Value, momentum, and short-term interest rates

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Value, momentum, and short-term interest rates"

Transcription

1 Value, momentum, and short-term interest rates Paulo Maio 1 Pedro Santa-Clara 2 First version: July 2011 This version: December Hanken School of Economics. paulofmaio@gmail.com. 2 Millennium Chair in Finance. Nova School of Business and Economics, NBER, and CEPR. psc@novasbe.pt. 3 We thank John Cochrane for comments on a preliminary version of this paper.

2 Abstract This paper offers a simple asset pricing model that goes a long way forward in explaining the value and momentum anomalies. We specify a three-factor conditional intertemporal CAPM, denoted as (C)ICAPM, where the factors (other than the market return) are the market factor scaled by the lagged state variable and the hedging, or intertemporal, risk factor. These two factors are based on the same macroeconomic state variable: the short-term interest rate. We test our three-factor model with 25 portfolios sorted on size and book-to-market and 25 portfolios sorted on size and momentum. The (C)ICAPM outperforms the Fama and French (1993) three-factor model in pricing both sets of portfolios, and only marginally underperforms the Carhart (1997) four-factor model. The ICAPM hedging risk factor explains the dispersion in risk premia across the BM portfolios, while the scaled factor prices the dispersion in risk premia across the momentum portfolios. According to our model, value stocks enjoy higher expected returns than growth stocks because they have higher interest rate risk; that is, they have more negative loadings on the hedging factor. Past winners also enjoy higher average returns than past losers, because they have greater conditional market risk; that is, past winners have higher market betas in times of high short-term interest rates. Keywords: Cross-section of stock returns; Asset pricing; Intertemporal CAPM; Conditional CAPM; Conditioning information; State variables; Linear multifactor models; Predictability of returns; Fama-French factors; Value premium; Momentum; Long-term reversal in returns JEL classification: G12; G14; E44

3 1 Introduction There is much evidence that the standard Sharpe (1964)-Lintner (1965) Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM) cannot explain the cross-section of U.S. stock returns in the post-war period. Value stocks (stocks with high book-to-market ratios, (BM)), for example, outperform growth stocks (low BM), which is known as the value premium anomaly [Rosenberg, Reid, and Lanstein (1985), Fama and French (1992)]. Also, stocks with high prior one-year returns outperform stocks with low prior returns, which is the momentum anomaly [Jegadeesh and Titman (1993)]. We offer a simple asset pricing model that goes a long way forward in explaining these two anomalies. We specify a three-factor conditional intertemporal CAPM, denoted as (C)ICAPM, that merges the conditional CAPM (CCAPM) and the intertemporal CAPM (ICAPM) from Merton (1973). The factors in the model are the market equity premium (as in both the CCAPM and the ICAPM); the market factor scaled by the state variable (as in the CCAPM); and the hedging or intertemporal factor (as in the ICAPM). The first source of systematic risk other than the market factor (the scaled factor) arises from time-varying betas. The second source of systematic risk (the innovation in the state variable) arises because stocks that are more correlated with good future investment opportunities should earn a higher risk premium as they do not provide a hedge for reinvestment risk (unfavorable changes in aggregate wealth for future periods). In the empirical applications of both the ICAPM and CCAPM, the ultimate source for the additional risk factors (relative to the usual market factor) is the same, that is, a time-varying market risk premium in the current (CCAPM) or future (ICAPM) periods, or time-varying betas (CCAPM), where the time variation is driven by common state variables. 1 In our three-factor model, we use short-term interest rates (proxied either by the Federal funds rate, F F R, or the relative or stochastically detrended Treasury-bill rate, RREL) as the single state variable that drives both future aggregate investment opportunities and conditional market betas. There is evidence in the return predictability literature that short-term interest rates forecast expected (excess) market returns, especially at short forecasting horizons [Campbell (1991), Hodrick (1992), Jensen, Mercer, and Johnson (1996), Patelis (1997), Thorbecke 1 State variables used to proxy for the expected market return or conditional betas are largely borrowed from the fast growing literature on equity premium predictability: the slope of the yield curve or term structure spread [Campbell (1987), Fama and French (1989)]; the spread between higher- and lower-rated corporate bond yields (default spread) [Keim and Stambaugh (1986), Fama and French (1989)]; short-term interest rates [Campbell (1991), Hodrick (1992)]; and aggregate valuation ratios like the dividend yield [Fama and French (1988, 1989)] or the earnings yield [Campbell and Shiller (1988)], among others. 1

4 (1997), Ang and Bekaert (2007), among others]. Thus, both the Fed funds rate and the relative T-bill rate represent valid ICAPM state variables. It is not surprising that a factor model based on the short-term interest rate would perform well in driving equity risk premia. Specifically, the Fed funds rate represents the major instrument of monetary policy, so changes in it should reflect the privileged information of the monetary authority about the future state of the economy. 2 We test the two versions of our three-factor model with 25 portfolios sorted on size and book-to-market and 25 portfolios sorted on size and momentum. The cross-sectional tests show that the (C)ICAPM explains a large percentage of the dispersion in average equity premia of the two portfolio groups, with explanatory ratios around 70%. The (C)ICAPM outperforms the Fama and French (1993) three-factor model when it comes to pricing both sets of portfolios, and is only marginally behind the Carhart (1997) four-factor model, which has explanatory ratios around 80%. The ultimate sources of systematic risk in our model (other than the market factor), however, are associated with a single variable from outside the equity market, the short-term interest rate. In contrast, the four-factor model has three equity financial-based sources of systematic risk (other than the market factor). Thus, our model is more parsimonious in this sense. Moreover, our model represents an application of the ICAPM using a macroeconomic variable, while the foundation for the Carhart (1997) model is less clear. 3 In this sense, our model is a step in the direction of a fundamental model of asset pricing instead of simply explaining equity portfolio returns with the returns of other equity portfolios. In other words, the Fed funds rate or the relative interest rate are not a priori mechanically related to the test portfolios, as is the case with some of the equity-based factors in Fama and French (1993) and Carhart (1997). Interestingly, the (C)ICAPM outperforms both the Fama and French (1993) and Carhart (1997) models in fitting the difficult-to-price small-growth portfolio. The hedging risk factor explains the dispersion in risk premia across the size-bm portfolios, while the scaled factor prices the dispersion in risk premia across the size-momentum portfolios. According to our model, value stocks enjoy higher expected returns than growth stocks because they have more exposure to changes in the state variable; that is, they have more negative 2 Bernanke and Blinder (1992) and Bernanke and Mihov (1998) argue that the Fed funds rate is a good proxy for Fed policy actions. 3 There is some evidence that the Fama-French size and value factors proxy for future investment opportunities [Petkova (2006) and Maio and Santa-Clara (2011)] and future GDP growth [Vassalou (2003)]. The justification for the momentum factor that Carhart (1997) uses is more controversial. 2

5 loadings on the hedging factor. One possible explanation for these loadings is that many value firms have a poor financial position and thus are more sensitive to rises in short-term interest rates that further constrain their access to external finance. As for explaining momentum, in our model past winners enjoy higher average returns than past losers because they have greater conditional market risk; that is, they have higher market betas in times of high short-term interest rates. The explanation for this is that winner and loser stocks have different characteristics at different points of the business cycle. Specifically, during economic expansions, which are associated with high short-term interest rates, winners tend to be cyclical firms, which have high market betas. Conversely, in recessions, with low short-term interest rates, winners tend to be non-cyclical firms, with low market betas [see Grundy and Martin (2001) and Daniel (2011) for a related discussion]. The results of the (C)ICAPM hold under a battery of robustness checks: conducting a bootstrap simulation; including bonds in the test assets; testing the model simultaneously on value and momentum portfolios; using an alternative measure of the innovation in the state variable; including the market equity premium in the test assets; estimating the model with an alternative sample; using alternative standard errors for the factor risk prices; and estimating the model in expected return-covariance form. We also test the (C)ICAPM over an alternative group of portfolios, 25 portfolios sorted on size and long-term prior returns (SLTR25), to assess whether the model explains the long-term reversal anomaly [De Bondt and Thaler (1985, 1987)]. The results show that our three-factor model can explain a significant fraction of the dispersion in equity premia of these portfolios, with explanatory ratios above 50%. As in the test with the SBM25 portfolios, it is the hedging factor that drives the explanatory power of the (C)ICAPM over the SLTR25 portfolios. Our work is related to the growing empirical literature on the ICAPM, in which the factors (other than the market return) proxy for future investment opportunities. 4 It is also related to the large conditional CAPM literature, which postulates that the CAPM should hold on a period-by-period basis, i.e., conditionally rather than unconditionally. 5 4 An incomplete list of papers that have implemented empirically testable versions of the original ICAPM over the cross section of stock returns includes Shanken (1990), Campbell (1996), and more recently, Chen (2003), Brennan, Wang, and Xia (2004), Campbell and Vuolteenaho (2004), Guo (2006), Hahn and Lee (2006), Petkova (2006), Guo and Savickas (2008), and Bali and Engle (2010). 5 An incomplete list of references includes Ferson, Kandel, and Stambaugh (1987), Harvey (1989), Cochrane (1996, 2005), He, Kan, Ng, and Zhang (1996), Jagannathan and Wang (1996), Ghysels (1998), Ferson and Harvey (1999), Lewellen (1999), Lettau and Ludvigson (2001), Wang (2003), Petkova and Zhang (2005), Avramov and Chordia (2006), and Ferson, Sarkissian, and Simin (2008). 3

6 Our paper is organized as follows. In Section 2, we derive our three-factor model. Section 3 describes the econometric methodology and the data. In Section 4, we present and analyze the main results for the cross-sectional tests of the (C)ICAPM. Section 5 provides a number of robustness checks. In Section 6, we analyze the long-term reversal anomaly. 2 A three-factor model We use a simple version of the Merton (1973) intertemporal CAPM (ICAPM) in discrete time (the full derivation is presented in Appendix A). 6 The expected return-covariance equation is given by E t (R i,t+1 ) R f,t+1 = γ Cov t (R i,t+1 R f,t+1, R m,t+1 ) + γ z Cov t (R i,t+1 R f,t+1, z t+1 ), (1) where R i,t+1 denotes the return on asset i; R f,t+1 stands for the risk-free rate; γ denotes the (constant) coefficient of relative risk aversion (RRA); R m,t+1 is the market return; and γ z represents the (covariance) risk price associated with state-variable risk, which is given by γ z J W z(w t, z t ) J W (W t, z t ). In this expression, J W ( ) denotes the marginal value of wealth (W ), and J W z ( ) represents a second-order cross-derivative relative to wealth and the state variable (z). γ z can be interpreted as a measure of aversion to state variable/intertemporal risk, with z t+1 = z t+1 z t representing the innovation in the state variable. We can rewrite the pricing equation (1) in expected return-beta form: E t (R i,t+1 ) R f,t+1 = γ Var t (R m,t+1 ) Cov t(r i,t+1 R f,t+1, R m,t+1 ) Var t (R m,t+1 ) +γ z Var t ( z t+1 ) Cov t(r i,t+1 R f,t+1, z t+1 ) Var t ( z t+1 ) = λ M,t β i,m,t + λ z,t β i,z,t, (2) where λ M,t and λ z,t represent the conditional (beta) risk prices associated with the market and state variable factors, respectively, and β i,m,t and β i,z,t denote the corresponding conditional betas for asset i. 7 Thus, although the market price of covariance risk is constant over time, the 6 Cochrane (2005) presents a similar covariance pricing equation based on a continuous time pricing kernel. 7 We call the innovation to the state variable a risk factor. 4

7 market price of beta risk is time-varying. We assume that the conditional beta associated with the state variable innovation is constant through time, that is, β i,z,t = β i,z, but, following the conditional CAPM literature [Harvey (1989), Ferson and Harvey (1999), Lettau and Ludvigson (2001), and Petkova and Zhang (2005), among others], we let the conditional market beta for asset i be linear in the lagged state variable: β i,m,t = β i,m + β i,mz z t. (3) We estimate β i,m and β i,mz (and also β i,z ) from the time-series multiple regression: R i,t+1 R f,t+1 = a i + β i,m,t R m,t+1 + β i,z z t+1 + ε i,t+1 = a i + (β i,m + β i,mz z t )R m,t+1 + β i,z z t+1 + ε i,t+1 = a i + β i,m R m,t+1 + β i,mz R m,t+1 z t + β i,z z t+1 + ε i,t+1, (4) where β i,m and β i,mz represent the unconditional betas associated with the market factor (R m,t+1 ) and scaled factor (R m,t+1 z t ), respectively. 8 By substituting equation (3) in (2), we obtain a three-factor model: E t (R i,t+1 ) R f,t+1 = λ M,t β i,m + λ M,t z t β i,mz + λ z,t β i,z. (5) By applying the law of iterated expectations, we define the model in unconditional form: E(R i,t+1 R f,t+1 ) = E(λ M,t )β i,m + E(λ M,t z t )β i,mz + E(λ z,t )β i,z = λ M β i,m + λ Mz β i,mz + λ z β i,z, (6) where λ M, λ Mz, and λ z represent the unconditional risk prices for the market, scaled, and hedging factors, respectively. This is a conditional intertemporal CAPM, (C)ICAPM. The economic intuition underlying the (C)ICAPM is that an asset that covaries positively with changes in the state variable earns a higher risk premium than an asset that is uncorrelated with the state variable. The reason is that the first asset does not provide a hedge against future negative shocks in the returns of aggregate wealth, since it offers high returns when 8 The interaction variable, R m,t+1z t, is often interpreted as a managed return. See Hansen and Richard (1987), Cochrane (1996, 2005), Bekaert and Liu (2004), Brandt and Santa-Clara (2006), among others. 5

8 future aggregate returns are also high. 9 Therefore, a rational investor is willing to hold such an asset only if it offers a higher expected return in excess of the risk-free rate. This additional risk premium is captured by the term λ z β i,z. The term λ Mz β i,mz represents an additional risk premium that arises from the fact that the market beta is time-varying and increases with the state variable. When z increases, asset i becomes more correlated with the market return, making this asset riskier. This three-factor model is parsimonious, since a single state variable drives the two sources of systematic risk (other than the market factor). In the empirical tests of the (C)ICAPM we use the Fed funds rate (F F R), and in an alternative version the relative Treasury bill rate (RREL), as the single state variable that drives future aggregate investment opportunities (market returns), and that also drives conditional market betas. There is strong evidence in the return predictability literature that short-term interest rates forecast expected market returns, especially at short-term forecasting horizons [Campbell (1991), Hodrick (1992), Jensen, Mercer, and Johnson (1996), Patelis (1997), Thorbecke (1997), and Ang and Bekaert (2007), among others] Econometric methodology and data In this section, we describe the econometric methodology and the data used in the asset pricing tests conducted in the following sections. 3.1 Econometric methodology The empirical methodology is the time-series/cross-sectional regressions approach (TSCS) presented in Cochrane (2005) (Chapter 12), which enables us to obtain direct estimates for factor betas and (beta) prices of risk. This method has been employed by Brennan, Wang, and Xia (2004), and Campbell and Vuolteenaho (2004), among others. The factor betas are estimated from the time-series multiple regressions for each test asset: 11 R i,t+1 R f,t+1 = δ i + β i,m RM t+1 + β i,m,z RM t+1 z t + β i,z z t+1 + ε i,t. (7) 9 In this reasoning, we are assuming that the state variable covaries positively with future investment opportunities. 10 Under some assumptions, Brennan and Xia (2006) and Nielsen and Vassalou (2006) show that the intercept of the capital market line, which corresponds to the risk-free rate, represents one valid state variable in the ICAPM. 11 The lagged conditioning variable is previously demeaned, which is a common practice in the conditional CAPM literature [see, for example, Lettau and Ludvigson (2001) and Ferson, Sarkissian, and Simin (2003)]. 6

9 We use the monthly excess market return (RM) to compute the betas, rather than the raw market return, as in most applications of linear factor models in the empirical asset pricing literature. RM is based on the value-weighted market return from CRSP and it is available on Kenneth French s website. RM t+1 z t denotes the scaled factor (the interaction between the equity premium and the lagged state variable), and z t+1 z t+1 z t stands for the innovation in the short-term interest rate, z = F F R or RREL. The expected return-beta representation from equation (6) is estimated in a second step by the OLS cross-sectional regression: R i R f = λ M β i,m + λ M,z β i,m,z + λ z β i,z + α i, (8) which produces estimates for factor risk prices ( λ) and pricing errors (ˆα i ). In this cross-sectional regression, R i R f represents the average time-series excess return for asset i. 12 We do not include an intercept in the cross-sectional regression since we want to impose the economic restrictions associated with the model. If the model is correctly specified, the intercept in the cross-sectional regression should be equal to zero; that is, assets with zero betas with respect to all the factors should have a zero risk premium relative to the risk-free rate. 13 Other studies use generalized least squares (GLS) or weighted least squares (WLS) crosssectional regressions to estimate factor risk prices in the cross-section of returns [e.g., Ferson and Harvey (1999), Shanken and Zhou (2007), Lewellen, Nagel, and Shanken (2010)]. The OLS cross-sectional regression is economically appealing and easy to interpret since it assigns equal weight to all testing returns. Thus, we can assess if some economically interesting group of portfolios (e.g., value or momentum portfolios) is properly priced by each model. Furthermore, the GLS or WLS cross-sectional regressions are more difficult to interpret, since the testing returns usually receive large positive and negative weights (the weights come from the inverse of the covariance matrix of the residuals associated with the time-series regressions). Therefore, it is harder to assess whether a particular model is able to explain the CAPM anomalies. Moreover, use of OLS regressions allows us to directly compare different models, unlike either 12 If the factor loadings are based on the whole sample, the risk price estimates from the TSCS approach are numerically equal to the risk price estimates from Fama and MacBeth (1973) regressions. The standard errors of the risk price estimates in the Fama-MacBeth procedure, however, do not take into account the estimation error in the factor loadings from the first-pass time-series regressions. In the TSCS approach, we use Shanken (1992) standard errors that correct for the error-in-variables bias, as discussed below. 13 Another reason for not including the intercept in the cross-sectional regressions is that often the market betas for equity portfolios are very close to 1 (e.g., 25 size/book-to-market portfolios), creating a multicollinearity problem [see Jagannathan and Wang (2007)]. 7

