha Ľudmila Ivančíková Abstract The EU statistics on income and living conditions (EU SILC) is

More information

Measuring pro-poor growth

Measuring pro-poor growth Economics Letters 78 (2003) 93 99 www.elsevier.com/ locate/ econbase q Measuring pro-poor growth * Martin Ravallion, Shaohua Chen World Bank, MSN MC 3-306 Development Research Group, 1818 H Street NW,

More information

An update to the World Bank s estimates of consumption poverty in the developing world *

An update to the World Bank s estimates of consumption poverty in the developing world * An update to the World Bank s estimates of consumption poverty in the developing world * The World Bank has been regularly monitoring the progress of developing countries against absolute poverty. Drawing

More information

THE EFFECT OF ECONOMIC GROWTH ON POVERTY IN EASTERN EUROPE

THE EFFECT OF ECONOMIC GROWTH ON POVERTY IN EASTERN EUROPE ZARZĄDZANIE PUBLICZNE 1 2(9 10)/2010 Zeszyty Naukowe Instytutu Spraw Publicznych Uniwersytetu Jagiellońskiego Institute of World and Regional Economics, University of Miskolc THE EFFECT OF ECONOMIC GROWTH

More information

Norway. HDI values and rank changes in the 2013 Human Development Report

Norway. HDI values and rank changes in the 2013 Human Development Report Human Development Report 2013 The Rise of the South: Human Progress in a Diverse World Explanatory note on 2013 HDR composite indices Norway HDI values and rank changes in the 2013 Human Development Report

More information

bulletin 126 Healthy life expectancy in Australia: patterns and trends 1998 to 2012 Summary Bulletin 126 NOVEMBER 2014

bulletin 126 Healthy life expectancy in Australia: patterns and trends 1998 to 2012 Summary Bulletin 126 NOVEMBER 2014 Bulletin 126 NOVEMBER 2014 Healthy life expectancy in Australia: patterns and trends 1998 to 2012 Summary bulletin 126 Life expectancy measures how many years on average a person can expect to live, if

More information

INCOME INEQUALITY SOCIAL MOBILITY AND ECONOMIC GROWTH*

INCOME INEQUALITY SOCIAL MOBILITY AND ECONOMIC GROWTH* NERO Conference Paris, 22 June 2015 INCOME INEQUALITY SOCIAL MOBILITY AND ECONOMIC GROWTH* Federico Cingano, ELS Employment Analysis Division *Source: OECD (2015) In It Together: Why less inequality benefits

More information

Inequality, pro-poor growth and development policy. Edward Anderson School of International Development University of East Anglia

Inequality, pro-poor growth and development policy. Edward Anderson School of International Development University of East Anglia Inequality, pro-poor growth and development policy Edward Anderson School of International Development University of East Anglia i. The adverse effects of inequality Since the 1970s, a large literature

More information

Inequality Briefing Briefing Paper No 1 (1 of 3). March 2002

Inequality Briefing Briefing Paper No 1 (1 of 3). March 2002 Inequality Briefing Briefing Paper No 1 (1 of 3). March 2002 Defining and Measuring Inequality Andrew McKay (Overseas Development Institute and University of Nottingham) Introduction: The Importance of

More information

Inequality, Mobility and Income Distribution Comparisons

Inequality, Mobility and Income Distribution Comparisons Fiscal Studies (1997) vol. 18, no. 3, pp. 93 30 Inequality, Mobility and Income Distribution Comparisons JOHN CREEDY * Abstract his paper examines the relationship between the cross-sectional and lifetime

More information

Summary. Accessibility and utilisation of health services in Ghana 245

Summary. Accessibility and utilisation of health services in Ghana 245 Summary The thesis examines the factors that impact on access and utilisation of health services in Ghana. The utilisation behaviour of residents of a typical urban and a typical rural district are used

More information

Administrative Decision Making in Early Childhood Education:

Administrative Decision Making in Early Childhood Education: Administrative Decision Making in Early Childhood Education: HOW DO I USE THE REPORTS AVAILABLE IN ONLINE REPORTER? Assessment Technology, Incorporated Written by: Jason K. Feld, Ph.D. Assessment Technology,

More information

Economic Growth, Poverty and The Child*

Economic Growth, Poverty and The Child* 2 Economic Growth, Poverty and The Child* INTRODUCTION In spite of rapid economic growth in many Third World countries, a disturbingly high rate of death due to child malnutrition continues. The physical

