Integration of the Mexican Stock Market. Abstract

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Integration of the Mexican Stock Market. Abstract"

Transcription

1 Integration of the Mexican Stock Market Alonso Gomez Albert Department of Economics University of Toronto Version Abstract In this paper, I study the ability of multi-factor asset pricing models to explain the unconditional and conditional cross-section of expected returns in Mexico. Two sets of factors, local and foreign factors, are evaluated consistent with the hypotheses of segmentation and of integration of the international finance literature. Only one variable, the Mexican U.S. exchange rate, appears in the list of both local and foreign factors. Empirical evidence suggests that the foreign factors do a better job explaining the cross-section of returns in Mexico in both the unconditional and conditional versions of the model. This evidence supports the hypothesis of integration of the Mexican stock exchange to the U.S. market. JEL Classification: G12, G15, F36. Keywords: Integration of Financial Markets, Linear Factor Models, Fama and French Factors, Unconditional Pricing, Conditional Pricing. I am grateful to Angelo Melino for helpful comments, suggestions and guidance. I also thank participants in the econometrics workshop at the University of Toronto. All remaining errors are mine. Alonso Gomez Albert, 150 St. George St., University of Toronto, Toronto, M5S3G7, Canada. Phone: (416) Fax:(416) agomez@chass.utoronto.ca.

2 1 Introduction The purpose of this paper is to study the determinants of equity returns in Mexico. The pricing performance of two sets of factors, inspired by the hypotheses of segmentation and integration of the Mexican stock exchange to the U.S. stock market, are evaluated. I examine the ability of multi-factor asset pricing models to explain the unconditional and conditional cross-section of expected returns of industry portfolios in Mexico. In the process I provide evidence on the integration of the Mexican and the U.S. stock markets. Financial markets have become steadily more open to foreign investors over the last forty years. Markets are considered integrated if assets with the same risk have identical expected returns regardless of their national status or where they are traded. Integrated capital markets provide the opportunity for better diversification and risk sharing and can lower the cost of capital for firms in emerging markets. Interest in emerging markets has rapidly grown in recent years as investors seek higher returns and international diversification. The average net capital flows to emerging market economies from 1995 to 2003 was billion U.S. dollars, of which 8 percent was portfolio investment 1. Foreign investment can have a significant impact on returns in emerging markets because they are generally small and illiquid compared to more mature international markets. Bekeart and Harvey (2000) present evidence of a negative relation between the cost of capital and the degree of integration with 1 International Monetary Fund, World Economic Outlook: Growth and Institutions, World Economic and Financial Surveys, April

3 the world market in emerging markets. Beginning in 1989, Mexico experienced a transformation from a closed and protected economy to one of the most open economies in Latin America (see Bekaert, Harvey and Lundblad (2003)), what increased the participation of foreign investors in Mexico. Figure 1 presents the growth in portfolio investment by foreigners from the beginning of 1990 to the end of By 1994, after the Mexican Peso s devaluation of almost 70%, control of the exchange rate was eliminated. Domestic companies sought to broaden their shareholder base by raising capital abroad. An increasing number of firms started listing in foreign equity markets, in particular, in the U.S. 2. Foreign investors accounted for over 30 percent of holdings 3 and up to 80 percent of trading in Mexican stocks since Figures 2 and 3 present the ratio of the value of holdings of Mexican stocks by foreign investors to domestic investors, and the ratio of the value of volume traded in ADRs to their Mexican counterpart respectively. The large role played by foreigners in Mexican stocks, the recognition hypothesis, provides support for the hypothesis of integration. A considerable number of empirical studies have focused on measuring the degree of integration of capital markets by the correlation between a local market index return and a proxy of the world market return, see the survey article by Karolyi (2003). In a seminal study, Bekaert and Harvey (1995) assumed that the conditional expected return of a national markets index is equal to a weighted average of 2 A striking increase of firms have undertaken ADRs programs, passing from 8 firms in 1992 to 71 in Many of the ADRs are traded over the counter, but by 2001 there were 28 different series traded on major exchanges. 3 Banco de Mexico, Development of Equity Markets,