10 GLS or WLS regressions, in which the weights are model-specific, and thus prevent us from directly comparing the fit of two different models (e.g., (C)ICAPM versus the CAPM). A test for the null hypothesis that the N pricing errors are jointly equal to zero (that is, the model is perfectly specified) is given by ˆα Var ( ˆα) 1 ˆα χ 2 (N K), (9) where K denotes the number of factors (K = 3 in the (C)ICAPM), and ˆα is the (N 1) vector of cross-sectional pricing errors. Both the t-statistics for the factor risk prices and the computation of Var( ˆα) are based on Shanken (1992) standard errors, which introduce a correction for the estimation error in the factor betas from the time-series regressions, thus accounting for the error-in-variables bias in the cross-sectional regression [see Cochrane (2005), Chapter 12]. Although the statistic (9) represents a formal test of the validation of a given asset pricing model, it is not particularly robust [Cochrane (1996, 2005), Hodrick and Zhang (2001)]. In some cases, the near singularity of Var( ˆα), and the inherent problems in inverting it, points to rejection of a model with low pricing errors. In other cases, it is possible that the low values for the statistic are a consequence of low values for Var(ˆα) 1 (overestimation of Var(ˆα)), rather than the result of low individual pricing errors. In both cases, this asymptotic statistic provides a misleading picture of the overall fit of the model. A simpler and more robust measure of the global fit of a given model over the cross-section of returns is the cross-sectional OLS coefficient of determination: R 2 OLS = 1 Var N (ˆα i ) Var N (R i R f ), where Var N ( ) stands for the cross-sectional variance. R 2 OLS represents a proxy for the proportion of the cross-sectional variance of average excess returns explained by the factors associated with a given model. A related measure is the mean absolute pricing error, computed as MAE = 1 N N α i, i=1 which represents the average pricing error associated with a given model. 8

11 3.2 Data and variables The data on the Federal funds rate and the three-month Treasury bill rate (T B) are from the FRED database (St. Louis Fed). The relative Treasury-bill rate (RREL) represents the difference between T B and its moving average over the previous twelve months, RREL t = T B t j=1 T B t j. The portfolio return data, the one-month Treasury bill rate used to construct portfolio excess returns, and the risk factors from alternative models are all obtained from Kenneth French s data library. The sample period we use is 1963: :12, where the starting date coincides with most cross-sectional asset pricing tests in the literature. Table 1 presents descriptive statistics for the factors in the (C)ICAPM, RM t+1, RM t+1 F F R t, RM t+1 RREL t, F F R t+1 and RREL t+1. We also present descriptive statistics for the size (SMB), value (HML), and momentum factors (UMD) from the Fama and French (1993) and Carhart (1997) factor models. We can see that the three (C)ICAPM factors are not persistent, with the innovation in the Fed funds rate being the most persistent variable, with an autoregressive coefficient of Moreover, the three factors are not significantly correlated among themselves, with correlation coefficients varying between (RM t+1 F F R t and F F R t+1 ) and 0.15 (RM t+1 and RM t+1 F F R t ), when the state variable is F F R. In the version with RREL the magnitudes of the correlations among the three factors are smaller than Hence the three factors from the (C)ICAPM seem to proxy for different sources of systematic risk. As for the correlation with the other risk factors, RM t+1 F F R t is marginally negatively correlated with HML (-0.26) and marginally positively correlated with UMD (0.22), while RM t+1 RREL t is also slightly positively correlated with the momentum factor (0.25). Figure 1 depicts the time-series of the changes in both the Fed funds rate and RREL. We can see that these two variables present an approximate pro-cyclical pattern, with sharp increases during economic expansions, and some significant declines during recessions. The average Fed funds rate change in expansions (as measured by the National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER)) is 0.06% per month, and in recessions -0.38% per month. In the case of RREL, we have an average of 0.14% in expansions and -0.21% in recessions. 9

12 4 Main empirical results 4.1 Testing the (C)ICAPM We assess whether the three-factor (C)ICAPM explains the value and momentum anomalies. The value premium corresponds to the empirical evidence showing that value stocks (stocks with a high book-to-market ratio) have higher average returns than growth stocks (stocks with a low book-to-market) [see Rosenberg, Reid, and Lanstein (1985), and Fama and French (1992), among others]. This spread in average returns is called an anomaly in the sense that the baseline CAPM [Sharpe (1964) and Lintner (1965)] is not able to explain such a premium [see Fama and French (1992, 1993, 2006)]. We use the standard 25 size/book-to-market portfolios (SBM25) from Fama and French (1993) to test the value premium puzzle. The momentum anomaly is that past winners (stocks with higher returns in the recent past) continue to have subsequent higher returns, while past losers continue to underperform in the near future [Jegadeesh and Titman (1993), and Chan, Jegadeesh, and Lakonishok (1996), among others]. This return premium is not explained by either the baseline CAPM or the Fama and French (1993) three-factor model [see Fama and French (1996)]. In fact, the momentum anomaly represents one of the major challenges for most asset pricing models in the literature (Cochrane (2007)). In order to assess the explanatory power of the (C)ICAPM for the momentum anomaly we use 25 portfolios sorted on both size and prior one-year returns (SM25). 14 The use of these portfolios allows us to assess whether momentum is persistent across different size groups [see Fama and French (2008)]. 15 The estimation results for the (C)ICAPM are displayed in Table 2. The results for the test with the SBM25 portfolios (Panel A) show that the (C)ICAPM s version with F F R explains a significant fraction of the dispersion in average returns of these portfolios, with an R 2 estimate of 70% and an average pricing error of only 0.10% per month (which compares with a crosssectional average portfolio risk premium of 0.67% per month). Moreover, the model passes the χ 2 test with a p-value of 6%. The point estimate for the hedging risk price, λ z, is negative and strongly statistically significant (1% level), while the point estimate for the risk price of the scaled factor, λ M,z, is largely insignificant. In the version with RREL, the model s fit is somewhat worse, but still shows a good ex- 14 Fama and French (1996), Bansal, Dittmar, and Lundblad (2005), Liu and Zhang (2008), He, Huh, and Lee (2010), and Maio (2011), among others, conduct asset pricing tests over portfolios sorted on momentum. 15 Some authors argue that double-sort portfolios produce a greater dispersion in average returns [see, for example, Lakonishok, Shleifer, and Vishny (1994)]. 10

13 planatory power with an R 2 estimate of 46% and an average pricing error of 0.14% per month. This version also passes the χ 2 test with a p-value of 9%. As in the version with F F R, the estimate for λ z is negative and strongly significant, while the estimate for λ M,z is now positive, although not significant at the 10% level. Thus, the key factor that drives the fit of the model over the SBM25 portfolios seems to be the innovation in the short-term interest rate, F F R t+1 or RREL t+1, rather than the scaled factor, RM t+1 F F R t or RM t+1 RREL t. 16 The results for the test with the SM25 portfolios (Panel B) indicate that the (C)ICAPM based on F F R also explains a large fraction of the dispersion in average returns of these portfolios, with an R 2 estimate of 71%, which is very close to the explanatory ratio in the test with the SBM25 portfolios. The average pricing error is 0.16% per month (compared to a cross-sectional average portfolio risk premium of 0.60% per month), which is higher than the corresponding mispricing in the test with SBM25, confirming that the size-momentum portfolios are harder to price than the size-bm portfolios. The (C)ICAPM does not pass the χ 2 test, although this rejection is largely explained by a mismeasured inverse of the covariance matrix of the pricing errors, Var( ˆα), given the good fit associated with the model. The point estimate for the risk price of the scaled factor is positive and strongly significant (1% level), but the risk price estimate associated with the hedging factor is not statistically significant at the 10% level. In the version based on RREL, the model s fit is marginally above the first version, with an explanatory ratio of 74% and an average pricing error of 0.15% per month. This shows that this version of the model performs relatively better in pricing the SM25 portfolios than the SBM25 portfolios. The model is rejected by the χ 2 statistic only marginally (p-value = 4%). As in the case of F F R, the estimate for λ M,z is positive and strongly significant, while the estimate for λ z is negative and significant at the 5% level. Thus, the scaled factor seems to be the key factor that drives the explanatory power of the (C)ICAPM over the SM25 portfolios. Therefore, the two key factors in the (C)ICAPM seem to measure two different and complementary sources of systematic risk. The hedging factor is able to capture the value anomaly, and the scaled factor prices momentum. 16 Brennan, Wang, and Xia (2004) and Petkova (2006) also price the SBM25 portfolios with multifactor models that contain the innovation in short-term interest rates as one of the factors. However, it is not clear in their models what is the contribution of the interest rate factor to drive the explanatory power over the size/bm portfolios. 11

14 4.2 Comparison with alternative factor models We compare the performance of the (C)ICAPM with three alternative linear factor models, the baseline unconditional CAPM; the Fama and French (1993, 1996) three-factor model (FF3); and the Carhart (1997) four-factor model (C4). FF3, the most widely used model in the empirical asset pricing literature, seeks to offer a risk-based explanation for both the size and value premiums. To the excess market return, Fama and French add two factors SMB (small minus big), and HML (high minus low) to account for the size and value premiums. The FF3 model can be represented in expected return-beta form as E (R i,t+1 R f,t+1 ) = λ M β i,m + λ SMB β i,smb + λ HML β i,hml, (10) where (λ SMB, λ HML ) denote the (beta) risk prices associated with the SMB and HML factors, respectively, and (β i,smb, β i,hml ) stand for the corresponding factor betas for asset i. The four-factor model is represented as E (R i,t+1 R f,t+1 ) = λ M β i,m + λ SMB β i,smb + λ HML β i,hml + λ UMD β i,umd, (11) where λ UMD denotes the risk price associated with the momentum factor, and β i,umd represents the corresponding beta for asset i. The novelty relative to the FF3 model is the risk premium associated with the momentum (UMD) factor. UMD (up minus down or winner minus loser) refers to the return of a self-financing portfolio (like SMB and HML), representing the spread in average returns between past short-term winner stocks and past short-term loser stocks. The results for these two factor models are displayed in Table 3. We can see that the baseline CAPM cannot price both sets of equity portfolios, with explanatory ratios of -42% and -18% in the tests with SBM25 and SM25, respectively. These negative estimates indicate that the model performs more poorly than a model that predicts constant risk premia in the cross section. The FF3 model, however, explains a significant proportion of the dispersion in average returns of the SBM25 portfolios, with an R 2 estimate of 67% and an average mispricing of 0.10% per month. These results are consistent with the evidence in Fama and French (1993, 1996). The risk price estimate associated with HM L is statistically significant at the 1% level, while the risk price for SMB is not significant. Yet the FF3 model cannot price the SM25 portfolios, as illustrated by the nearly zero estimate of the coefficient of determination (3%), 12

15 which is in line with previous evidence [Fama and French (1996)]. When we compare the performance of FF3 and the (C)ICAPM (version with F F R), we see that both models have similar performance in pricing the SBM25 portfolios, but the (C)ICAPM (both versions) clearly outperforms in pricing the size-momentum portfolios. In other words, the (C)ICAPM can explain the two anomalies, while the FF3 can price only the value premium. The C4 model explains a large fraction of the cross-sectional dispersion in average returns, with explanatory ratios of 78% and 85% in the tests with SBM25 and SM25, respectively, and the UMD factor is priced in both cases (1% level). Thus, the four-factor model outperforms the (C)ICAPM (version with F F R) by about 8% and 14% (in the explanatory ratios) in explaining the SBM25 and SM25 portfolios, respectively. When we compare against the version based on RREL, the C4 model outperforms by about 0.32% and 0.11% in pricing the SBM25 and SM25 portfolios, respectively. Note that the C4 model includes three independent sources of systematic risk (in addition to the market return), while in the (C)ICAPM the two key sources of systematic risk (scaled factor and innovation in the state variable) are associated with the same state variable, the short-term interest rate. 4.3 Individual pricing errors Although both R 2 OLS and MAE represent measures of the overall fit of the (C)ICAPM, it is important to assess the relative explanatory power of the model over the different portfolios within a certain group (e.g., value versus growth portfolios, or past winners versus past losers portfolios). Figure 2 plots the pricing errors (and respective t-statistics) associated with the SBM25 portfolios in the version with F F R. For the (C)ICAPM, the biggest negative outlier is the extreme large-value portfolio (S5BM 5) with a pricing error of -0.21% per month, and the main positive outliers are the small-value portfolios (S1BM 4 and S1BM 5), with pricing errors of 0.26% per month. In terms of statistical significance, only the pricing error for portfolio S1BM5 is significant at the 5% level. In comparison, in the test with the FF3 model there are seven portfolios with significant pricing errors. It is interesting to see that the (C)ICAPM outperforms both the FF3 and C4 models in pricing the extreme small-growth portfolio (S1BM1) with a pricing error of -0.15% per month, compared to mispricing of -0.41% and -0.31% for FF3 and C4, respectively. This portfolio is particularly hard to price for most models in the empirical asset pricing literature [see, for example, Fama and French (1993) and Campbell and Vuolteenaho 13

16 (2004)]. In untabulated results for the version with RREL, there are four portfolios with significant pricing errors at the 5% level (S1BM1, S1BM4, S1BM5 and S5BM1), which is consistent with the lower explanatory power of this version relative to the version with F F R in pricing the SBM25 portfolios. Figure 3, which is similar to Figure 2, provides a visual representation of the model s fit (version with F F R) in a cross-sectional test with the SM25 portfolios. The main negative outliers associated with the (C)ICAPM are the big-intermediate (S5M 3) and big-winner (S5M 4) portfolios, with pricing errors of -0.37% and -0.40% per month, respectively. The main positive outlier is the small-winner portfolio (S1M5), with a pricing error of 0.43% per month. We can see that for most portfolios the (C)ICAPM produces significantly lower pricing errors than the FF3 model and similar errors to the C4 model. Regarding the statistical significance, there are five portfolios with significant mispricing (S1BM5, S3BM5, S5BM3, S5BM4 and S5BM5). However, in the case of the alternative factor models, the number of significant pricing errors is greater (nine and eighteen for C4 and FF3, respectively). Untabulated results show that in the version based on RREL, there are only three portfolios with significant mispricing (S1BM 3, S1BM 5 and S2BM 1). 4.4 Which factors explain the value and momentum premiums? The results in Table 2 suggest that the innovation in the state variable drives the fit of the (C)ICAPM for pricing the SBM25 portfolios, while the scaled factor seems to drive the explanatory power of the model for the SM25 portfolios. To see more clearly which factors drive the explanatory power of the (C)ICAPM in pricing each set of portfolios, we conduct an accounting analysis of the contribution of each factor to the overall fit of the model. Specifically, we compute the average factor risk premium (average beta times risk price) for each factor and across every book-to-market(bm)/momentum quintile. For example, the average market risk premium associated with the BM/momentum quintile j is given by λ M β j,m, where the average beta for BM/momentum quintile j = 1,..., 5 is computed as the simple 14

17 average of the market betas for portfolio j across the 5 size quintiles within SBM25 or SM25: β j,m = β i,m, i = 1j, 2j, 3j, 4j, 5j, i=1 where the first number refers to the size quintile, and j refers to the BM/momentum quintile. The results for this accounting decomposition are shown in Table 4. The spread in average excess returns between the first (Q1, growth) and the fifth BM quintile (Q5, value) is -0.53% per month, which corresponds to the (symmetric of the) value premium in our sample. This gap has to be (partially) matched by the risk premium associated with one or more of the factors in the (C)ICAPM, as shown in the respective beta pricing equation (6), if this model is able to price the value premium. In the version with F F R, the spread Q1 Q5 in the market risk premium is 0.13% per month, which moves the model farther from explaining the value premium, and confirms why the baseline CAPM does not price the value anomaly. The spread associated with the scaled factor has the right sign, but the magnitude is quite low (-0.03% per month). Thus, it is the innovation in the Fed funds rate that accounts for the value premium, with a spread in the respective risk premium of -0.58% per month, which more than explains the original value premium of -0.53%. Only -0.04%, of the original gap of -0.53%, is left unexplained by the threefactor ICAPM; this is another way to gauge the success of the model in explaining the value anomaly. Thus, value stocks covary negatively with innovations to the Fed funds rate, which has a negative risk price. In the version based on RREL, the accounting decomposition is qualitatively similar. The gaps in risk premiums associated with the market, scaled and hedging factors are 0.15%, 0.17% and -0.69%, respectively, producing a mispricing Q1 Q5 of -0.16% per month. Thus, it is the hedging factor that drives the value premium. With regard to the momentum spread, the gap Q1 Q5 (loser minus winner) in average excess returns is about -1% per month, nearly twice the size of the value premium in our sample. As in the case of the value anomaly, the CAPM cannot explain momentum, as the gap (Q1 Q5) in the market risk premium is positive (0.14% per month). A similar positive spread in risk premium (0.19% per month) is generated by the innovation in the Fed funds rate, showing that this factor does not help to price momentum. Thus, it is the scaled factor that is key in pricing momentum, generating a gap Q1 Q5 in risk premia of 15

18 about -1.16% per month that more than matches the original return spread of -1.01%. Only -0.18% of this last spread is left unexplained by the three-factor ICAPM, thus justifying the large fit of the model in pricing the SM25 portfolios, as documented above. In the case of the version based on RREL, once again we have similar results. The spreads in risk premiums for the market, scaled and hedging factors are 0.08%, -1.43% and 0.49%, respectively, leading to a mispricing of only -0.14% per month. These results confirm that the two non-market factors in the (C)ICAPM drive two different sources of systematic risk, one related to the value premium, and another related to momentum. We conduct a similar decomposition for the FF3 and C4 models to assess the factors that drive the explanatory power of these models over the value and momentum quintiles, which is presented in Table 5. In the case of the FF3 model, the gap Q1 Q5 associated with the HML factor is -0.56% per month, which is about the same as the risk premium gap associated with the hedging factor in the (C)ICAPM, and nearly matches the original value spread of -0.53%. When it comes to pricing the momentum quintiles, the spread associated with HML is only -0.29% per month, about one-third of (the size of) the original momentum spread of -1.01%, thus leading to a gap Q1 Q5 in mispricing of -0.84% per month. In other words, the FF3 cannot price the momentum spread. In the case of the C4 model and BM quintiles, the risk premium gap associated with HML is very similar to the corresponding spread of HML in the FF3 model (-0.55% per month). For the momentum quintiles, the risk premium spread associated with UMD is -0.94%, which almost matches the original momentum spread. Thus, the key factor that prices the value premium in both models is HML (similarly to the hedging factor in the (C)ICAPM), while the UMD factor drives momentum in the C4 model (just like the scaled factor in the (C)ICAPM). These results also suggest that the innovation in our state variable is correlated (conditional on the other factors of the (C)ICAPM) with the HML factor, while the scaled factor is correlated with the U M D factor. To assess this conjecture, we conduct time-series multiple 16