More information

A GENERALIZATION OF THE PFÄHLER-LAMBERT DECOMPOSITION. Jorge Onrubia Universidad Complutense. Fidel Picos REDE-Universidade de Vigo

A GENERALIZATION OF THE PFÄHLER-LAMBERT DECOMPOSITION. Jorge Onrubia Universidad Complutense. Fidel Picos REDE-Universidade de Vigo A GENERALIZATION OF THE PFÄHLER-LAMBERT DECOMPOSITION Jorge Onrubia Universidad Complutense Fidel Picos REDE-Universidade de Vigo María del Carmen Rodado Universidad Rey Juan Carlos XX Encuentro de Economía

More information

The South African Child Support Grant Impact Assessment. Evidence from a survey of children, adolescents and their households

The South African Child Support Grant Impact Assessment. Evidence from a survey of children, adolescents and their households The South African Child Support Grant Impact Assessment Evidence from a survey of children, adolescents and their households Executive Summary EXECUTIVE SUMMARY UNICEF/Schermbrucker Cover photograph: UNICEF/Pirozzi

More information

Demographics of Atlanta, Georgia:

Demographics of Atlanta, Georgia: Demographics of Atlanta, Georgia: A Visual Analysis of the 2000 and 2010 Census Data 36-315 Final Project Rachel Cohen, Kathryn McKeough, Minnar Xie & David Zimmerman Ethnicities of Atlanta Figure 1: From

More information

Bank of Japan Review. Japanese Life Insurance Companies' Balance-Sheet Structure and Japanese Government Bond Investment. February 2013.

Bank of Japan Review. Japanese Life Insurance Companies' Balance-Sheet Structure and Japanese Government Bond Investment. February 2013. Bank of Japan Review 213-E-2 Japanese Life Insurance Companies' Balance-Sheet Structure and Japanese Government Bond Investment Financial System and Bank Examination Department Kazutoshi Kan, Yoshiyuki

More information

Retirement Planning Software and Post-Retirement Risks: Highlights Report

Retirement Planning Software and Post-Retirement Risks: Highlights Report Retirement Planning Software and Post-Retirement Risks: Highlights Report DECEMBER 2009 SPONSORED BY PREPARED BY John A. Turner Pension Policy Center Hazel A. Witte, JD This report provides a summary of

More information

Priority Areas of Australian Clinical Health R&D

Priority Areas of Australian Clinical Health R&D Priority Areas of Australian Clinical Health R&D Nick Pappas* CSES Working Paper No. 16 ISSN: 1322 5138 ISBN: 1-86272-552-7 December 1999 *Nick Pappas is a Henderson Research Fellow at the Centre for Strategic

More information

Schools Value-added Information System Technical Manual

Schools Value-added Information System Technical Manual Schools Value-added Information System Technical Manual Quality Assurance & School-based Support Division Education Bureau 2015 Contents Unit 1 Overview... 1 Unit 2 The Concept of VA... 2 Unit 3 Control

More information

Income Distribution Database (http://oe.cd/idd)

Income Distribution Database (http://oe.cd/idd) Income Distribution Database (http://oe.cd/idd) TERMS OF REFERENCE OECD PROJECT ON THE DISTRIBUTION OF HOUSEHOLD INCOMES 2014/15 COLLECTION October 2014 The OECD income distribution questionnaire aims

More information

VOLATILITY AND DEVIATION OF DISTRIBUTED SOLAR

VOLATILITY AND DEVIATION OF DISTRIBUTED SOLAR VOLATILITY AND DEVIATION OF DISTRIBUTED SOLAR Andrew Goldstein Yale University 68 High Street New Haven, CT 06511 andrew.goldstein@yale.edu Alexander Thornton Shawn Kerrigan Locus Energy 657 Mission St.