4 the covariance between the world market and the national index returns, and the variance of the country s returns. These authors defined a time-varying measure of integration given by the weighting factor that is applied to the covariance and variance nesting the domestic and international version of the capital asset pricing model (CAPM). Using this measure, Bekaert and Harvey (1995) report considerable variability over time in the degree of integration between the Mexican stock index return and a proxy for the global stock market. With a sample of 12 emerging countries, including Mexico, they concluded that the degree of integration is timevarying. However, the empirical specification was rejected for many of the tested countries. Their diagnostic tests suggest that rejection of the model was as a result of omitting important local factors. In a closely related study, but with a more recent sample, Alder and Qi (2003) estimated a time-varying measure of integration between the Mexican stock index and the U.S. market. These authors, like Bekaert and Harvey (1995), assumed that the conditional expected return of the Mexican market is a time-varying weighted average of the covariance of the market index with the North American market return, and the variance of the Mexican market. In addition to the domestic and foreign market risk, they included exchange rate risk as an additional factor. Alder and Qi also concluded that the degree of integration is time varying and that exchange risk is priced in the case of the Mexican Stock Exchange. Even if the Mexican market is integrated to the world capital market, theoretical and empirical evidence suggests that exchange rate risk is priced and should be included as a source of systematic risk. Whenever a domestic investor holds a foreign 3

5 asset, her return in domestic currency depends on the exchange rate and therefore bears exchange rate risk. Ferson and Harvey (1993), Brown and Otsuki (1993), Ferson and Harvey (1994), Bekaert and Harvey (1995), Dumas and Solnik (1995), De Santis and Gerard (1998), Karolyi and Stulz (2003) and references therein, find that the price of currency risk, from the U.S. perspective, is significantly different from zero. Therefore, models of international asset pricing that only include proxies of the world market as the only risk factor are misspecified. This paper contributes to the international finance literature in testing the hypothesis of integration of the Mexican stock market to the U.S. market from a cross-section perspective. I examine the cross-section of returns of industry-based portfolios of Mexican equities. Data and studies of the Mexican stock market, indeed of any Latin American capital market, are scarce. To my knowledge, this is the first paper that examines whether international factors affect the cross-section of expected returns in Mexico. I explore the relative ability of two sets of factors, local and foreign, to explain the cross-section of returns. Following Bailey and Chung (1995), the local-factor model includes as factors the local market risk, exchange rate risk and political risk as the only sources of systematic risk in expected returns in Mexico. Fama and French U.S. portfolios were selected as the set of foreign factors used to explain the cross-section of returns in Mexico. In response to the failures of the CAPM in explaining the cross-section of expected returns sorted by size and book-to-market in the U.S., alternative models have been suggested to explain the pattern of returns. Fama and French (1993) developed a three-factor model, with 4

6 factors related to market risk, book-to-market and firm size, that has proved to be successful in capturing the cross-section of average returns in the U.S.. I compare the power of the Fama and French factors relative to the local factors for explaining the cross-section of expected returns. Empirically, I infer integration of the Mexican stock exchange to the U.S. market if the Fama and French factors synthesize better the risk exposures of the cross-section of returns in Mexico relative to the local factors. Finally, taking together the hypothesis of integration and the evidence that suggests that exchange rate risk is priced, a hybrid model that incorporates the Fama and French factors together with exchange rate is evaluated. I search for both unconditional and conditional versions of the local-factor model and Fama and French model. In the unconditional model, risk premia are assumed to be constant. For the conditional model, factors in the stochastic discount factor are expected to price assets only conditionally, leading to time-varying rather than fixed linear factor models. If risk premia are time-varying, the parameters in the stochastic discount factor will depend (among other conditional moments), on investors expectations of future average returns. To capture this variation, I assume that the parameters of the stochastic discount factor depend on current-period information variables, as in Cochrane (1996), Ferson and Harvey (1999) and Lettau and Ludvigson (2001). Factors are scaled by variables (instruments) that are likely to be important in summarizing variation in expected future returns. A conditional linear factor model can be expressed as an unconditional multi-factor model on the scaled factors. However, the choice of conditioning variables is of central importance 5