19 regressions: 17,18 HML t+1 = ρ 0 + ρ 1 RM t+1 + ρ 2 RM t+1 z t + ρ 3 z t+1, (12) UMD t+1 = ρ 0 + ρ 1 RM t+1 + ρ 2 RM t+1 z t + ρ 3 z t+1. (13) To measure the individual statistical significance of the regressors, we compute heteroskedasticityrobust GMM standard errors [White (1980)]. The results displayed in Table 6 show that in the regression for HML (Panel A), conditional on the market return, both the hedging factor, F F R t+1, and the scaled factor, RM t+1 F F R t, are negatively correlated with HML t+1, and the slopes are strongly significant (1% level). In the regression for UMD, the scaled factor is positively correlated with UMD t+1, and this effect is strongly significant (at the 1% level), while the slope associated with F F R t+1 is not significant at the 10% level. The correlations are far from perfect, however, as indicated by the R 2 estimates of 16% and 8% in the regressions for HML and UMD, respectively. When the state variable is RREL, the results are qualitatively similar. Both RM t+1 RREL t and RREL t+1 are negatively correlated with HML t+1, although the slope associated with the scaled factor is not significant at the 10% level. In the regression of UMD, both factors are positively correlated with UMD t+1, and both coefficients are statistically significant. Hence, F F R t+1 and RREL t+1 both measure some of the risks captured by HML, and the same happens to the scaled factor in relation to UMD, but these effects are only partial. This result for UMD is consistent with other evidence showing that the payoffs of momentum strategies can be, at least partially, accounted for by lagged macroeconomic variables linked to the business cycle as is the case of the Fed funds rate or relative Treasury bill rate [see Chordia and Shivakumar (2002) and Ahn, Conrad, and Dittmar (2003)]. 4.5 Factor betas and intuition Our analysis shows that the innovation in the Fed funds (or in the relative T-bill rate) is the factor in the (C)ICAPM responsible for pricing the value spread, and the scaled factor accounts for the momentum anomaly. Put differently, there is a dispersion in the betas associated with 17 Other evidence shows that some of the risk factors in the ICAPM or conditional CAPM measure approximately the same types of risks associated with HML [e.g., Lettau and Ludvigson (2001), Vassalou (2003), Hahn and Lee (2006), Petkova (2006), among others]. 18 Ferguson and Shockley (2003) and Hahn and Lee (2006) conduct similar time-series regressions for SMB and HML. 17

20 the hedging factor within the size-bm portfolios that fits the value premium, and there is a similar dispersion in the betas associated with the scaled factor within the size-momentum portfolios that fits the momentum premium. The multiple-regression betas associated with both factors in the case of the SBM25 portfolios are displayed in Figure 4. We can see that value stocks have negative betas associated with F F R t+1, while growth stocks have positive betas for this same factor. This dispersion in betas scaled by the negative risk price for F F R t+1 generates a spread in risk premia. A similar pattern holds for the factor loadings associated with RREL t+1. Why are value stocks more (negatively) sensitive to unexpected rises in short-term interest rates? One possible explanation is that many of these firms are near financial distress as a result of a sequence of negative shocks to their cash flows [Fama and French (1992)], and are thus more sensitive to rises in short-term interest rates. According to the credit channel theory of monetary policy [Bernanke and Gertler (1995)], a monetary tightening (increase in the Fed funds rate) represents an increase in financial costs and restricts access to external financing. This effect should be stronger for firms in poorer financial position, as typically those firms have higher costs of external financing, and the value of their assets (which act as collateral for new loans) is relatively depressed. Increases in interest rates would thus constrain access to financial markets and prevent those firms from investing in profitable investment projects. This mechanism is consistent with the analysis of Lettau and Wachter (2007) who show that the prices (and realized returns) of value stocks are more sensitive to shocks in near-term cash flows, while the prices of growth stocks are more related to shocks to discount rates (long-term expected returns). The analysis of the betas for the SM25 portfolios in Figure 5 shows that past winners have slightly positive betas with the scaled factor, while past losers have large negative betas. This dispersion in betas multiplied by the positive risk price of the scaled factor, RM t+1 F F R t, generates the risk premium necessary to explain the momentum spread. In the case of RM t+1 RREL t the dispersion of betas (negative versus positive) between past losers and winners is even more clear. Thus, past winners are riskier not because they have higher market betas in average times, but because they are more correlated with the market in periods of high short-term interest rates. 18

21 We can assess this in greater detail by computing the average conditional market betas: 19 β i,m,t = β i,m + β i,m,z z t, where z t represents the average of the scaling variable calculated over periods with high and low interest rates. A period with high interest rates occurs when the Fed funds rate or RREL is 1.5 standard deviations above its mean; similarly, a period with low interest rates occurs when F F R (RREL) is 1.5 standard deviations below its mean. When we consider all the periods, the average conditional market beta corresponds to the unconditional (multiple-regression) market beta since the scaling variable has unconditional zero mean, E(F F R t ) = E(RREL t ) = 0. Figure 6 plots the average conditional market betas in the test with the SM25 portfolios for both versions of the model. 20 In Panels A and B, we can see that past winners have lower unconditional market betas than past losers across all size quintiles. That is, past losers are unconditionally riskier than past winners. This shows the inability of the simple CAPM to price the momentum portfolios. In Panels C and D, however, we can see that in periods of high interest rates, past winners have higher market betas than past losers, an effect that is robust across all size deciles. On the other hand, in periods with low interest rates, past losers have higher market betas than past winners, as shown in Panels E and F. Thus, past winners are riskier than past losers because they have greater market risk in times of high short-term interest rates. Why are past winners riskier than past losers in periods with high interest rates? A possible explanation relies on the different characteristics of winner and loser stocks at different points of the business cycle. That is, during economic expansions (which are associated with high shortterm interest rates) winners tend to be cyclical firms, which have high market betas. Conversely, during recessions (periods with low short-term interest rates) winners tend to be non-cyclical firms, with low market betas. The changing composition of the momentum portfolios leads to the time variation in its market betas. This reasoning is consistent with evidence in the momentum literature that momentum profits are pro-cyclical. 21 The mean of the momentum factor (UMD) in economic expansions 19 Lettau and Ludvigson (2001) perform a similar analysis. 20 The analysis is conducted only for the SM25 portfolios, since the scaled factor is not relevant to price the SBM25 portfolios. 21 See Johnson (2002), Chordia and Shivakumar (2002), Cooper, Gutierrez, and Hameed (2004), Sagi and Seasholes (2007), and Stivers and Sun (2010). Specifically, the theoretical analysis in Johnson suggests that momentum profits might be the result of episodic but persistent shocks in cash flows, which can be related with 19

22 (as classified by the NBER) is 0.85% per month compared to only 0.01% per month in recessions. Thus, the time variation in market betas matches the time variation in momentum returns. This variation in risk premium is justified because under positive business conditions and high shortterm interest rates, the market future risk premium is low. Risk-averse investors are willing to invest in winner stocks, which are cyclical at this point of the cycle and have high betas, only if these stocks sell at a greater discount, that is, offer a higher expected return. Our results are also consistent with the evidence provided in Grundy and Martin (2001) and Daniel (2011) that momentum profits are associated with time-varying market betas of winner and loser portfolios. They find that after a bear equity market, the market beta of the momentum factor is low since past winners have low betas (defensive stocks that performed relatively better in the bear market) and past losers have high betas (aggressive or cyclical stocks that underperformed more in the bear market). At the same time, in a bear market interest rates are usually at low levels, and so it follows that past losers have high betas when interest rates are low while past winners have low betas. On the other hand, in a bull market interest rates are at high levels, and thus past winners (those that have outperformed in the bull market) have high market betas while past losers exhibit low betas. Thus, interest rates represent an instrument that signals time variation in market betas of the winner and loser portfolios as a result of changing market conditions and hence of the changing composition of the momentum portfolios and of their market betas. Figure 7 shows that there is some correlation over time between the momentum factor and the conditional market beta of UMD, computed as β UMD,M,t = β UMD,M + β UMD,M,z z t. Specifically, the momentum crashes that occurred in 2001 and 2009 [as documented by Daniel (2011)] are roughly associated with a sharp decline in the current and lagged market betas of the UMD factor. 5 Additional results In this section, we apply a battery of robustness checks to our main results. short-term business conditions. 20

23 5.1 Bootstrap simulation Following Lewellen, Nagel, and Shanken (2010), we estimate empirical confidence intervals for the coefficient of determination and average pricing error in the cross-sectional regressions. We use a bootstrap simulation with 5,000 replications in which the excess portfolio returns and risk factor realizations are simulated (with replacement from the original sample) independently and without imposing the (C)ICAPM s restrictions. Thus, the data generating process is derived under the assumption that the model is not true. We want to investigate the following question: under the assumption that the (C)ICAPM does not hold, how likely is it that we obtain the fit found in the data. In other words, are our results in the cross-sectional tests spurious? In untabulated results and in the test with SBM25, the 95% confidence intervals for R 2 are [ 1.09, 0.19] and [ 1.08, 0.19] when the state variables are F F R and RREL, respectively. The 95% confidence intervals for the average pricing error are [0.48, 0.72] and [0.48, 0.72] for the versions with F F R and RREL, respectively. When we compare these intervals with the actual estimates, it follows that for both versions of the model the estimated coefficients of determination (70% and 46%) are well above the upper bounds on the intervals. Simultaneously, the sample MAE estimates (0.10% and 0.14%) are significantly below the lower bounds on the corresponding empirical intervals. In the test with SM25, the confidence intervals for MAE are quite similar to those in the test with SBM25, which implies that the MAE estimates from the original sample (0.16% and 0.15%) are statistically significant. On the other hand, the 95% interval for R 2 is [ 0.46, 0.27] for both versions of the model, implying that also in this case, the actual R 2 estimates of 71% and 74% are well above the upper limit. Overall, these results suggest that the fit of the model in pricing the BM and momentum portfolios is not spurious. 5.2 Pricing bond returns Adding bond returns to the empirical tests of the (C)ICAPM enables us to assess whether the model can jointly price stocks and bonds. 22 We add to each equity portfolio group the excess returns on seven Treasury bonds with maturities of 1, 2, 5, 7, 10, 20, and 30 years. The data are available from CRSP. This involves a total of 32 test assets in each estimation (SBM25 or 22 Fama and French (1993) and Koijen, Lustig, and Van Nieuwerburgh (2010) also estimate factor models over the joint cross-section of stock and bond returns. 21

24 SM25). The results are presented in Table 7. In the test with SBM25 and version based on F F R, the explanatory ratio increases to 85% from 70% in the benchmark test, while the average pricing error is 0.09% per month. The point estimate for λ F F R is slightly lower (-0.48) than in the benchmark test, but remains strongly significant (1% level). In the test with SM25, the R 2 and average pricing error estimates are the same as in the tests for the equity portfolios. The risk price for the scaled factor, λ M,F F R, is close to the corresponding estimate in the benchmark test and is significant at the 1% level. In the tests with either portfolio group, the model is rejected by the χ 2 test, likely mainly because of a poor inversion of Var( ˆα) when the number of test returns is relatively large. In the version based on RREL, the explanatory ratio in the test with SBM25 is 57% (up from 46% in the benchmark test), and the average pricing error is 0.16% per month. The estimate for the hedging risk price is significantly lower in magnitude than in the baseline case (-0.18%) but is still significant at the 1% level. In the test containing the SM25 portfolios, the fit of the model is basically the same as in the benchmark case, with a coefficient of determination of 76%. As before, the estimates for λ M,RREL and λ RREL are positive and negative, respectively, but only the scaled factor is priced. We also estimate the alternative linear factor models by including bond risk premiums in the menu of test assets. Untabulated results show explanatory ratios of 31% and 12% for the baseline CAPM in the tests with SBM25 and SM25, respectively. This shows that the CAPM has some explanatory power over bond risk premia. The FF3 model has a fit very similar to the (C)ICAPM (version with F F R) in the test with SBM25 (R 2 = 82%), but it underperforms significantly in the test with SM25 (R 2 = 26%). The explanatory ratio for the C4 model is quite similar to the (C)ICAPM in the test with SBM25 (88%), while it outperforms in the test with SM25, with an explanatory ratio of 89%. Overall, when we price equity and bond risk premia jointly, the results for the (C)ICAPM are quite similar to the benchmark results. 5.3 Pricing alternative equity portfolios We estimate the (C)ICAPM with alternative equity portfolios 10 portfolios sorted on size, 10 portfolios sorted on BM and 10 momentum portfolios, for a total of 30 portfolios. This cross-sectional test enables us to check whether our three-factor model prices simultaneously 22

25 the BM and momentum portfolios. The results are displayed in Table 8. We can see that in the version based on F F R the model s fit is smaller than in the tests with either SBM25 or SM25, with an explanatory ratio of 29% and an average pricing error of 0.15% per month. The risk price estimates for the non-market factors have the same signs than in the test with SM25, and both estimates are significant at the 1% level. In the version with RREL, the explanatory power is significantly greater than in the first version, with an R 2 of 60% and an average mispricing of 0.12% per month. This fit is halfway the one obtained for the tests with the SBM25 and SM25 portfolios. The risk price estimates for the scaled and hedging factors have the same signs as in the version with F F R, and both estimates are statistically significant. In untabulated results, the explanatory ratios for the FF3 and C4 models are -9% and 85%, respectively. These results show that overall, the (C)ICAPM does a good job in pricing simultaneously the size, BM and momentum portfolios. 5.4 Pricing the market return We next reestimate the (C)ICAPM by including the market equity premium (RM) in the set of test assets. 23 This enables us to assess whether the model can jointly price the equity portfolios (SMB25 or SM25) and the market return. Results not tabulated show that the (C)ICAPM fit is very close to that of the benchmark test including only equity portfolios, with R 2 estimates of 71% and 69% in the tests with SBM25 and SM25, respectively, when the state variable is F F R. In the version based on RREL, the explanatory ratios are 48% and 74% in the tests with SBM25 and SM25, respectively. For both versions of the model, the risk price estimates are also nearly the same as in the benchmark test of the (C)ICAPM. Thus, forcing the model to price the aggregate equity premium does not have an impact on the fit of the (C)ICAPM. 23 Lewellen, Nagel, and Shanken (2010) advocate that when the factors are returns, they should be included in the set of test assets. 23

26 5.5 Alternative ICAPM specification In an alternative ICAPM specification, the innovation in the state variable represents the residual from an AR(1) model: z t+1 ε t+1 = z t+1 φ z ρ z z t. (14) By using this new proxy for z t+1, we want to assess whether the results for the (C)ICAPM are sensitive to the measurement of the innovation in the state variable. Untabulated results are very similar to the benchmark test using the first difference in either F F R or RREL. In the version based on F F R, the explanatory ratios are 72% and 71% in the tests with SBM25 and SM25, respectively, while average pricing errors are the same as in the benchmark test. In the version with RREL, the R 2 estimates are 54% and 76% in the tests with SBM25 and SM25, respectively. The corresponding MAE estimates are 0.13% and 0.14% per month, which are very similar to the corresponding values in the benchmark test. The point estimates for the factor risk prices are also very close to the estimates in the benchmark test, for both versions of the model. Thus, the results of the (C)ICAPM are robust to the way we measure the innovation in the state variable, the hedging risk factor. 5.6 Alternative standard errors We use alternative standard errors for the factor risk prices and pricing errors. These GMMbased standard errors can be interpreted as a generalization of the Shanken (1992) standard errors to the extent that they relax the implicit assumption of independence between the factors and the residuals from the time-series regressions [see Cochrane (2005) (Chapter 12)]. The full details are provided in Appendix B. Untabulated results show that the t-statistics for the risk price estimates based on the new standard errors lead to the same qualitative decisions as the Shanken t-statistics. Specifically, λ z in the test with SBM25 and λ M,z in the test with SM25 are both significant at the 1% level. The main difference occurs with the χ 2 statistic in the tests with SBM25, which now has p-values of 2% and 4% in the versions with F F R and RREL, respectively. This values are related to a poor inversion of the covariance matrix of the pricing errors, given their lowness (0.10% or 0.14% per month). 24

27 5.7 Alternative sample We estimate out three-factor model in the test with the SM25 portfolios for the 1963: :12 period. We want to assess whether the fit of the model in pricing the momentum portfolios is robust to removing the momentum crash occurred in 2009, as documented by Daniel (2011). Untabulated results show that the explanatory power of the version based on F F R is only marginally lower than in the test for the full sample, with an R 2 estimate of 60% and an average pricing error of 0.22% per month. On the other hand, in the version based on RREL, the fit of the (C)ICAPM is basically the same as in the benchmark test (R 2 = 73%, MAE = 0.17%). In both versions, the point estimates of the risk price for the scaled factor are strongly significant (1% level). Overall, these results show that the 2009 momentum crash does not have a meaningful impact on the capacity of the model in pricing the momentum portfolios. 5.8 Estimating the (C)ICAPM in expected return-covariance representation We define and test the (C)ICAPM in expected return-covariance representation: E(R i,t+1 R f,t+1 ) = γ M Cov(R i,t+1 R f,t+1, RM t+1 ) +γ M,z Cov(R i,t+1 R f,t+1, RM t+1 z t ) + γ z Cov(R i,t+1 R f,t+1, z t+1 ), (15) where (γ M, γ M,z, γ z ) denote the covariance risk prices associated with the market return, the scaled factor, and the innovation in the state variable, respectively. This version of the model is equivalent to an expected return-single beta pricing equation. Thus, the model should fit as well as the version with multiple-regression betas, although the risk prices might have different signs, given possible correlation among the factors. Though, as the factors in the (C)ICAPM are not significantly correlated, as shown in Table 1, the factor risk prices should have the same signs in either multiple- or single-regression betas (or equivalently, covariances). We estimate specification (15) by first-stage GMM [Hansen (1982) and Cochrane (2005)]. This method uses equally weighted moments, which is conceptually equivalent to running an OLS cross-sectional regression of average excess returns on factor covariances (right-hand side variables). One advantage of using the GMM procedure is that we do not need to have previous estimates of the individual covariances, since these are implied in the GMM moment conditions. 25