More information

The Elasticity of Taxable Income: A Non-Technical Summary

The Elasticity of Taxable Income: A Non-Technical Summary The Elasticity of Taxable Income: A Non-Technical Summary John Creedy The University of Melbourne Abstract This paper provides a non-technical summary of the concept of the elasticity of taxable income,

More information

Accurately and Efficiently Measuring Individual Account Credit Risk On Existing Portfolios

Accurately and Efficiently Measuring Individual Account Credit Risk On Existing Portfolios Accurately and Efficiently Measuring Individual Account Credit Risk On Existing Portfolios By: Michael Banasiak & By: Daniel Tantum, Ph.D. What Are Statistical Based Behavior Scoring Models And How Are

More information

Poverty and Growth: Lessons from Uninspiring or negative economic growth contexts

Poverty and Growth: Lessons from Uninspiring or negative economic growth contexts Poverty and Growth: Lessons from Uninspiring or negative economic growth contexts Murray Leibbrandt (SALDRU, UCT) Mapping the Future of Development Economics UNU-WIDER 3o th Anniversary Conference 17-19

More information

Turkey. HDI values and rank changes in the 2013 Human Development Report

Turkey. HDI values and rank changes in the 2013 Human Development Report Human Development Report 2013 The Rise of the South: Human Progress in a Diverse World Explanatory note on 2013 HDR composite indices Turkey HDI values and rank changes in the 2013 Human Development Report

More information

What Is Poverty and Why Measure It?

What Is Poverty and Why Measure It? Chapter What Is Poverty and Why Measure It? Summary Poverty is pronounced deprivation in well-being. The conventional view links wellbeing primarily to command over commodities, so the poor are those who

More information

Economic inequality and educational attainment across a generation

Economic inequality and educational attainment across a generation Economic inequality and educational attainment across a generation Mary Campbell, Robert Haveman, Gary Sandefur, and Barbara Wolfe Mary Campbell is an assistant professor of sociology at the University

More information

Poverty Indicators Household Income and Expenditure Survey - 2006/07 Department of Census and Statistics Ministry of Finance and Planning Sri Lanka

Poverty Indicators Household Income and Expenditure Survey - 2006/07 Department of Census and Statistics Ministry of Finance and Planning Sri Lanka ISSN 1391-4695 March 2008 Poverty Indicators Household Income and Expenditure Survey - 2006/07 Department of Census and Statistics Ministry of Finance and Planning Sri Lanka Introduction The Household

More information

Chapter 4. Measures of Poverty

Chapter 4. Measures of Poverty Chapter 4. Measures of overty Summary Assume that information is available on a welfare measure such as income per capita, and a poverty line, for each household or individual. This chapter explains how

More information

Analysis of School Finance Equity and Local Wealth Measures in Maryland

Analysis of School Finance Equity and Local Wealth Measures in Maryland Analysis of School Finance Equity and Local Wealth Measures in Maryland Prepared for The Maryland State Department of Education By William J. Glenn Mike Griffith Lawrence O. Picus Allan Odden Picus Odden

More information

Overseas Aspect of Well-Being in the World

Overseas Aspect of Well-Being in the World October 2015 How s Life in the? Additional information, including the data used in this country note, can be found at: www.oecd.org/statistics/hows-life-2015-country-notes-data.xlsx HOW S LIFE IN THE NETHERLANDS

More information

A Half-Century of California Poverty

A Half-Century of California Poverty A Half-Century of California Poverty Robert G. Mogull California State University at Sacramento In this article, poverty statistics are examined over the past 50 years for insights on trends. Data were

More information

A Study of Incidence Experience for Taiwan Life Insurance

A Study of Incidence Experience for Taiwan Life Insurance A Study of Incidence Experience for Taiwan Life Insurance Jack C. Yue 1 and Hong-Chih Huang 2 ABSTRACT Mortality improvement has become a major issue in ratemaking for the insurance companies, and it is

More information

Girls education the facts

Girls education the facts Education for All Global Monitoring Report Fact Sheet October 2013 Girls education the facts Millions of girls around the world are still being denied an education PRIMARY SCHOOL: There are still 31 million

More information

Chapter 1. The Development Gap

Chapter 1. The Development Gap Chapter 1 The Development Gap STORIES OF CATCH-UP AND DECLINE The development gap emerged because some countries developed earlier than others. In historical perspective the Industrial Revolution : The

More information

Income and non-income Pro-Poor Growth in Colombia from 1996 to 2995: a multidimensional approach

Income and non-income Pro-Poor Growth in Colombia from 1996 to 2995: a multidimensional approach Income and non-income Pro-Poor Growth in Colombia from 1996 to 2995: a multidimensional approach Adriana Cardozo, Melanie Grosse This version: August 24, 27 Abstract By using the multidimensional approach

More information

How s Life in Finland?