7 for this approach. The fact that expected returns are a function of investors conditioning information, which is unobservable, represents a practical obstacle in testing conditional factor models. In order to address this problem, a set of conditioning variables are selected based on their empirical performance in forecasting returns. The empirical results from cross-section regressions suggest that the unconditional model using the Fama and French factors does a good job explaining the cross-section of Mexican stock returns (see Figure 1). This result is consistent with the hypothesis of integration of the Mexican market to the U.S. market. Compared to the Fama and French model, the local-factor model was not able to capture the cross-section of average returns (see upper-right graph of Figure 1). In time-series regressions, I observed that portfolio returns appeared to be highly correlated with local factors, yielding high R 2 s. However, on cross-section regressions, these risk exposures have low explanatory power when compared to the Fama and French risk exposures. Results for the conditional asset pricing models suggest that risk premiums can be significantly time-varying in the case of Fama and French factors, whereas in the local-factor the hypothesis of time-varying risk exposures was rejected. In both specifications, unconditional and conditional, Fama and French specification dominates the local-factor specification. The conditional version of the Fama and French model does not provide a substantial improvement with respect to its unconditional version. However, when the exchange rate is included, the conditional version of the Fama and French model outperforms all of the other specifications by explaining 60 percent of the cross- 6

8 section of expected returns compared to a 47 percent for the local-factor model. The evidence supports the hypothesis of integration of the Mexican stock exchange. Global factors, in particular, the Fama and French factors and exchange rate risk appear to be more important in explaining the cross-section of returns than local factors. The paper is organized as follows. In section 2, I give a brief summary of factor pricing models and address the difference between conditional and unconditional asset pricing. A detailed description of the data used in this paper is given in section 3. Section 4 presents the empirical results. Conclusions are presented in the final section. 2 Empirical Methodology 2.1 Linear Factor Model In the absence of arbitrage, we have the fundamental equation: P t = E t (m t+1 (P t+1 + D t+1 )) (1) where P t is a vector of asset prices at time t, D t+1 represents a vector of interest, dividends or other payments at t+1, and m t+1 is the stochastic discount factor (SDF) 4. E t represents the conditional expectation with respect to Ω t, the market-wide information set. Since Ω t is unobservable from a researcher s perspective, expectations 4 Also known as the pricing kernel or intertemporal marginal rate of substitution. 7

9 are usually conditioned on a vector Z t of observable variables (instruments) that are contained in Ω t. Equation (1) can be expressed in terms of returns. While no arbitrage principles place a restriction on m t+1, in particular strict positivity, more structure is needed in order to explore the model empirically. Multiple factor models for asset pricing follow when m t+1 can be written as a function of several factors. The notion that the SDF comes from an investor optimization problem, and is equal to the growth in the marginal rate of substitution, suggests that likely candidates for the factors are variables that can proxy consumption growth or wealth, or any state variable that affects the marginal rate of substitution in an optimal consumption-investment path. In terms of returns, investors are willing to trade off overall performance to improve it in bad states of nature. If equation (1) holds it implies that: E t (m t+1 r t+1,i ) = 0 i = 1,..., N (2) where r t+1,i are excess returns. Expanding equation (2) in terms of the covariance: E t (r t+1,i ) = Cov t(r t+1,i, m t+1 ) E t (m t+1 ) i = 1,..., N (3) The conditional covariance of the excess return with the SDF is a general measure of systematic risk. In standard economic models, it measures the component of returns that is related to fluctuations in the marginal utility of wealth. A linear factor model is of the form: m t+1 = a + b f t+1, where f t+1 is a vector of size k of risk factors. In general, m t+1 can be written as m t+1 = m t+1 + ε t+1 where m t+1 is the projection of m t+1 on the asset space and ε t+1 is orthogonal to 8