28 The GMM system has N + 3 moment conditions, where the first N sample moments correspond to the pricing errors for each of the N testing returns: (R i,t+1 R f,t+1 ) γ M (R i,t+1 R f,t+1 ) (RM t+1 µ M ) γ M,z (R i,t+1 R f,t+1 ) (RM t+1 z t µ M,z ) g T (b) 1 T T 1 t=0 γ z (R i,t+1 R f,t+1 ) ( z t+1 µ z ) RM t+1 µ M = 0. RM t+1 z t µ M,z z t+1 µ z i = 1,..., N, (16) In this system, the last three moment conditions enable us to estimate the factor means. Thus, the estimated covariance risk prices from the first N moment conditions correct for the estimation error in the factor means, as in Cochrane (2005) (Chapter 13) and Yogo (2006). There are N 3 overidentifying conditions (N + 3 moments and 2 3 parameters to estimate). The standard errors for the parameter estimates and the remaining GMM formulas are presented in Appendix C. By defining the first N residuals from the GMM system as the pricing errors associated with the N test assets, α i, i = 1,..., N, the χ 2, ROLS 2, and MAE measures are defined analogously to the formulas presented in Section 3. The GMM estimation results are displayed in Table 9. As expected, the R 2 and MAE estimates are the same as in the benchmark test of the beta pricing equation. Now, however, the (C)ICAPM version based on F F R is rejected by the χ 2 statistic in the estimation with the SBM25 portfolios (p-value = 1%), which again should be the result of a poor inversion of Var(ˆα). The point estimate for γ F F R is negative and statistically significant (at the 5% level) in the test with SBM25, while the point estimate for γ M,F F R is positive and strongly significant (1% level) in the test with SM25. Thus, the signs of the covariance risk prices of the non-market factors are the same as in the test of the beta pricing equation. The market covariance risk prices, γ M, are negative, but these point estimates are largely insignificant. In the version with RREL, the (C)ICAPM continues to pass the χ 2 test when the test portfolios are SBM25 (p-value = 6%). The estimates for γ M,RREL and γ RREL have the same signs as λ M,RREL and λ RREL, in the benchmark test. The hedging risk price in the test with SBM25 and the scaled factor risk price in the test with SM25 are statistically significant at the 26

29 1% and 5% levels, respectively. In contrast with the version based on F F R, the estimates for the market risk price are now positive, although largely insignificant. Overall, the estimation results for the covariance pricing equation are consistent with those in the benchmark test. We also estimate the expected return-covariance equation by including an intercept that represents a proxy for the excess zero-beta rate: E(R i,t+1 R f,t+1 ) = γ 0 + γ M Cov(R i,t+1 R f,t+1, RM t+1 ) +γ M,z Cov(R i,t+1 R f,t+1, RM t+1 z t ) + γ z Cov(R i,t+1 R f,t+1, z t+1 ). (17) As we note in Section 3, if the (C)ICAPM is correctly specified, the estimate for γ 0 should not be statistically different from zero. Results not tabulated show that the point estimates for γ 0 are nearly zero and largely insignificant in the tests with both the SBM25 and SM25 portfolios, and for both versions of the model. Moreover, the MAE and R 2 estimates are nearly the same as in the benchmark restricted pricing equation without intercept, thus showing that the constant factor plays no relevant role. These results seem to suggest that the (C)ICAPM is not misspecified. That is, there are no relevant missing risk factors, at least when it comes to price the value and momentum portfolios. 5.9 Nested models The (C)ICAPM consists of two important nested models. The standard ICAPM can be obtained as a special case of the (C)ICAPM by imposing β i,mz = 0, i.e., that the conditional market beta is constant over time: E(R i,t+1 R f,t+1 ) = λ M β i,m + λ z β i,z. (18) Similarly, the conditional CAPM in unconditional form can be obtained from (6) by imposing λ z = 0; that is, investment opportunities are constant through time: E(R i,t+1 R f,t+1 ) = λ M β i,m + λ Mz β i,mz. (19) We estimate the two nested models of the (C)ICAPM: the two-factor conditional CAPM in equation (19), and the two-factor (unconditional) ICAPM in equation (18). This analysis 27

30 allows us to evaluate the incremental explanatory power of the benchmark three-factor model against each nested model in pricing both sets of equity portfolios. The estimation results are displayed in Table 10. In the test with SBM25, the conditional CAPM based on F F R has some explanatory power over the size-bm portfolios with an R 2 estimate of 34% and an average mispricing of 0.15% per month. The fit of the two-factor ICAPM is significantly better, with an explanatory ratio of 67% and an average pricing error of 0.11% per month, for almost the same explanatory power as in the benchmark (C)ICAPM. Moreover, the point estimate for λ F F R is negative and strongly significant (1% level). When the state variable is RREL, the CCAPM cannot price the size/bm portfolios, with a coefficient of determination of -18% and a MAE estimate of 0.22% per month. On the other hand, the fit of the two-factor ICAPM (R 2 = 40%) is almost the same as in the (C)ICAPM, and the estimate for λ z is significant at the 1% level. In the test with SM25, the two-factor ICAPM cannot price these portfolios, with a negative R 2 estimate (-18%) and an average pricing error as high as 0.32% per month. On the other hand, the fit of the conditional CAPM is nearly the same as that of the (C)ICAPM, with a coefficient of determination of 69% and an MAE estimate of 0.16% per month. Moreover, the risk price of the scaled factor is positive and highly significant. The results for the version based on RREL are qualitatively similar. The two-factor ICAPM performs poorly with an explanatory ratio of just 7%. In contrast, the fit of the CCAPM (66%) is close to that of the benchmark three-factor model and the risk price estimate for the scaled factor is significant at the 1% level. Thus, these results are consistent with the analysis so far. The (C)ICAPM provides the best of both worlds, that is, the best characteristics of the two nested models. It includes the hedging risk factor that prices the BM portfolios (as in the baseline ICAPM), and also the scaled factor that prices the momentum portfolios (as in the conditional CAPM). 6 Long-term reversal Can the (C)ICAPM explain the long-term reversal in returns anomaly [De Bondt and Thaler (1985, 1987)]? The anomaly is that stocks with low returns over the long term (three to five years) have higher subsequent future returns, while past long-term winners have lower future returns. This long-term mean reversion in stock returns is not explained by the CAPM. This 28

31 anomaly should be closely related to the value anomaly, as long-term underperformers end up with high book-to-market ratios. To test the explanatory power of the (C)ICAPM for this anomaly, we use 25 portfolios sorted on both size and long-term past returns (SLTR25). The portfolios come from the intersection of five portfolios formed on size (market equity) and five portfolios formed on past returns (13 to 60 months before the portfolio formation date). The portfolios are obtained from Kenneth French s data library. 24 The results for the (C)ICAPM pricing equation in the test with the SLTR25 portfolios are shown in Table 11. We can see that the (C)ICAPM based on F F R has considerable explanatory power, with a coefficient of determination of 63%, while the corresponding average pricing error is 0.09% per month. This is a relatively similar fit to the test with the SBM25 portfolios. Moreover, the point estimate for λ F F R is negative and strongly significant (1% level), while the risk price of the scaled factor is largely insignificant. In the version based on RREL, the fit is only marginally lower with an explanatory ratio of 51% and an average mispricing of 0.11% per month. Moreover, the hedging risk factor is strongly priced (1% level). Thus, as in the test with SBM25, most of the explanatory power of the model over the SLTR25 portfolios seems to be driven by the hedging factor. We also estimate the alternative factor models with these SLTR25 portfolios. Results not tabulated show that the baseline CAPM cannot price these portfolios, with an R 2 of -9%, and an average pricing error of 0.17% per month. The FF3 model significantly outperforms the CAPM, with an explanatory ratio of 75%, marginally better than the fit of the (C)ICAPM. Moreover, the risk price for HML is strongly priced. The C4 model has the best overall fit, with an R 2 estimate of 92%, indicating that UMD, in addition to HML, helps to price these portfolios. The plot of the individual pricing errors, presented in Figure 8, shows that the main outlier in the test with the (C)ICAPM s version with F F R is the small/past winner portfolio (S1LT R5), with a pricing error of -0.36% per month; the corresponding mispricing in the case of the FF3 model is -0.33% per month. The pricing errors for portfolios S1LT R3 and S1LT R5 are statistically significant at the 5% level, while in the case of the FF3 model there are three portfolios with significant errors. Untabulated results show that, similarly to the version with F F R, 24 Fama and French (1996), Da (2009), and Da and Warachka (2009), among others, also conduct asset pricing tests over portfolios sorted on prior long-term returns. 29

32 when the state variable is RREL only the pricing errors associated with portfolios S1LT R3 and S1LT R5 are statistically significant. Thus, as in the test over the size/bm portfolios, the (C)ICAPM seems to behave much like the FF3 model. We also conduct an accounting decomposition of the long-term reversal spread, similar to the analysis made for the value and momentum spreads in Section 4. In untabulated results, the gap Q1 Q5 in average excess returns (past long-term loser minus past long-term winner) is about 0.45% per month, which corresponds to the long-term reversal spread in our sample. This premium is comparable to the size of the value premium reported above (0.53%). The risk premium (beta times risk price) gap (Q1 Q5) associated with the market factor is -0.03% per month, thus confirming that the baseline CAPM cannot price the long-term reversal (LTR) quintiles. The spreads in risk premium associated with the hedging and scaled factors are 0.26% and 0.09% per month, respectively. Of the original 0.45% spread in returns, 0.14% is not explained by the model, which represents about one-third of the original gap. Thus, the key factor responsible for the explanatory power of the (C)ICAPM over the long-term reversal portfolios is the hedging factor, similar to the results obtained for the value premium. When the state variable is RREL, the results are qualitatively similar: the risk premium gaps for the market, scaled and hedging factors are -0.04%, 0.05% and 0.19%, respectively, producing a spread in pricing errors of 0.25% per month. Thus, as in the case with F F R, the hedging factor drives most of the explanatory power of the model over the long-term reversal spread. An analogous decomposition for the FF3 model shows that the HML factor is the key driver of the LTR spread, with a gap in risk premium of 0.34% per month, while the SMB makes a marginal contribution (gap of 0.02%) leading to a gap in mispricing of 0.11% per month. In the case of the C4 model, the gaps in risk premium associated with the SMB, HML, and UMD factors are 0.12%, 0.26%, and 0.07% per month, respectively, producing a gap Q1 Q5 in average pricing error of only 0.02% per month, consistent with the high explanatory ratio. Analysis of the factor loadings in Figure 9 sheds light on the way the (C)ICAPM, more precisely, the hedging factor, prices the long-term reversal anomaly. We can see that, across all size quintiles, past long-term losers have relatively high negative betas associated with the innovation in the Fed funds rate, while past long-term winners have positive loadings (within the first size quintile, negative betas but with lower magnitudes). This spread in betas scaled 30

33 by the corresponding risk price generates the risk premium necessary to partially explain the long-term reversal return spread. When the state variable is RREL, with the exception of the first size quintile, we also have negative factor loadings for past long-term losers and positive betas for past winners. Why are past long-term losers have greater interest risk than past long-term winners? Past long-term losers are likely to have a long sequence of negative shocks in their cash flows, and hence become more financially constrained through time. Hence, these firms will be more sensitive to additional negative shocks in their earnings, specifically further rises in short-term interest rates. Hence, past long-term losers act much like value stocks, while past-winners behave more like growth stocks. 7 Conclusion We offer a simple asset pricing model that goes a long way forward in explaining the value and momentum anomalies. We specify a three-factor conditional intertemporal CAPM, denoted as (C)ICAPM. The factors are the market equity premium, the market factor scaled by the state variable (arising from time-varying market betas), and the hedging or intertemporal factor. These last two factors are based on the same macroeconomic state variable, the Federal funds rate or the relative T-bill rate. We test our three-factor model with 25 portfolios sorted on size and book-to-market and 25 portfolios sorted on size and momentum. The cross-sectional tests show that the (C)ICAPM explains a large faction of the dispersion in average equity premia of the two portfolio groups, with explanatory ratios around 70%. The (C)ICAPM outperforms the Fama and French (1993) three-factor model when it comes to pricing both sets of portfolios, and only marginally underperforms the Carhart (1997) four-factor model. The ultimate non-market sources of systematic risk in our model are associated with one single variable, a proxy for short-term interest rates; in the four-factor model, there are three unrelated non-market sources of systematic risk. Moreover, the factors in Carhart (1997) are selffinancing portfolios related to the test portfolios, while we use a macroeconomic state variable that a priori is not mechanically related to the test portfolios. The ICAPM hedging risk factor explains the dispersion in risk premia across the book-tomarket portfolios, and the scaled factor prices the dispersion in risk premia across the momentum 31

34 portfolios. According to our model, the reason that value stocks enjoy higher expected returns than growth stocks is because they have higher interest rate risk; that is, they have more negative factor loadings on the hedging factor. Furthermore, in our model past winners enjoy higher average returns than past losers because they have greater conditional market risk; that is, past winners have higher market risk in times of high short-term interest rates. 32

35 References Ahn, Dong-Hyun, Jennifer Conrad, and Robert F. Dittmar, 2003, Risk adjustment and trading strategies, Review of Financial Studies 16, Ang, Andrew, and Geert Bekaert, 2007, Stock return predictability: Is it there? Review of Financial Studies 20, Avramov, Doron, and Tarun Chordia, 2006, Asset pricing models and financial market anomalies, Review of Financial Studies 19, Bali, Turan G., and Robert F. Engle, 2010, The intertemporal capital asset pricing model with dynamic conditional correlations, Journal of Monetary Economics 57, Balvers, Ronald J., and Dayong Huang, 2009, Money and the (C)CAPM, Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 44, Bansal, Ravi, Robert F. Dittmar, and Christian T. Lundblad, 2005, Consumption, dividends, and the cross section of equity returns, Journal of Finance 60, Bekaert, Geert, and Jun Liu, 2004, Conditioning information and variance bounds on pricing kernels, Review of Financial Studies 17, Bernanke, Ben S., and Alan S. Blinder, 1992, The Federal funds rate and the channels of monetary transmission, American Economic Review 82, Bernanke, Ben S., and Mark Gertler, 1995, Inside the black box: The credit channel of monetary policy transmission, Journal of Economic Perspectives 9, Bernanke, Ben S., and Ilian Mihov, 1998, Measuring monetary policy, Quarterly Journal of Economics 113, Brandt, Michael W., and Pedro Santa-Clara, 2006, Dynamic portfolio selection by augmenting the asset space, Journal of Finance 61, Brandt, Michael W., and Kevin Q. Wang, 2003, Time-varying risk aversion and unexpected inflation, Journal of Monetary Economics 50, Brennan, Michael J., Ashley Wang, and Yihong Xia, 2004, Estimation and test of a simple model of intertemporal capital asset pricing, Journal of Finance 59, Brennan, Michael J., and Yihong Xia, 2006, Risk and valuation under an intertemporal capital asset pricing model, Journal of Business 79,

36 Campbell, John Y., 1987, Stock returns and the term structure, Journal of Financial Economics 18, Campbell, John Y., 1991, A variance decomposition for stock returns, Economic Journal 101, Campbell, John Y., 1996, Understanding risk and return, Journal of Political Economy 104, Campbell, John Y., and Robert J. Shiller, 1988, Stock prices, earnings, and expected dividends, Journal of Finance 43, Campbell, John Y., and Tuomo Vuolteenaho, 2004, Bad beta, good beta, American Economic Review 94, Carhart, Mark, 1997, On persistence in mutual fund performance, Journal of Finance 52, Chan, Louis K. C., Narasimhan Jegadeesh, and Josef Lakonishok, 1996, Momentum strategies, Journal of Finance 51, Chen, Joseph, 2003, Intertemporal CAPM and the cross-section of stock returns, Working paper, University of California, Davis. Chordia, Tarun, and Lakshmanan Shivakumar, 2002, Momentum, business cycle, and timevarying expected returns, Journal of Finance 57, Cochrane, John H., 1996, A cross-sectional test of an investment-based asset pricing model, Journal of Political Economy 104, Cochrane, John H., 2005, Asset pricing (revised edition), Princeton University Press. Cochrane, John H., 2007, Financial markets and the real economy, in Rajnish Mehra, Ed., Handbook of the Equity Premium, Elsevier, Cooper, Michael J., Roberto C. Gutierrez, Jr., and Allaudeen Hameed, 2004, Market states and momentum, Journal of Finance 59, Da, Zhi, 2009, Cash flow, consumption risk, and the cross-section of stock returns, Journal of Finance 64, Da, Zhi, and Mitchell C. Warachka, 2009, Cashflow risk, systematic earnings revisions, and the cross-section of stock returns, Journal of Financial Economics 94, Daniel, Kent, 2011, Momentum crashes, Working paper, Columbia University. 34

37 De Bondt, Werner F., and Richard H. Thaler, 1985, Does the stock market overreact? Journal of Finance 40, De Bondt, Werner F., and Richard H. Thaler, 1987, Further evidence on investor overreaction and stock market seasonality, Journal of Finance 42, Fama, Eugene F., and Kenneth R. French, 1988, Dividend yields and expected stock returns, Journal of Financial Economics 22, Fama, Eugene F., and Kenneth R. French, 1989, Business conditions and expected returns on stock and bonds, Journal of Financial Economics 25, Fama, Eugene F., and Kenneth R. French, 1992, The cross-section of expected stock returns, Journal of Finance 47, Fama, Eugene F., and Kenneth R. French, 1993, Common risk factors in the returns on stocks and bonds, Journal of Financial Economics 33, Fama, Eugene F., and Kenneth R. French, 1996, Multifactor explanations of asset pricing anomalies, Journal of Finance 51, Fama, Eugene F., and Kenneth R. French, 2006, The value premium and the CAPM, Journal of Finance 61, Fama, Eugene F., and Kenneth R. French, 2008, Dissecting anomalies, Journal of Finance 63, Fama, Eugene F., and James MacBeth, 1973, Risk, return, and equilibrium: Empirical tests, Journal of Political Economy 81, Ferguson, Michael F., and Richard L. Shockley, 2003, Equilibrium anomalies, Journal of Finance 58, Ferson, Wayne E., and Campbell R. Harvey, 1999, Conditioning variables and the cross section of stock returns, Journal of Finance 54, Ferson, Wayne E., Shmuel Kandel, and Robert F. Stambaugh, 1987, Tests of asset pricing with time-varying expected risk premiums and market betas, Journal of Finance 42, Ferson, Wayne E., Sergei Sarkissian, and Timothy Simin, 2003, Spurious regressions in financial economics? Journal of Finance 58,