How s Life in Finland? October 2015 How s Life in Finland? Additional information, including the data used in this country note, can be found at: www.oecd.org/statistics/hows-life-2015-country-notes-data.xlsx HOW S LIFE IN FINLAND

More information

Lessons Learned from MDG Monitoring From A Statistical Perspective

Lessons Learned from MDG Monitoring From A Statistical Perspective Lessons Learned from MDG Monitoring From A Statistical Perspective Report of the Task Team on Lessons Learned from MDG Monitoring of the IAEG-MDG United Nations March 2013 The views expressed in this paper

More information

Todaro, M. P. (1994). Economic Development (5th ed.). New York, London: Longman.

Todaro, M. P. (1994). Economic Development (5th ed.). New York, London: Longman. Todaro, M. P. (1994). Economic Development (5th ed.). New York, London: Longman. Appendix 2.1 Social Indicators as Alternative Measures of Development: The Physical Quality of Life and Human Development

More information

Is Economic Growth Good for the Poor?

Is Economic Growth Good for the Poor? Is Economic Growth Good for the Poor? Tracking Low Incomes Using General Means by James E. Foster and Miguel Székely Department of Economics Vanderbilt University Research Department Inter-American Development

More information

AN ANNUITY THAT PEOPLE MIGHT ACTUALLY BUY

AN ANNUITY THAT PEOPLE MIGHT ACTUALLY BUY July 2007, Number 7-10 AN ANNUITY THAT PEOPLE MIGHT ACTUALLY BUY By Anthony Webb, Guan Gong, and Wei Sun* Introduction Immediate annuities provide insurance against outliving one s wealth. Previous research

More information

Report on the Lapse and Mortality Experience of Post-Level Premium Period Term Plans

Report on the Lapse and Mortality Experience of Post-Level Premium Period Term Plans Report on the Lapse and Mortality Experience of Post-Level Premium Period Term Plans Sponsored by The Product Development Section and The Committee on Life Insurance Research of the Society of Actuaries

More information

Ethiopia. HDI values and rank changes in the 2013 Human Development Report

Ethiopia. HDI values and rank changes in the 2013 Human Development Report Human Development Report 2013 The Rise of the South: Human Progress in a Diverse World Explanatory note on 2013 HDR composite indices Ethiopia HDI values and rank changes in the 2013 Human Development

More information

ACT Research Explains New ACT Test Writing Scores and Their Relationship to Other Test Scores

ACT Research Explains New ACT Test Writing Scores and Their Relationship to Other Test Scores ACT Research Explains New ACT Test Writing Scores and Their Relationship to Other Test Scores Wayne J. Camara, Dongmei Li, Deborah J. Harris, Benjamin Andrews, Qing Yi, and Yong He ACT Research Explains

More information

The Research SUPPLEMENTAL POVERTY MEASURE: 2010

The Research SUPPLEMENTAL POVERTY MEASURE: 2010 The Research SUPPLEMENTAL POVERTY MEASURE: 2010 Consumer Income Issued November 2011 P60-241 INTRODUCTION The current official poverty measure was developed in the early 1960s, and only a few minor changes

More information

Forecaster comments to the ORTECH Report

Forecaster comments to the ORTECH Report Forecaster comments to the ORTECH Report The Alberta Forecasting Pilot Project was truly a pioneering and landmark effort in the assessment of wind power production forecast performance in North America.

More information

IFPRI logo here. Addressing the Underlying Social Causes of Nutrition in India Reflections from an economist

IFPRI logo here. Addressing the Underlying Social Causes of Nutrition in India Reflections from an economist IFPRI logo here Addressing the Underlying Social Causes of Nutrition in India Reflections from an economist The 2013 Lancet Nutrition Series estimated that scaling up 10 proven effective nutrition specific

More information

PARTICIPATION STATUS AMONG VERY POOR FOOD STAMP ELIGIBLE HOUSEHOLDS

PARTICIPATION STATUS AMONG VERY POOR FOOD STAMP ELIGIBLE HOUSEHOLDS VI. PARTICIPATION STATUS AMONG VERY POOR FOOD STAMP ELIGIBLE HOUSEHOLDS As established in the previous chapter, while non-participants might not be participating because they are only temporarily poor,

More information