38 Ferson, Wayne E., Sergei Sarkissian, and Timothy Simin, 2008, Asset pricing models with conditional betas and alphas: The effects of data snooping and spurious regression, Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 43, Ghysels, Eric, 1998, On stable factor structures in the pricing of risk: Do time-varying betas help or hurt? Journal of Finance 53, Guo, Hui, 2006, Time-varying risk premia and the cross section of stock returns, Journal of Banking and Finance 30, Guo, Hui, and Robert Savickas, 2008, Average idiosyncratic volatility in G7 countries, Review of Financial Studies 21, Grundy, Bruce, and J. Spencer Martin, 2001, Understanding the nature of the risks and the source of the rewards to momentum investing, Review of Financial Studies 14, Hahn, Jaehoon, and Hangyong Lee, 2006, Yield spreads as alternative risk factors for size and book-to-market, Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 41, Hansen, Lars P., 1982, Large sample properties of generalized method of moments estimators, Econometrica 50, Hansen, Lars P., and Scott F. Richard, 1987, The role of conditioning information in deducing testable restrictions implied by dynamic asset pricing models, Econometrica 55, Harvey, Campbell R., 1989, Time-varying conditional covariances in tests of asset pricing models, Journal of Financial Economics 24, He, Zhongzhi, Sahn-Wook Huh, and Bong-Soo Lee, 2010, Dynamic factors and asset pricing, Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 45, He, Jia, Raymond Kan, Lilian Ng, and Chu Zhang, 1996, Tests of the relations among marketwide factors, firm-specific variables, and stock returns using a conditional asset pricing model, Journal of Finance 51, Hodrick, Robert J., 1992, Dividend yields and expected stock returns: Alternative procedures for inference and measurement, Review of Financial Studies 5, Hodrick, Robert J., and Xiaoyan Zhang, 2001, Evaluating the specification errors of asset pricing models, Journal of Financial Economics 62, Jagannathan, Ravi, and Yong Wang, 2007, Lazy investors, discretionary consumption, and the cross-section of stock returns, Journal of Finance 62,

39 Jagannathan, Ravi, and Zhenyu Wang, 1996, The conditional CAPM and the cross-section of expected returns, Journal of Finance 51, Jegadeesh, Narasimhan, and Sheridan Titman, 1993, Returns to buying winners and selling losers: Implications for stock market efficiency, Journal of Finance 48, Jensen, Gerald R., Jeffrey M. Mercer, and Robert R. Johnson, 1996, Business conditions, monetary policy, and expected security returns, Journal of Financial Economics 40, Johnson, Timothy, 2002, Rational momentum effects, Journal of Finance 57, Keim, Donald, and Robert Stambaugh, 1986, Predicting returns in the stock and bond markets, Journal of Financial Economics 17, Koijen, Ralph S.J., Hanno Lustig, and Stijn Van Nieuwerburgh, 2010, The cross-section and time-series of stock and bond returns, Working paper, University of Chicago Booth School of Business. Lakonishok, Josef, Andrei Shleifer, and Robert W. Vishny, 1994, Contrarian investment, extrapolation, and risk, Journal of Finance 49, Lettau, Martin, and Sydney Ludvigson, 2001, Resurrecting the (C)CAPM: A cross sectional test when risk premia are time-varying, Journal of Political Economy 109, Lettau, Martin, and Jessica A. Wachter, 2007, Why is long-horizon equity less risky? A durationbased explanation of the value premium, Journal of Finance 62, Lewellen, Jonathan, 1999, The time-series relations among expected return, risk, and book-tomarket, Journal of Financial Economics 54, Lewellen, Jonathan, Stefan Nagel, and Jay Shanken, 2010, A skeptical appraisal of asset-pricing tests, Journal of Financial Economics 96, Lintner, J., 1965, The valuation of risk assets and the selection of risky investments in stock portfolios and capital budgets, Review of Economics and Statistics 47, Liu, Laura X., and Lu Zhang, 2008, Momentum profits, factor pricing, and macroeconomic risk, Review of Financial Studies 21, Maio, Paulo, 2011, Intertemporal CAPM with conditioning variables, Working paper, Durham Business School. Maio, Paulo, and Pedro Santa-Clara, 2011, The time-series and cross-sectional consistency of the ICAPM, Working paper, Nova School of Business and Economics. 37

40 Merton, Robert C., 1973, An intertemporal capital asset pricing model, Econometrica 41, Nielsen, Lars T., and Maria Vassalou, 2006, The instantaneous capital market line, Economic Theory 28, Patelis, Alex D., 1997, Stock return predictability and the role of monetary policy, Journal of Finance 52, Petkova, Ralitsa, 2006, Do the Fama-French factors proxy for innovations in predictive variables? Journal of Finance, 61, Petkova, Ralitsa, and Lu Zhang, 2005, Is value riskier than growth? Journal of Financial Economics 78, Rosenberg, Barr, Kenneth Reid, and Ronald Lanstein, 1985, Persuasive evidence of market inefficiency, Journal of Portfolio Management 11, Sagi, Jacob S., and Mark S. Seasholes, 2007, Firm-specific attributes and the cross-section of momentum, Journal of Financial Economics 84, Shanken, Jay, 1990, Intertemporal asset pricing: An empirical investigation, Journal of Econometrics 45, Shanken, Jay, 1992, On the estimation of beta pricing models, Review of Financial Studies 5, Shanken, Jay, and Guofu Zhou, 2007, Estimating and testing beta pricing models: Alternative methods and their performance in simulations, Journal of Financial Economics 84, Sharpe, W., 1964, Capital asset prices: A theory of market equilibrium under conditions of risk, Journal of Finance 19, Stein, Charles M., 1981, Estimation of the mean of a multivariate normal distribution, The Annals of Statistics 9, Stivers, Chris, and Licheng Sun, 2010, Cross-sectional return dispersion and time variation in value and momentum premiums, Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 45, Thorbecke, Willem, 1997, On stock market returns and monetary policy, Journal of Finance 52,

41 Vassalou, Maria, 2003, News related to future GDP growth as a risk factor in equity returns, Journal of Financial Economics 68, Wang, Kevin Q., 2003, Asset pricing with conditioning information: A new test, Journal of Finance 58, White, H., 1980, A heteroskedasticity-consistent covariance matrix estimator and a direct test for heteroskedasticity, Econometrica 48, Yogo, Motohiro, 2006, A consumption-based explanation of expected stock returns, Journal of Finance 61,

42 A Derivation of the ICAPM in discrete time The problem for the representative investor in the economy is stated as J (W t, z t ) max {C t+j } j=0,{ω i,t+j} j=0 E t δ j U (C t+j ) j=0 W t+1 = R p,t+1 (W t C t ) s.t. R p,t+1 = g (z t ) + ε t+1 R p,t+1 = N i=1 ω i,tr i,t+1 and can be represented in a dynamic programming framework, as follows:, J (W t, z t ) max {U (C t ) + δ E t [J (W t+1, z t+1 )]} C t,ω i,t W t+1 = R p,t+1 (W t C t ) s.t. R p,t+1 = g (z t ) + ε t+1, (A.1) R p,t+1 = N i=1 ω i,tr i,t+1 where J (W t, z t ) denotes the time t value function; U (C t ) denotes the utility over consumption; R p,t+1 is the gross return on the aggregate portfolio; z t is the state variable that forecasts R p,t+1 ; ω i,t is the weight for asset i in the representative investor s portfolio; and δ is a time-subjective discount factor. 25 ε t+1 represents a forecasting error, and g (z t ) denotes a function of the state variable that represents the component of the market return that is predictable by the state variable. The first-order condition (f.o.c.) with respect to C t is equal to U C (C t ) = δ E t [J W (W t+1, z t+1 ) R p,t+1 ], (A.2) where U C ( ) and J W ( ) denote the first-order partial derivatives of U( ) relative to C t and J ( ) with respect to W t+1, respectively. The return on aggregate wealth can be rewritten as R p,t+1 = N 1 i=1 ω i,t (R i,t+1 R f,t+1 ) + R f,t+1, (A.3) 25 For notational convenience we assume there is only one state variable, i.e., z t is a scalar. 40

43 where R f,t+1 denotes a benchmark return (for example, the risk-free rate), and where we impose the constraint that the portfolio weights must sum up to 1, N i=1 ω i,t = Then, the f.o.c. with respect to ω i,t is given by E t [J W (W t+1, z t+1 ) (W t C t ) (R i,t+1 R f,t+1 )] = 0. (A.4) By applying the envelope theorem to (A.1), J W ( ) can be represented as J W (W t, z t ) = C t W t {U C (C t ) δ E t [J W (W t+1, z t+1 ) R p,t+1 ]} + δ E t [J W (W t+1, z t+1 ) R p,t+1 ] + ω i,t W t E t [J W (W t+1, z t+1 ) (W t C t ) (R i,t+1 R f,t+1 )]. (A.5) By using Equations (A.2) and (A.4), Equation (A.5) simplifies to J W (W t, z t ) = δ E t [J W (W t+1, z t+1 ) R p,t+1 ], (A.6) and by combining with Equation (A.2), this leads to the usual envelope condition: J W (W t, z t ) = U C (C t ). (A.7) By updating (A.7), substituting the result in (A.2), and rearranging, we obtain the Euler equation: [ 1 = E t δ U ] [ C(C t+1 ) U C (C t ) R p,t+1 = E t δ J ] W (W t+1, z t+1 ) R p,t+1. (A.8) J W (W t, z t ) Given (A.8), we can substitute consumption out of the model, and the resulting stochastic discount factor (SDF) is equal to M t+1 = δ J W (W t+1, z t+1 ). (A.9) J W (W t, z t ) To derive the Euler equation for an arbitrary individual risky return, R i,t+1, by using the law of iterated expectations, the f.o.c. with respect to ω i,t can be rewritten as E t (M t+1 R i,t+1 ) = E t (M t+1 R f,t+1 ). (A.10) 26 The normalization that the benchmark return is the Nth asset does not play any role in the derivation. 41

44 By substituting (A.3) in (A.8), and rearranging, we obtain, 1 = N 1 i=1 ω i,t E t [M t+1 (R i,t+1 R f,t+1 )] + E t (M t+1 R f,t+1 ). (A.11) By using (A.10), we derive the pricing equation for asset i: 1 = E t (M t+1 R f,t+1 ) = E t (M t+1 R i,t+1 ). (A.12) To linearize the model, we use the general expected return-covariance representation: E t (R i,t+1 ) R f,t+1 = Cov t(r i,t+1 R f,t+1, M t+1 ). (A.13) E t (M t+1 ) By using Stein s lemma, we can rewrite the covariance term Cov t (R i,t+1 R f,t+1, M t+1 ) as: 27 [ Cov t (R i,t+1 R f,t+1, M t+1 ) = Cov t R i,t+1 R f,t+1, δ J ] W (W t+1, z t+1 ) J W (W t, z t ) δ = J W (W t, z t ) {E t[j W W (W t+1, z t+1 )] Cov t (R i,t+1 R f,t+1, W t+1 ) = + E t [J W z (W t+1, z t+1 )] Cov t (R i,t+1 R f,t+1, z t+1 )} ( δ {W t E t [J W W (W t+1, z t+1 )] Cov t R i,t+1 R f,t+1, W ) t+1 J W (W t, z t ) W t + E t [J W z (W t+1, z t+1 )] Cov t (R i,t+1 R f,t+1, z t+1 )}. (A.14) The conditional mean SDF is given by E t (M t+1 ) = δ J W (W t, z t ) E t[j W (W t+1, z t+1 )]. (A.15) By substituting Equations (A.14) and (A.15) into (A.13), we obtain: E t (R i,t+1 ) R f,t+1 = W t E t [J W W (W t+1, z t+1 )] E t [J W (W t+1, z t+1 )] ( Cov t R i,t+1 R f,t+1, W ) t+1 W t E t[j W z (W t+1, z t+1 )] E t [J W (W t+1, z t+1 )] Cov t(r i,t+1 R f,t+1, z t+1 ). (A.16) 27 For applications of the Stein (1981) lemma to asset pricing, see, for example, Brandt and Wang (2003), Cochrane (2005), and Balvers and Huang (2009). 42

45 Finally, by assuming the approximations, E t [J W (W t+1, z t+1 )] = J W (W t, z t ), E t [J W W (W t+1, z t+1 )] = J W W (W t, z t ), E t [J W z (W t+1, z t+1 )] = J W z (W t, z t ), we obtain the ICAPM pricing equation: E t (R i,t+1 ) R f,t+1 = γ Cov t (R i,t+1 R f,t+1, R m,t+1 ) J W z(w t, z t ) J W (W t, z t ) Cov t(r i,t+1 R f,t+1, z t+1 ), where γ WtJ W W (W t,z t) J W (W t,z t) (A.17) denotes the parameter of relative risk aversion (assumed to be constant), and we use the result from the intertemporal budget constraint that the return on aggregate wealth is approximately equal to the change in wealth, W t+1 W t R m,t Since Cov t (R i,t+1 R f,t+1, z t ) = 0, we use the innovation in the state variable, which is measured by the first difference in z t+1 : 29 z t+1 = z t+1 z t. (A.18) The resulting pricing equation is given by E t (R i,t+1 ) R f,t+1 = γ Cov t (R i,t+1 R f,t+1, R m,t+1 ) J W z(w t, z t ) J W (W t, z t ) Cov t(r i,t+1 R f,t+1, z t+1 ). (A.19) This specification is also consistent with the original ICAPM in continuous time, which is based on the innovations in the state variables. 28 This is true if consumption is low relative to wealth, C t W t. 29 The simple change corresponds to the innovation if the state variable follows a random-walk process. 43

46 B Cross-sectional regressions with GMM robust standard errors The GMM system equivalent to the time series/cross-sectional regressions approach has a set of moment conditions given by g T (Θ) = 1 T T t=1 (r t R f,t 1 N δ βf t ) T t=1 (r t R f,t 1 N δ βf t ) f t = T t=1 (r t R f,t 1 N βλ) 0 (N 1) 0 (NK 1) 0 (N 1), (B.20) where r t (N 1) is a vector of simple returns; 1 N (N 1) is a vector of ones; δ(n 1) is a vector of constants for the time series regressions; β(n K) is a matrix of K factor loadings for the N test assets; f t (K 1) is a vector of common factors used to price assets; λ(k 1) is a vector of beta risk prices; denotes the Kronecker product; and 0 denotes conformable vectors of zeros. The first two sets of moment conditions identify the factor loadings (including the constants or Jensen alphas), and thus are equivalent to the time-series regressions. These moment conditions are exactly identified with N + NK orthogonality conditions and N + NK parameters to estimate. The third set of moments corresponds to the cross-sectional regression, and identifies the beta risk prices, λ. Hence, the third set of moments has N moment conditions and K parameters to estimate, leading to N K overidentifying restrictions, which also corresponds to the number of overidentifying conditions in the entire system. System (B.20) represents a straightforward generalization of the system presented in Cochrane (2005) (Chapter 12), for the case of K > 1 risk factors affecting the cross-section of returns. The vector of parameters to estimate in this GMM system is given by Θ = [δ β λ ], (B.21) where β vec(β ), and vec is the operator that enables us to stack the factor loadings for the N assets into a column vector. The matrix that chooses which moment conditions are set to zero in the GMM first-order 44

47 condition, ag T ( ˆΘ) = 0, is given by 0 (N(K+1) N) a = I N I K+1 0 (K N(K+1)) β, (B.22) where I m denotes an identity matrix of order m. The matrix of sensitivities of the moment conditions to the parameters is given by d g T (Θ) Θ ( I N I N 1 ) T T t=1 f t ( = I N 1 ) ( T T t=1 f t I N 1 ) T T t=1 f tf t 0 (N N) I N λ β 0 (N K) 0 (NK K). (B.23) The variance-covariance matrix of the moments, S, has the form: r t R f,t 1 N δ βf t r t j R f,t j 1 N δ βf t j S = E (r t R f,t 1 N δ βf t ) f t (r t j R f,t j 1 N δ βf t j ) f t j j= r t R f,t 1 N βλ r t j R f,t j 1 N βλ = j= E ɛ t ɛ t f t β(f t E(f t )) + ɛ t ɛ t j ɛ t j f t j β(f t j E(f t )) + ɛ t j, (B.24) where ɛ t r t R f,t 1 N δ βf t, represents the vector of time-series residuals. In the last equality, we impose the null that the asset pricing model relation is true, E (r t R f,t 1 N ) = βλ: r t R f,t 1 N βλ = r t R f,t 1 N E (r t R f,t 1 N ) = r t R f,t 1 N δ β E(f t ) = β(f t E(f t )) + ɛ t. (B.25) By using the general GMM formula for the variance-covariance matrix of the parameter estimates, Var( ˆΘ) = 1 T (ad) 1 aŝa (ad) 1, (B.26) the last K elements of the main diagonal give the variances of the estimated factor risk prices, used to calculate the t-statistics. In addition, if we use the formula for the variance-covariance matrix of the GMM moment 45

48 conditions (errors), Var(g T ( ˆΘ)) = 1 T ( ( I N(K+2) d(ad) a) 1 Ŝ I N(K+2) d(ad) a) 1, (B.27) we obtain the covariance matrix of the cross-sectional pricing errors ( ˆα) from the bottom-right (N N) block of Var(g T ( ˆΘ)), which is used to conduct the test that the pricing errors are jointly equal to zero: ˆα Var( ˆα) 1 ˆα χ 2 (N K). (B.28) The Shanken (1992) standard errors can be derived as a special case of the GMM robust standard errors derived above, as noted by Cochrane (2005) (Chapter 12). If we assume that ɛ t is jointly i.i.d.; ɛ t and f t are independent; and finally f t has no serial correlation, then the spectral density matrix S in (B.24) specializes to ɛ t ɛ t S = E ɛ t f t ɛ t f t β(f t E(f t )) + ɛ t β(f t E(f t )) + ɛ t Σ Σ E(f t) Σ = Σ E(f t ) Σ E(f t f t) Σ E(f t ), Σ Σ E(f t) βσ f β + Σ (B.29) where Σ f E [(f t E(f t ))(f t E(f t )) ] represents the variance-covariance matrix associated with the factors, and Σ E(ɛ t ɛ t) denotes the variance-covariance matrix associated with the residuals from the time-series regressions. By replacing (B.29) in (B.26) we obtain the Shanken variances for the estimated factor risk premia: Var(ˆλ) = 1 T [ (β β ) 1 β Σβ ( β β ) 1 ( 1 + λ Σ 1 f λ ) + Σ f ]. (B.30) Similarly, the Shanken variances for pricing errors are given by Var(ˆα) = 1 T ( I N β ( β β ) ) ( 1 β Σ I N β ( β β ) ) ( ) 1 β 1 + λ Σ 1 f λ. (B.31) 46

49 C GMM formulas Following Cochrane (2005), the weighting matrix associated with the GMM system (16) is given by W = W 0, 0 I K (C.32) where W = I N is an N-dimensional identity matrix; 0 denotes a conformable matrix of zeros; and I K denotes a K-dimensional identity matrix, with K representing the number of factors in the model. In this specification, W is the weighting matrix for the first N moment conditions (corresponding to the N pricing errors), while I K is the weighting matrix associated with the last K orthogonality conditions that identify the factor means. The risk price estimates ˆb have variance formulas given by Var(ˆb) = 1 T (d Wd) 1 d WŜWd(d Wd) 1, (C.33) where d g T (b) b represents the matrix of moments sensitivities to the parameters; and Ŝ is an estimator for the spectral density matrix S derived under the heteroskedasticity-robust or White (1980) standard errors (that is, no lags of the moment functions are considered in the computation of Ŝ). The variance covariance matrix for the moments from first-stage GMM is given by ( ) Var g T (ˆb) = 1 T ( ( I N+K d(d Wd) 1 d W) Ŝ I N+K Wd(d Wd) 1 d ), (C.34) where the first (N, N) block of (C.34) represents the covariance matrix of the N pricing errors. 47

50 Table 1: Descriptive statistics for (C)ICAPM factors This table reports descriptive statistics for the risk factors from the (C)ICAPM and alternative factor models. RM t+1, RM t+1 z t and z t+1 denote the market, scaled and intertemporal risk factors from the (C)ICAPM. The conditioning variables (z) are the Fed funds rate (F F R) and the relative T-bill rate (RREL). SMB t+1, HML t+1, and UMD t+1 denote the size, value, and momentum factors, respectively. The sample is 1963: :12. φ designates the first order autocorrelation coefficient. The correlations between the state variables are presented in Panel B. Panel A Mean (%) Stdev. (%) Min. (%) Max. (%) φ RM t SMB t HML t UMD t RM t+1 F F R t F F R t RM t+1 RREL t RREL t Panel B SMB t+1 HML t+1 UMD t+1 RM t+1 F F R t F F R t+1 RM t+1 RREL t RREL t+1 RM t SMB t HML t UMD t RM t+1 F F R t F F R t RM t+1 RREL t RREL t

51 Table 2: Factor risk premia for (C)ICAPM This table reports the estimation and evaluation results for the three-factor Conditional Intertemporal CAPM ((C)ICAPM). The estimation procedure is the time-series/cross-sectional regressions approach. The test portfolios are the 25 size/book-to-market portfolios (SBM25, Panel A) and 25 size/momentum portfolios (SM25, Panel B). λ M denotes the beta risk price estimate for the market factor; λ M,z denotes the risk price associated with the scaled factor; and λ z represents the risk price associated with the intertemporal risk factor. The conditioning variables (z) are the Fed funds rate (F F R) and the relative T-bill rate (RREL). Below the risk price estimates (in %) are displayed t-statistics based on Shanken standard errors (in parenthesis). The column labeled MAE(%) presents the mean absolute pricing error (in %), and the column labeled R 2 OLS denotes the cross-sectional OLS R2. The column labeled χ 2 presents the χ 2 statistic (first line), and associated asymptotic p-values (in parenthesis) for the test on the joint significance of the pricing errors. The sample is 1963: :12. Italic, underlined and bold numbers denote statistical significance at the 10%, 5% and 1% levels, respectively. λ M λ M,z λ z χ 2 MAE(%) Panel A (SBM25) ROLS 2 F F R (2.22) ( 0.20) ( 2.83) (0.06) RREL (2.57) (1.05) ( 2.90) (0.09) Panel B (SM25) F F R (3.22) (4.50) ( 1.54) (0.00) RREL (2.32) (3.23) ( 2.08) (0.04) 49

52 Table 3: Factor risk premia for alternative factor models This table reports the estimation and evaluation results for alternative models the CAPM (Row 1), the Fama-French three-factor model (Row 2) and the Carhart four-factor model (Row 3). The estimation procedure is the time-series/cross-sectional regressions approach. The test portfolios are the 25 size/book-to-market portfolios (SBM25, Panel A) and 25 size/momentum portfolios (SM25, Panel B). λ M, λ SMB, λ HML, λ UMD denote the beta risk price estimates for the market, size, value and momentum factors, respectively. Below the risk price estimates (in %) are displayed t-statistics based on Shanken standard errors (in parenthesis). The column labeled MAE(%) presents the mean absolute pricing error (in %), and the column labeled ROLS 2 denotes the cross-sectional OLS R2. The column labeled χ 2 presents the χ 2 statistic (first line), and associated asymptotic p-values (in parenthesis) for the test on the joint significance of the pricing errors. The sample is 1963: :12. Italic, underlined and bold numbers denote statistical significance at the 10%, 5% and 1% levels, respectively. Row λ M λ SMB λ HML λ UMD χ 2 MAE(%) Panel A (SBM25) ROLS (2.94) (0.00) (2.07) (1.62) (3.81) (0.00) (2.43) (1.59) (3.67) (3.72) (0.05) Panel B (SM25) (2.56) (0.00) (2.53) (3.05) ( 2.82) (0.00) (2.64) (1.40) (2.13) (4.37) (0.00) 50

53 Table 4: Average risk premia across book-to-market and momentum quintiles This table reports the average risk premium (average beta times (beta) risk price) for each factor, across quintiles for book-to-market (BM) and prior short-term returns (momentum, M). The model is the three-factor (C)ICAPM when the state variables (z) are the Fed funds rate (F F R) and the relative T-bill rate (RREL). E(R) denotes the average excess return for each BM and M quintile, and α represents the average pricing error per quintile. RM t+1, RM t+1 z t and z t+1 denote the market, scaled and intertemporal risk factors from the (C)ICAPM. All the values are presented in percentage points. BM1 and M1 denote the lowest BM and M quintile, respectively, and Dif. denotes the difference across extreme quintiles. The sample is 1963: :12. E(R) RM t+1 RM t+1 z t z t+1 ᾱ Panel A (F F R) BM BM Dif M M Dif Panel B (RREL) BM BM Dif M M Dif Table 5: Average risk premia across BM and momentum quintiles: Alternative models This table reports the average risk premium (average beta times (beta) risk price) for each factor, across quintiles for book-to-market (BM) and prior short-term returns (momentum, M). The models are the Fama-French model (FF3, Panel A), and the Carhart model (C4, Panel B). E(R) denotes the average excess return for each BM and M quintile, and α represents the average pricing error per quintile. RM, SMB, HML, and UMD denote the market, size, value, and momentum factors, respectively. All the values are presented in percentage points. BM 1 and M 1 denote the lowest BM and M quintile, respectively, and Dif. denotes the difference across extreme quintiles. The sample is 1963: :12. Panel A: FF3 E(R) RM t+1 SMB t+1 HML t+1 ᾱ BM BM Dif M M Dif Panel B: C4 E(R) RM t+1 SMB t+1 HML t+1 UMD t+1 ᾱ BM BM Dif M M Dif

54 Table 6: Time-series regressions for HML and UMD This table reports the results from time-series regressions of HML (Panel A) and UMD (Panel B) on the (C)ICAPM factors, RM t+1, RM t+1 z t and z t+1. The conditioning variables (z) are the Fed funds rate (F F R) and the relative T-bill rate (RREL). Below the coefficient estimates are displayed heteroskedasticity-robust t-statistics (in parenthesis). The column labeled R 2 denotes the adjusted coefficient of determination. The sample is 1963: :12. Italic, underlined and bold numbers denote statistical significance at the 10%, 5% and 1% levels, respectively. const. RM t+1 RM t+1 z t z t+1 R 2 Panel A (HML t+1 ) F F R (3.88) ( 5.54) ( 4.56) ( 3.80) RREL (4.07) ( 6.06) ( 1.48) ( 3.77) Panel B (UMD t+1 ) F F R (5.04) ( 2.48) (3.45) (1.47) RREL (5.09) ( 1.81 ) (4.01) (2.15) Table 7: Factor risk premia for (C)ICAPM: Bond returns This table reports the estimation and evaluation results for the three-factor Conditional Intertemporal CAPM ((C)ICAPM). The estimation procedure is the time-series/cross-sectional regressions approach. The test portfolios are 7 Treasury bond returns plus 25 equity portfolios. The equity portfolios are the 25 size/book-to-market portfolios (SBM25, Panel A) and 25 size/momentum portfolios (SM25, Panel B). λ M denotes the beta risk price estimate for the market factor; λ M,z denotes the risk price associated with the scaled factor; and λ z represents the risk price associated with the intertemporal risk factor. The conditioning variables (z) are the Fed funds rate (F F R) and the relative T-bill rate (RREL). Below the risk price estimates (in %) are displayed t-statistics based on Shanken standard errors (in parenthesis). The column labeled MAE(%) presents the mean absolute pricing error (in %), and the column labeled R 2 OLS denotes the cross-sectional OLS R2. The column labeled χ 2 presents the χ 2 statistic (first line), and associated asymptotic p-values (in parenthesis) for the test on the joint significance of the pricing errors. The sample is 1963: :12. Italic, underlined and bold numbers denote statistical significance at the 10%, 5% and 1% levels, respectively. λ M λ M,z λ z χ 2 MAE(%) Panel A (SBM25) ROLS 2 F F R (2.29) ( 1.34) ( 3.19) (0.01) RREL (3.05) ( 1.15) ( 2.66) (0.00) Panel B (SM25) F F R (3.33) (4.31) (0.51) (0.00) RREL (2.57) (3.86) ( 1.33) (0.00) 52

55 Table 8: Factor risk premia for (C)ICAPM (30 portfolios) This table reports the estimation and evaluation results for the three-factor Conditional Intertemporal CAPM ((C)ICAPM). The estimation procedure is the time-series/cross-sectional regressions approach. The test portfolios are 10 portfolios sorted on size, 10 portfolios sorted on book-to-market and 10 momentum portfolios. λ M denotes the beta risk price estimate for the market factor; λ M,z denotes the risk price associated with the scaled factor; and λ z represents the risk price associated with the intertemporal risk factor. The conditioning variables (z) are the Fed funds rate (F F R) and the relative T-bill rate (RREL). Below the risk price estimates (in %) are displayed t-statistics based on Shanken standard errors (in parenthesis). The column labeled MAE(%) presents the mean absolute pricing error (in %), and the column labeled R 2 OLS denotes the cross-sectional OLS R2. The column labeled χ 2 presents the χ 2 statistic (first line), and associated asymptotic p-values (in parenthesis) for the test on the joint significance of the pricing errors. The sample is 1963: :12. Italic, underlined and bold numbers denote statistical significance at the 10%, 5% and 1% levels, respectively. λ M λ M,z λ z χ 2 MAE(%) ROLS 2 F F R (2.59) (3.14) ( 2.90) (0.13) RREL (2.45) (3.46) ( 2.31) (0.19) Table 9: Factor risk premia for (C)ICAPM: Estimation by GMM This table reports the estimation and evaluation results for the three-factor Conditional Intertemporal CAPM ((C)ICAPM). The estimation procedure is first-stage GMM with equally weighted errors. The test portfolios are the 25 size/book-to-market portfolios (SBM25, Panel A) and 25 size/momentum portfolios (SM25, Panel B). γ M denotes the (covariance) risk price estimate for the market factor; γ M,z denotes the risk price associated with the scaled factor; and γ z represents the risk price associated with the intertemporal risk factor. The conditioning variables (z) are the Fed funds rate (F F R) and the relative T-bill rate (RREL). The first line associated with each row presents the covariance risk price estimates, and the second line reports the asymptotic GMM robust t-statistics (in parenthesis). The column labeled MAE(%) presents the mean absolute pricing error (in %), and the column labeled ROLS 2 denotes the cross-sectional OLS R 2. The column labeled χ 2 presents the χ 2 statistic (first line), and associated asymptotic p-values (in parenthesis) for the test on the joint significance of the pricing errors. The sample is 1963: :12. Italic, underlined and bold numbers denote statistical significance at the 10%, 5% and 1% levels, respectively. γ M γ M,z γ z χ 2 MAE(%) Panel A (SBM25) ROLS 2 F F R ( 0.12) ( 1.23) ( 2.17) (0.01) RREL (0.03) (1.13) ( 3.19) (0.06) Panel B (SM25) F F R ( 0.13) (2.87) ( 0.92) (0.00) RREL (0.57) (2.51) ( 1.85 ) (0.02) 53

56 Table 10: Factor risk premia for nested models This table reports the estimation and evaluation results for nested models of the (C)ICAPM. The two nested models are the two-factor conditional CAPM (Row 1) and the two-factor ICAPM (Row 2). The estimation procedure is the time-series/cross-sectional regressions approach. The test portfolios are the 25 size/book-to-market portfolios (SBM25, Panels A and C) and 25 size/momentum portfolios (SM25, Panels B and D). λ M denotes the beta risk price estimate for the market factor; λ M,z denotes the risk price associated with the scaled factor; and λ z represents the risk price associated with the intertemporal risk factor. The conditioning variables (z) are the Fed funds rate (F F R) and the relative T-bill rate (RREL). Below the risk price estimates (in %) are displayed t-statistics based on Shanken standard errors (in parenthesis). The column labeled MAE(%) presents the mean absolute pricing error (in %), and the column labeled R 2 OLS denotes the cross-sectional OLS R2. The column labeled χ 2 presents the χ 2 statistic (first line), and associated asymptotic p-values (in parenthesis) for the test on the joint significance of the pricing errors. The sample is 1963: :12. Italic, underlined and bold numbers denote statistical significance at the 10%, 5% and 1% levels, respectively. Row λ M λ M,z λ z χ 2 MAE(%) Panel A (SBM25, F F R) ROLS (2.48) ( 3.43) (0.00) (2.17) ( 2.96) (0.25) Panel B (SM25, F F R) (3.31) (4.20) (0.00) (2.66) (0.54) (0.00) Panel C (SBM25, RREL) (3.21) ( 1.68 ) (0.00) (2.68) ( 2.81) (0.00) Panel D (SM25, RREL) (2.60) (3.79) (0.00) (2.54) (2.19) (0.00) 54

57 Table 11: Factor risk premia for (C)ICAPM (size/long-term reversal portfolios) This table reports the estimation and evaluation results for the three-factor Conditional Intertemporal CAPM ((C)ICAPM). The estimation procedure is the time-series/cross-sectional regressions approach. The test portfolios are the 25 size/long-term reversal portfolios (SLTR25). λ M denotes the beta risk price estimate for the market factor; λ M,z denotes the risk price associated with the scaled factor; and λ z represents the risk price associated with the intertemporal risk factor. The conditioning variables (z) are the Fed funds rate (F F R) and the relative T-bill rate (RREL). Below the risk price estimates (in %) are displayed t-statistics based on Shanken standard errors (in parenthesis). The column labeled MAE(%) presents the mean absolute pricing error (in %), and the column labeled ROLS 2 denotes the cross-sectional OLS R 2. The column labeled χ 2 presents the χ 2 statistic (first line), and associated asymptotic p-values (in parenthesis) for the test on the joint significance of the pricing errors. The sample is 1963: :12. Italic, underlined and bold numbers denote statistical significance at the 10%, 5% and 1% levels, respectively. λ M λ M,z λ z χ 2 MAE(%) ROLS 2 F F R (2.54) ( 0.61) ( 2.81) (0.02) RREL (2.47) (1.99) ( 2.63) (0.63) 55

58 Panel A: F F R Panel B: RREL Figure 1: Short-term interest rates This figure plots the time-series for the monthly changes in the Fed funds rate ( F F R) and the relative T-bill rate ( RREL). The sample is 1963: :12. The vertical lines indicate the NBER recession periods. 56

59 Panel A: pricing errors Panel B: t-statistics Figure 2: Individual pricing errors (F F R): SBM25 This figure plots the pricing errors (in %, Panel A), and respective t-statistics (Panel B) of the 25 size/book-to-market portfolios (SBM25) from the (C)ICAPM (version based on F F R); Fama-French model (FF3); and the Carhart model (C4). The pricing errors are obtained from an OLS cross-sectional regression of average excess returns on factor betas. ij designates a portfolio associated with the ith size quintile and jth book-to-market quintile. 57

60 Panel A: pricing errors Panel B: t-statistics Figure 3: Individual pricing errors (F F R): SM25 This figure plots the pricing errors (in %, Panel A), and respective t-statistics (Panel B) of the 25 size/momentum portfolios (SM25) from the (C)ICAPM (version based on F F R); Fama-French model (FF3); and the Carhart model (C4). The pricing errors are obtained from an OLS cross-sectional regression of average excess returns on factor betas. ij designates a portfolio associated with the ith size quintile and jth prior return quintile. 58

61 Panel A: RM t+1 F F R t Panel B: RM t+1 RREL t Panel C: F F R t+1 Panel D: RREL t+1 Figure 4: Regression betas for SBM25 This figure plots the multiple regression beta estimates associated with the SBM25 portfolios from (C)ICAPM. The factors are the scaled factor (RM t+1 F F R t, RM t+1 RREL t ) and the innovations in the state variable ( F F R t+1, RREL t+1 ). ij designates a portfolio associated with the ith size quintile and jth book-to-market quintile. The sample is 1963: :12. 59

62 Panel A: RM t+1 F F R t Panel B: RM t+1 RREL t Panel C: F F R t+1 Panel D: RREL t+1 Figure 5: Regression betas for SM25 This figure plots the multiple regression beta estimates associated with the SM25 portfolios from (C)ICAPM. The factors are the scaled factor (RM t+1 F F R t, RM t+1 RREL t ) and the innovations in the state variable ( F F R t+1, RREL t+1 ). ij designates a portfolio associated with the ith size quintile and jth prior return quintile. The sample is 1963: :12. 60

63 Panel A: All periods, F F R Panel B: All periods, RREL Panel C: Periods with high F F R Panel D: Periods with high RREL Panel E: Periods with low F F R Panel F: Periods with low RREL Figure 6: Average conditional market betas for SM25 This figure plots the average conditional market beta estimates associated with the SM25 portfolios from (C)ICAPM, β i,m + β i,m,z E(z t ). In Panels A and B all the periods are used, whereas in Panels C,D (E,F) only the61 periods in which F F R, RREL are 1.5 standard deviations above (below) the mean are used. ij designates a portfolio associated with the ith size quintile and jth prior return quintile. The sample is 1963: :12.

Does Mutual Fund Performance Vary over the Business Cycle?

Does Mutual Fund Performance Vary over the Business Cycle? Does Mutual Fund Performance Vary over the Business Cycle? Anthony W. Lynch New York University and NBER Jessica Wachter New York University and NBER Walter Boudry New York University First Version: 15

More information

Discussion of Momentum and Autocorrelation in Stock Returns

Discussion of Momentum and Autocorrelation in Stock Returns Discussion of Momentum and Autocorrelation in Stock Returns Joseph Chen University of Southern California Harrison Hong Stanford University Jegadeesh and Titman (1993) document individual stock momentum:

More information

Dividend yields, dividend growth, and return predictability. in the cross-section of stocks

Dividend yields, dividend growth, and return predictability. in the cross-section of stocks Dividend yields, dividend growth, and return predictability in the cross-section of stocks Paulo Maio 1 Pedro Santa-Clara 2 First version: June 2012 This version: November 2012 3 1 Hanken School of Economics.

More information

Dividend Yields, Dividend Growth, and Return Predictability in the Cross Section of Stocks

Dividend Yields, Dividend Growth, and Return Predictability in the Cross Section of Stocks JOURNAL OF FINANCIAL AND QUANTITATIVE ANALYSIS Vol. 50, Nos. 1/2, Feb./Apr. 2015, pp. 33 60 COPYRIGHT 2015, MICHAEL G. FOSTER SCHOOL OF BUSINESS, UNIVERSITY OF WASHINGTON, SEATTLE, WA 98195 doi:10.1017/s0022109015000058

More information

Is value riskier than growth? $

Is value riskier than growth? $ Journal of Financial Economics 78 (2005) 187 202 www.elsevier.com/locate/jfec Is value riskier than growth? $ Ralitsa Petkova a, Lu Zhang b,c, a Weatherhead School of Management, Case Western Reserve University,

More information

Does Mutual Fund Performance Vary over the Business Cycle?

Does Mutual Fund Performance Vary over the Business Cycle? Does Mutual Fund Performance Vary over the Business Cycle? Anthony W. Lynch New York University and NBER Jessica A. Wachter University of Pennsylvania and NBER First Version: 15 November 2002 Current Version:

More information

DOES IT PAY TO HAVE FAT TAILS? EXAMINING KURTOSIS AND THE CROSS-SECTION OF STOCK RETURNS

DOES IT PAY TO HAVE FAT TAILS? EXAMINING KURTOSIS AND THE CROSS-SECTION OF STOCK RETURNS DOES IT PAY TO HAVE FAT TAILS? EXAMINING KURTOSIS AND THE CROSS-SECTION OF STOCK RETURNS By Benjamin M. Blau 1, Abdullah Masud 2, and Ryan J. Whitby 3 Abstract: Xiong and Idzorek (2011) show that extremely

More information

Do Implied Volatilities Predict Stock Returns?

Do Implied Volatilities Predict Stock Returns? Do Implied Volatilities Predict Stock Returns? Manuel Ammann, Michael Verhofen and Stephan Süss University of St. Gallen Abstract Using a complete sample of US equity options, we find a positive, highly

More information

Asymmetric Volatility and the Cross-Section of Returns: Is Implied Market Volatility a Risk Factor?

Asymmetric Volatility and the Cross-Section of Returns: Is Implied Market Volatility a Risk Factor? Asymmetric Volatility and the Cross-Section of Returns: Is Implied Market Volatility a Risk Factor? R. Jared Delisle James S. Doran David R. Peterson Florida State University Draft: June 6, 2009 Acknowledgements:

More information

New Zealand mutual funds: measuring performance and persistence in performance

New Zealand mutual funds: measuring performance and persistence in performance Accounting and Finance 46 (2006) 347 363 New Zealand mutual funds: measuring performance and persistence in performance Rob Bauer a,rogér Otten b, Alireza Tourani Rad c a ABP Investments and Limburg Institute

More information

Broker-Dealer Leverage and the Cross-Section of Stock Returns 1

Broker-Dealer Leverage and the Cross-Section of Stock Returns 1 Broker-Dealer Leverage and the Cross-Section of Stock Returns 1 Tobias Adrian, Erkko Etula and Tyler Muir Federal Reserve Bank of New York and Northwestern University Bank of England, January -5, 11 1

More information

Stock market booms and real economic activity: Is this time different?

Stock market booms and real economic activity: Is this time different? International Review of Economics and Finance 9 (2000) 387 415 Stock market booms and real economic activity: Is this time different? Mathias Binswanger* Institute for Economics and the Environment, University

More information

The capital asset pricing model (CAPM) of William Sharpe (1964) and John

The capital asset pricing model (CAPM) of William Sharpe (1964) and John Journal of Economic Perspectives Volume 18, Number 3 Summer 2004 Pages 25 46 The Capital Asset Pricing Model: Theory and Evidence Eugene F. Fama and Kenneth R. French The capital asset pricing model (CAPM)

More information

Integration of the Mexican Stock Market. Abstract

Integration of the Mexican Stock Market. Abstract Integration of the Mexican Stock Market Alonso Gomez Albert Department of Economics University of Toronto Version 02.02.06 Abstract In this paper, I study the ability of multi-factor asset pricing models

More information

Does the Stock Market React to Unexpected Inflation Differently Across the Business Cycle?

Does the Stock Market React to Unexpected Inflation Differently Across the Business Cycle? Does the Stock Market React to Unexpected Inflation Differently Across the Business Cycle? Chao Wei 1 April 24, 2009 Abstract I find that nominal equity returns respond to unexpected inflation more negatively

More information

B.3. Robustness: alternative betas estimation

B.3. Robustness: alternative betas estimation Appendix B. Additional empirical results and robustness tests This Appendix contains additional empirical results and robustness tests. B.1. Sharpe ratios of beta-sorted portfolios Fig. B1 plots the Sharpe

More information

Appendices with Supplementary Materials for CAPM for Estimating Cost of Equity Capital: Interpreting the Empirical Evidence

Appendices with Supplementary Materials for CAPM for Estimating Cost of Equity Capital: Interpreting the Empirical Evidence Appendices with Supplementary Materials for CAPM for Estimating Cost of Equity Capital: Interpreting the Empirical Evidence This document contains supplementary material to the paper titled CAPM for estimating

More information

W ORKING PAPERS SES. A Note on the Impact of Portfolio Overlapping in Tests of the Fama and French Three-Factor Model 11.

W ORKING PAPERS SES. A Note on the Impact of Portfolio Overlapping in Tests of the Fama and French Three-Factor Model 11. 11.2012 N 433 W ORKING PAPERS SES A Note on the Impact of Portfolio Overlapping in Tests of the Fama and French Three-Factor Model Martin Wallmeier and Kathrin Tauscher F ACULTÉ DES SCIENCES ECONOMIQUES

More information

Chap 3 CAPM, Arbitrage, and Linear Factor Models

Chap 3 CAPM, Arbitrage, and Linear Factor Models Chap 3 CAPM, Arbitrage, and Linear Factor Models 1 Asset Pricing Model a logical extension of portfolio selection theory is to consider the equilibrium asset pricing consequences of investors individually

More information

The Cross-Section of Volatility and Expected Returns

The Cross-Section of Volatility and Expected Returns THE JOURNAL OF FINANCE VOL. LXI, NO. 1 FEBRUARY 2006 The Cross-Section of Volatility and Expected Returns ANDREW ANG, ROBERT J. HODRICK, YUHANG XING, and XIAOYAN ZHANG ABSTRACT We examine the pricing of

More information

Investing in Foreign Currency is like Betting on your Intertemporal Marginal Rate of Substitution.

Investing in Foreign Currency is like Betting on your Intertemporal Marginal Rate of Substitution. Investing in Foreign Currency is like Betting on your Intertemporal Marginal Rate of Substitution. Hanno Lustig UCLA and NBER Adrien Verdelhan Boston University December 13, 2005 Abstract Investors earn

More information

Stock Return Momentum and Investor Fund Choice

Stock Return Momentum and Investor Fund Choice Stock Return Momentum and Investor Fund Choice TRAVIS SAPP and ASHISH TIWARI* Journal of Investment Management, forthcoming Keywords: Mutual fund selection; stock return momentum; investor behavior; determinants

More information

Momentum and Autocorrelation in Stock Returns

Momentum and Autocorrelation in Stock Returns Momentum and Autocorrelation in Stock Returns Jonathan Lewellen MIT Sloan School of Management This article studies momentum in stock returns, focusing on the role of industry, size, and book-to-market

More information

Internet Appendix to CAPM for estimating cost of equity capital: Interpreting the empirical evidence

Internet Appendix to CAPM for estimating cost of equity capital: Interpreting the empirical evidence Internet Appendix to CAPM for estimating cost of equity capital: Interpreting the empirical evidence This document contains supplementary material to the paper titled CAPM for estimating cost of equity

More information

Empirical Evidence on Capital Investment, Growth Options, and Security Returns

Empirical Evidence on Capital Investment, Growth Options, and Security Returns Empirical Evidence on Capital Investment, Growth Options, and Security Returns Christopher W. Anderson and Luis Garcia-Feijóo * ABSTRACT Growth in capital expenditures conditions subsequent classification

More information

On Selection Biases in Book-to-Market Based Tests of Asset Pricing Models. William J. Breen and Robert A. Korajczyk

On Selection Biases in Book-to-Market Based Tests of Asset Pricing Models. William J. Breen and Robert A. Korajczyk On Selection Biases in Book-to-Market Based Tests of Asset Pricing Models William J. Breen and Robert A. Korajczyk Northwestern University Direct correspondence to: Robert A. Korajczyk Kellogg Graduate

More information

Does Mutual Fund Performance Vary over the Business Cycle?

Does Mutual Fund Performance Vary over the Business Cycle? Does Mutual Fund Performance Vary over the Business Cycle? André de Souza Fordham University Anthony W. Lynch New York University and NBER Current Version: 9 August 2012 Comments welcome. This paper supersedes

More information

Good Times or Bad Times? Investors Uncertainty and Stock Returns

Good Times or Bad Times? Investors Uncertainty and Stock Returns Good Times or Bad Times? Investors Uncertainty and Stock Returns Arzu Ozoguz University of North Carolina at Chapel Hill This paper investigates empirically the dynamics of investors beliefs and Bayesian

More information

Fama and French Three-Factor Model: Evidence from Istanbul Stock Exchange

Fama and French Three-Factor Model: Evidence from Istanbul Stock Exchange Volume 4 Number 2 2013 pp. 11-22 ISSN: 1309-2448 www.berjournal.com Fama and French Three-Factor Model: Evidence from Istanbul Stock Exchange Veysel Eraslan a Abstract: This study tests the validity of

More information

The Risk-Free Rate s Impact on Stock Returns with Representative Fund Managers

The Risk-Free Rate s Impact on Stock Returns with Representative Fund Managers School of Economics and Management Department of Business Administration FEKN90 Business Administration- Degree Project Master of Science in Business and Economics Spring term of 2013 The Risk-Free Rate

More information

CAPM, Arbitrage, and Linear Factor Models

CAPM, Arbitrage, and Linear Factor Models CAPM, Arbitrage, and Linear Factor Models CAPM, Arbitrage, Linear Factor Models 1/ 41 Introduction We now assume all investors actually choose mean-variance e cient portfolios. By equating these investors

More information

Betting Against Beta

Betting Against Beta Betting Against Beta Andrea Frazzini AQR Capital Management LLC Lasse H. Pedersen NYU, CEPR, and NBER Preliminary Copyright 2010 by Andrea Frazzini and Lasse H. Pedersen Motivation Background: Security

More information

Financial Intermediaries and the Cross-Section of Asset Returns

Financial Intermediaries and the Cross-Section of Asset Returns Financial Intermediaries and the Cross-Section of Asset Returns Tobias Adrian - Federal Reserve Bank of New York 1 Erkko Etula - Goldman Sachs Tyler Muir - Kellogg School of Management May, 2012 1 The

More information

Stock Returns and Equity Premium Evidence Using Dividend Price Ratios and Dividend Yields in Malaysia

Stock Returns and Equity Premium Evidence Using Dividend Price Ratios and Dividend Yields in Malaysia Stock Returns and Equity Premium Evidence Using Dividend Price Ratios and Dividend Yields in Malaysia By David E. Allen 1 and Imbarine Bujang 1 1 School of Accounting, Finance and Economics, Edith Cowan

More information

Is the Value Spread a Useful Predictor of Returns?

Is the Value Spread a Useful Predictor of Returns? Is the Value Spread a Useful Predictor of Returns? Naiping Liu The Wharton School University of Pennsylvania Lu Zhang Stephen M. Ross School of Business University of Michigan and NBER September 2006 Abstract

More information

Online appendix to paper Downside Market Risk of Carry Trades

Online appendix to paper Downside Market Risk of Carry Trades Online appendix to paper Downside Market Risk of Carry Trades A1. SUB-SAMPLE OF DEVELOPED COUNTRIES I study a sub-sample of developed countries separately for two reasons. First, some of the emerging countries

More information

Financial Market Imgrad Models

Financial Market Imgrad Models Asset Pricing Implications of Firms Financing Constraints. Joao F. Gomes, Amir Yaron, and Lu Zhang October 2003 Abstract We use a production-based asset pricing model to investigate whether financial market

More information

The term structure of equity option implied volatility

The term structure of equity option implied volatility The term structure of equity option implied volatility Christopher S. Jones Tong Wang Marshall School of Business Marshall School of Business University of Southern California University of Southern California

More information

Can Investment Shocks Explain the Cross-section of Stock Returns?

Can Investment Shocks Explain the Cross-section of Stock Returns? Can Investment Shocks Explain the Cross-section of Stock Returns? Lorenzo Garlappi University of British Columbia Zhongzhi Song CKGSB This draft: August 2012 We are grateful to Laura Liu and seminar participants

More information

Chapter 5. Conditional CAPM. 5.1 Conditional CAPM: Theory. 5.1.1 Risk According to the CAPM. The CAPM is not a perfect model of expected returns.

Chapter 5. Conditional CAPM. 5.1 Conditional CAPM: Theory. 5.1.1 Risk According to the CAPM. The CAPM is not a perfect model of expected returns. Chapter 5 Conditional CAPM 5.1 Conditional CAPM: Theory 5.1.1 Risk According to the CAPM The CAPM is not a perfect model of expected returns. In the 40+ years of its history, many systematic deviations

More information

How to Discount Cashflows with Time-Varying Expected Returns

How to Discount Cashflows with Time-Varying Expected Returns THE JOURNAL OF FINANCE VOL. LIX, NO. 6 DECEMBER 2004 How to Discount Cashflows with Time-Varying Expected Returns ANDREW ANG and JUN LIU ABSTRACT While many studies document that the market risk premium

More information

Discussion of "The Cross Section and Time Series of Stock and Bond Returns" by Koijen, Lustig & Van Nieuwerburgh

Discussion of The Cross Section and Time Series of Stock and Bond Returns by Koijen, Lustig & Van Nieuwerburgh Discussion of "The Cross Section and Time Series of Stock and Bond Returns" by Koijen, Lustig & Van Nieuwerburgh Monika Piazzesi Stanford University & NBER AFA Atlanta 2010 Summary A ne model in which:

More information

A new measure of equity and cash flow duration: The duration-based explanation of the value premium revisited

A new measure of equity and cash flow duration: The duration-based explanation of the value premium revisited A new measure of equity and cash flow duration: The duration-based explanation of the value premium revisited David Schröder Birkbeck College, University of London Florian Esterer Bank J. Safra Sarasin

More information

A Review of Cross Sectional Regression for Financial Data You should already know this material from previous study

A Review of Cross Sectional Regression for Financial Data You should already know this material from previous study A Review of Cross Sectional Regression for Financial Data You should already know this material from previous study But I will offer a review, with a focus on issues which arise in finance 1 TYPES OF FINANCIAL

More information

Do the asset pricing factors predict future economy growth? An Australian study. Bin Liu Amalia Di Iorio

Do the asset pricing factors predict future economy growth? An Australian study. Bin Liu Amalia Di Iorio Do the asset pricing factors predict future economy growth? An Australian study. Bin Liu Amalia Di Iorio Abstract In this paper we examine whether past returns of the market portfolio (MKT), the size portfolio

More information

The Abnormal Performance of Bond Returns

The Abnormal Performance of Bond Returns The University of Reading THE BUSINESS SCHOOL FOR FINANCIAL MARKETS The Abnormal Performance of Bond Returns Joëlle Miffre ISMA Centre, The University of Reading, Reading, Berks., RG6 6BA, UK Copyright

More information

Absolute Strength: Exploring Momentum in Stock Returns

Absolute Strength: Exploring Momentum in Stock Returns Absolute Strength: Exploring Momentum in Stock Returns Huseyin Gulen Krannert School of Management Purdue University Ralitsa Petkova Weatherhead School of Management Case Western Reserve University March

More information

Luck versus Skill in the Cross-Section of Mutual Fund Returns

Luck versus Skill in the Cross-Section of Mutual Fund Returns THE JOURNAL OF FINANCE VOL. LXV, NO. 5 OCTOBER 2010 Luck versus Skill in the Cross-Section of Mutual Fund Returns EUGENE F. FAMA and KENNETH R. FRENCH ABSTRACT The aggregate portfolio of actively managed

More information

Journal of Financial Economics

Journal of Financial Economics Journal of Financial Economics 105 (2012) 457 472 Contents lists available at SciVerse ScienceDirect Journal of Financial Economics journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/jfec Size, value, and momentum

More information

Book-to-Market Equity, Distress Risk, and Stock Returns

Book-to-Market Equity, Distress Risk, and Stock Returns THE JOURNAL OF FINANCE VOL. LVII, NO. 5 OCTOBER 2002 Book-to-Market Equity, Distress Risk, and Stock Returns JOHN M. GRIFFIN and MICHAEL L. LEMMON* ABSTRACT This paper examines the relationship between

More information

LIQUIDITY AND ASSET PRICING. Evidence for the London Stock Exchange

LIQUIDITY AND ASSET PRICING. Evidence for the London Stock Exchange LIQUIDITY AND ASSET PRICING Evidence for the London Stock Exchange Timo Hubers (358022) Bachelor thesis Bachelor Bedrijfseconomie Tilburg University May 2012 Supervisor: M. Nie MSc Table of Contents Chapter

More information

Research Division Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Working Paper Series

Research Division Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Working Paper Series Research Division Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Working Paper Series Market Timing with Aggregate and Idiosyncratic Stock Volatilities Hui Guo and Jason Higbee Working Paper 2005-073B http://research.stlouisfed.org/wp/2005/2005-073.pdf

More information

The Time-Varying Liquidity Risk of Value and Growth Stocks

The Time-Varying Liquidity Risk of Value and Growth Stocks EDHEC-Risk Institute 393-400 promenade des Anglais 06202 Nice Cedex 3 Tel.: +33 (0)4 93 18 32 53 E-mail: research@edhec-risk.com Web: www.edhec-risk.com The Time-Varying Liquidity Risk of Value and Growth

More information

The Impact of Credit Risk and Implied Volatility on Stock Returns

The Impact of Credit Risk and Implied Volatility on Stock Returns The Impact of Credit Risk and Implied Volatility on Stock Returns Florian Steiger 1 Working Paper, May 2010 JEL Classification: G10, G12, G17 Abstract: This paper examines the possibility of using derivative-implied

More information

What Drives the Performance of US Convertible Bond Funds?

What Drives the Performance of US Convertible Bond Funds? What Drives the Performance of US Convertible Bond Funds? Manuel Ammann, Axel Kind, and Ralf Seiz May 2006 Abstract This paper examines the return characteristics of US mutual funds investing primarily

More information

Variance Risk Premium and Cross Section of Stock Returns

Variance Risk Premium and Cross Section of Stock Returns Variance Risk Premium and Cross Section of Stock Returns Bing Han and Yi Zhou This Version: December 2011 Abstract We use equity option prices and high frequency stock prices to estimate stock s variance

More information

Asian Economic and Financial Review THE CAPITAL INVESTMENT INCREASES AND STOCK RETURNS

Asian Economic and Financial Review THE CAPITAL INVESTMENT INCREASES AND STOCK RETURNS Asian Economic and Financial Review journal homepage: http://www.aessweb.com/journals/5002 THE CAPITAL INVESTMENT INCREASES AND STOCK RETURNS Jung Fang Liu 1 --- Nicholas Rueilin Lee 2 * --- Yih-Bey Lin

More information

ON THE IMPORTANCE OF MEASURING PAYOUT YIELD: IMPLICATIONS FOR EMPIRICAL ASSET PRICING

ON THE IMPORTANCE OF MEASURING PAYOUT YIELD: IMPLICATIONS FOR EMPIRICAL ASSET PRICING ON THE IMPORTANCE OF MEASURING PAYOUT YIELD: IMPLICATIONS FOR EMPIRICAL ASSET PRICING Jacob Boudoukh a, Roni Michaely b, Matthew Richardson c and Michael R. Roberts d* This Version: December 16, 2003 *

More information

A Behavioral Economics Exploration into the Volatility Anomaly *

A Behavioral Economics Exploration into the Volatility Anomaly * Policy Research Institute, Ministry of Finance, Japan, Public Policy Review, Vol.9, No.3, September 2013 457 A Behavioral Economics Exploration into the Volatility Anomaly * The NUCB Graduate School Equity

More information

How To Explain Momentum Anomaly In International Equity Market

How To Explain Momentum Anomaly In International Equity Market Does the alternative three-factor model explain momentum anomaly better in G12 countries? Steve Fan University of Wisconsin Whitewater Linda Yu University of Wisconsin Whitewater ABSTRACT This study constructs

More information

Firm Fundamentals and Variance Risk Premiums

Firm Fundamentals and Variance Risk Premiums Firm Fundamentals and Variance Risk Premiums Matthew R. Lyle and James P. Naughton August 2015 Abstract We develop and empirically test an accounting-based model that ties two firm characteristics, book-to-market

More information

What Level of Incentive Fees Are Hedge Fund Investors Actually Paying?

What Level of Incentive Fees Are Hedge Fund Investors Actually Paying? What Level of Incentive Fees Are Hedge Fund Investors Actually Paying? Abstract Long-only investors remove the effects of beta when analyzing performance. Why shouldn t long/short equity hedge fund investors

More information

Momentum and Credit Rating

Momentum and Credit Rating USC FBE FINANCE SEMINAR presented by Doron Avramov FRIDAY, September 23, 2005 10:30 am 12:00 pm, Room: JKP-104 Momentum and Credit Rating Doron Avramov Department of Finance Robert H. Smith School of Business

More information

Selection of Investment Strategies in Thai Stock Market.

Selection of Investment Strategies in Thai Stock Market. CMRI Working Paper 05/2014 Selection of Investment Strategies in Thai Stock Market. โดย ค ณธนะช ย บ ญสายทร พย สถาบ นบ ณฑ ตบร หารธ รก จ ศศ นทร แห งจ ฬาลงกรณ มหาว ทยาล ย เมษายน 2557 Abstract This paper examines

More information

Facts and Fantasies About Factor Investing

Facts and Fantasies About Factor Investing Zélia Cazalet Quantitative Research Lyxor Asset Management, Paris zelia.cazalet@lyxor.com Thierry Roncalli Quantitative Research Lyxor Asset Management, Paris thierry.roncalli@lyxor.com October 2014 Abstract

More information

The cross section of expected stock returns

The cross section of expected stock returns The cross section of expected stock returns Jonathan Lewellen Dartmouth College and NBER This version: August 2014 Forthcoming in Critical Finance Review Tel: 603-646-8650; email: jon.lewellen@dartmouth.edu.

More information

THE CAPITAL ASSET PRICING MODEL VERSUS THE THREE FACTOR MODEL: A United Kingdom Perspective

THE CAPITAL ASSET PRICING MODEL VERSUS THE THREE FACTOR MODEL: A United Kingdom Perspective P a g e 1 THE CAPITAL ASSET PRICING MODEL VERSUS THE THREE FACTOR MODEL: A United Kingdom Perspective Chandra Shekhar Bhatnagar Department of Social Sciences, The University of the West Indies, Trinidad

More information

The Term Structure of the Risk-Return Tradeoff

The Term Structure of the Risk-Return Tradeoff The Term Structure of the Risk-Return Tradeoff John Y. Campbell and Luis M. Viceira 1 Recent research in empirical finance has documented that expected excess returns on bonds and stocks, real interest

More information

The size effect in value and momentum factors: Implications for the cross-section of international stock returns

The size effect in value and momentum factors: Implications for the cross-section of international stock returns The size effect in value and momentum factors: Implications for the cross-section of international stock returns February 8, 013 Abstract Small stocks mimic common risks on equity markets. To reach this

More information

HARVARD UNIVERSITY Department of Economics

HARVARD UNIVERSITY Department of Economics HARVARD UNIVERSITY Department of Economics Economics 970 Behavioral Finance Science Center 103b Spring 2002 M, W 7-8:30 pm Mr. Evgeny Agronin Teaching Fellow agronin@fas.harvard.edu (617) 868-5766 Course

More information

Estimating firm-specific long term growth rate and cost of capital

Estimating firm-specific long term growth rate and cost of capital Estimating firm-specific long term growth rate and cost of capital Rong Huang, Ram Natarajan and Suresh Radhakrishnan School of Management, University of Texas at Dallas, Richardson, Texas 75083 November

More information

The Determinants of Stock and Bond Return Comovements

The Determinants of Stock and Bond Return Comovements The Determinants of Stock and Bond Return Comovements Lieven Baele Tilburg University, CentER, Netspar Geert Bekaert Columbia University, NBER, CEPR Koen Inghelbrecht Ghent University Research questions

More information

Trading Probability and Turnover as measures of Liquidity Risk: Evidence from the U.K. Stock Market. Ian McManus. Peter Smith.

Trading Probability and Turnover as measures of Liquidity Risk: Evidence from the U.K. Stock Market. Ian McManus. Peter Smith. Trading Probability and Turnover as measures of Liquidity Risk: Evidence from the U.K. Stock Market. Ian McManus (Corresponding author). School of Management, University of Southampton, Highfield, Southampton,

More information

Are Mutual Fund Shareholders Compensated for Active Management Bets?

Are Mutual Fund Shareholders Compensated for Active Management Bets? Are Mutual Fund Shareholders Compensated for Active Management Bets? Russ Wermers Department of Finance Robert H. Smith School of Business University of Maryland at College Park College Park, MD 2742-1815

More information

Price Momentum and Trading Volume

Price Momentum and Trading Volume THE JOURNAL OF FINANCE VOL. LV, NO. 5 OCT. 2000 Price Momentum and Trading Volume CHARLES M. C. LEE and BHASKARAN SWAMINATHAN* ABSTRACT This study shows that past trading volume provides an important link

More information

A Panel Data Analysis of Corporate Attributes and Stock Prices for Indian Manufacturing Sector

A Panel Data Analysis of Corporate Attributes and Stock Prices for Indian Manufacturing Sector Journal of Modern Accounting and Auditing, ISSN 1548-6583 November 2013, Vol. 9, No. 11, 1519-1525 D DAVID PUBLISHING A Panel Data Analysis of Corporate Attributes and Stock Prices for Indian Manufacturing

More information

Online Appendices to the Corporate Propensity to Save

Online Appendices to the Corporate Propensity to Save Online Appendices to the Corporate Propensity to Save Appendix A: Monte Carlo Experiments In order to allay skepticism of empirical results that have been produced by unusual estimators on fairly small

More information

Performance of UK Pension Funds. - Luck or Skill?

Performance of UK Pension Funds. - Luck or Skill? Performance of UK Pension Funds - Luck or Skill? Emelie Jomer Master Thesis, Department of Economics, Uppsala University June 7, 2013 Supervisor: Mikael Bask, Associate Professor of Economics, Uppsala

More information

The Risk Anomaly Tradeoff of Leverage *

The Risk Anomaly Tradeoff of Leverage * USC FBE FINANCE SEMINAR presented by Malcolm Baker FRIDAY, Dec. 5, 2014 10:30 am 12:00 pm, Room: JKP-102 The Risk Anomaly Tradeoff of Leverage * Malcolm Baker Harvard Business School and NBER Jeffrey Wurgler

More information

Is momentum really momentum?

Is momentum really momentum? Is momentum really momentum? Robert Novy-Marx Abstract Momentum is primarily driven by firms performance 12 to seven months prior to portfolio formation, not by a tendency of rising and falling stocks

More information

Expectations of Returns and Expected Returns *

Expectations of Returns and Expected Returns * Expectations of Returns and Expected Returns * Robin Greenwood and Andrei Shleifer Revised: January 2013 (First draft October 2012) Abstract We analyze time-series of investor expectations of future stock

More information

Cash Holdings and Mutual Fund Performance. Online Appendix

Cash Holdings and Mutual Fund Performance. Online Appendix Cash Holdings and Mutual Fund Performance Online Appendix Mikhail Simutin Abstract This online appendix shows robustness to alternative definitions of abnormal cash holdings, studies the relation between

More information

Cash-Flow News, Discount-Rate News and the Co-skewness Risk

Cash-Flow News, Discount-Rate News and the Co-skewness Risk Cash-Flow News, Discount-Rate News and the Co-skewness Risk Leon Zolotoy Melbourne Business School, University of Melbourne Petko S. Kalev Centre for Applied Financial Studies, School of Commerce, University

More information

Predicting Future Stock Market Performance using Style-Based Portfolio Returns. Yingying Shao* University of Arkansas

Predicting Future Stock Market Performance using Style-Based Portfolio Returns. Yingying Shao* University of Arkansas Predicting Future Stock Market Performance using Style-Based Portfolio Returns Yingying Shao* University of Arkansas Craig G. Rennie University of Arkansas This draft: Nov 14, 2007 Abstract This paper

More information

THE NUMBER OF TRADES AND STOCK RETURNS

THE NUMBER OF TRADES AND STOCK RETURNS THE NUMBER OF TRADES AND STOCK RETURNS Yi Tang * and An Yan Current version: March 2013 Abstract In the paper, we study the predictive power of number of weekly trades on ex-post stock returns. A higher

More information

Disentangling value, growth, and the equity risk premium

Disentangling value, growth, and the equity risk premium Disentangling value, growth, and the equity risk premium The discounted cash flow (DCF) model is a theoretically sound method to value stocks. However, any model is only as good as the inputs and, as JASON

More information

Portfolio Performance and Strategic Asset Allocation Across Different Economic Conditions

Portfolio Performance and Strategic Asset Allocation Across Different Economic Conditions Portfolio Performance and Strategic Asset Allocation Across Different Economic Conditions 1 Jarjisu Sa-Aadu *, James D. Shilling **, Ashish Tiwari *** ABSTRACT Motivated by the theoretical results on strategic

More information

Norges Bank s Expert Group on Principles for Risk Adjustment of Performance Figures Final Report

Norges Bank s Expert Group on Principles for Risk Adjustment of Performance Figures Final Report Norges Bank s Expert Group on Principles for Risk Adjustment of Performance Figures Final Report November 16, 2015 Magnus Dahlquist Professor, Stockholm School of Economics Christopher Polk Professor,

More information

Investment and the Term Structure of Stock Returns

Investment and the Term Structure of Stock Returns Investment and the Term Structure of Stock Returns Sandra Mortal Fogelman College of Business and Economics University of Memphis Memphis, TN 38152 scmortal@memphis.edu Michael J. Schill Darden Graduate

More information

Lecture 6: Arbitrage Pricing Theory

Lecture 6: Arbitrage Pricing Theory Lecture 6: Arbitrage Pricing Theory Investments FIN460-Papanikolaou APT 1/ 48 Overview 1. Introduction 2. Multi-Factor Models 3. The Arbitrage Pricing Theory FIN460-Papanikolaou APT 2/ 48 Introduction

More information

Market Efficiency and Behavioral Finance. Chapter 12

Market Efficiency and Behavioral Finance. Chapter 12 Market Efficiency and Behavioral Finance Chapter 12 Market Efficiency if stock prices reflect firm performance, should we be able to predict them? if prices were to be predictable, that would create the

More information

Short-Term Persistence in Mutual Fund Performance

Short-Term Persistence in Mutual Fund Performance Short-Term Persistence in Mutual Fund Performance Nicolas P. B. Bollen Vanderbilt University Jeffrey A. Busse Emory University We estimate parameters of standard stock selection and market timing models

More information

The Cost of Capital of the Financial Sector

The Cost of Capital of the Financial Sector Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Reports The Cost of Capital of the Financial Sector Tobias Adrian Evan Friedman Tyler Muir Staff Report No. 755 December 2015 This paper presents preliminary findings

More information

VOLATILITY FORECASTING FOR MUTUAL FUND PORTFOLIOS. Samuel Kyle Jones 1 Stephen F. Austin State University, USA E-mail: sjones@sfasu.

VOLATILITY FORECASTING FOR MUTUAL FUND PORTFOLIOS. Samuel Kyle Jones 1 Stephen F. Austin State University, USA E-mail: sjones@sfasu. VOLATILITY FORECASTING FOR MUTUAL FUND PORTFOLIOS 1 Stephen F. Austin State University, USA E-mail: sjones@sfasu.edu ABSTRACT The return volatility of portfolios of mutual funds having similar investment

More information

Equity returns following changes in default risk: New insights. into the informational content of credit ratings.

Equity returns following changes in default risk: New insights. into the informational content of credit ratings. Equity returns following changes in default risk: New insights into the informational content of credit ratings. Maria Vassalou and Yuhang Xing First Draft: October 30, 2002 This Draft: July 18, 2003 The

More information

Credit Ratings and The Cross-Section of Stock Returns

Credit Ratings and The Cross-Section of Stock Returns Credit Ratings and The Cross-Section of Stock Returns Doron Avramov Department of Finance Robert H. Smith School of Business University of Maryland davramov@rhsmith.umd.edu Tarun Chordia Department of

More information

Market sentiment and mutual fund trading strategies

Market sentiment and mutual fund trading strategies Nelson Lacey (USA), Qiang Bu (USA) Market sentiment and mutual fund trading strategies Abstract Based on a sample of the US equity, this paper investigates the performance of both follow-the-leader (momentum)

More information

Volatility and Premiums in US Equity Returns. Eugene F. Fama and Kenneth R. French *

Volatility and Premiums in US Equity Returns. Eugene F. Fama and Kenneth R. French * Volatility and Premiums in US Equity Returns Eugene F. Fama and Kenneth R. French * Understanding volatility is crucial for informed investment decisions. This paper explores the volatility of the market,

More information

Stocks with Extreme Past Returns: Lotteries or Insurance?

Stocks with Extreme Past Returns: Lotteries or Insurance? Stocks with Extreme Past Returns: Lotteries or Insurance? Alexander Barinov Terry College of Business University of Georgia E-mail: abarinov@terry.uga.edu http://abarinov.myweb.uga.edu/ This version: June

More information