10 the asset space, so E( m t+1 ε t+1 ) = 0. Any random variable orthogonal to returns can be added to m, leaving the pricing implications unchanged. In the case of conditional factor models, the coefficients a t and b t vary over time as a function of conditioning information, m t+1 = a t + b tf t+1. To illustrate this heuristically, I assume that the factors f t+1 are returns on tradeable assets 5. Imposing the condition that the model correctly prices the risk free rate R f t and the factors, f t+1, yields: ι k = E t (m t+1 f t+1 ) and 1 = E t (m t+1 R f t ) (4) where ι k ɛr k is a vector with all of its components equal to one. Solving for a t and b t we obtain: a t = 1 R f t E t (f t+1)b t and b t = (V ar t (f t+1 )) 1 ( ι k E ) t(f t+1 ) R f t (5) Equation (5) shows explicitly that both a t and b t are functions of R f t, and the conditional moments E t (R t+1 ), E t (f t+1 ), and V ar t (f t+1 ). Therefore, if conditional moments are time-varying, the parameters in the stochastic discount factor will not be constant in general. Following Cochrane (1996), Ferson and Harvey (1999) and Lettau and Ludvigson (2001), I assume that the denominator in b t is not likely to be highly variable 6. On the other hand, a large body of literature has documented 5 If f t+1 does not belong to the payoff space, we can replace it with f t+1 = proj(f t+1 X), where X represents the asset space. 6 Predictable movements in volatility may be a source of variation in b t, however they appear to be more concentrated in high-frequency data (see Cambell, Lo and MacKinlay (1997)) than in monthly, or quarterly returns. 9

11 that excess returns are predictable to some degree using monthly or quarterly data. Therefore, in this paper I assume that the only source of variation in b t is a consequence of the predictability of equity premia. The beta representation for expected returns can be obtained by combining equation (3) with the linear specification of the SDF (a t + b tf t+1 ): E t (r t+1,i ) = Cov t(r t+1,i, f t+1) b t β V ar t (f t+1 ) t,i E t (m t+1 ) E t (m t+1 ) b t β t,iλ t (6) where β t,i are the population time-varying regression coefficients of a regression of r t+1,i on f t+1, and are the loadings or risk exposures to f t+1 risks. λ t are the associated prices of risk for each unit of risk exposure. Following Cochrane (1996) and Lettau and Ludvigson (2001), the conditional factor pricing model given above is implemented by explicitly modeling the dependence of the parameters in the stochastic discount factor, a t and b t, on time-t information variables, Z t, where Z t set of variables that help forecast excess returns. To evaluate differences in exposures to risk factors, I measure risk exposures with time-series regressions of industrial portfolio excess returns on contemporaneous risk factors. r t+1,i = c t,i + β t,i (f t+1 ) + ɛ t+1,i, i = 1,..., N (7) where r t+1,i are excess returns over a one-month government zero coupon bond yield, and f t+1 is a vector of excess returns of economic risk factors. The vector of coefficients β t,i represent risk exposures of portfolio excess returns to the factors f t+1. In section 2.2 above, I further describe the scaled factor approach in order to 10

12 estimate β t,i of equation (7). The property E t (ɛ t,i f t+1 ) = 0 captures the fact that the coefficients β t,i are the conditional betas of the returns. The idea behind the beta representation (6) is to explain the variation in excess returns across assets where betas are a measure of risk compensation between assets, and the λ are the reward per unit of risk. Equation (6) can be estimated with a cross-sectional regression, E t (r t+1,i ) = β t,i λt + α i,t i = 1,..., N (8) where the betas are the right-hand variables that come from (7), the factor risk premia λ are the regression coefficients, and α i are the pricing errors (differences between expected and predicted returns). This method is also known as a twopass regression estimate. In applying standard OLS formulas to cross-sectional regressions, it is implicitly assumed that the right-hand variables (in this case β) are fixed. However, in this case, the β is the estimate of a time-series regression and is therefore not fixed. Shanken (1992) provides the corrected asymptotic standard errors for λ and for α (see Cochrane (2001)). 2.2 Unconditional and Conditional Factor Pricing Models As mentioned above, the betas are the variables that explain the variation in average returns across assets. Therefore, the general model for expected returns should have betas that vary asset by asset. To evaluate if expected returns and risks are time varying, I first estimate the unconditional version of equation (7) and (8) where the coefficients are assumed to be constant through time. The unconditional approach 11

13 will not be adequate if risk exposures of a financial asset or portfolio vary in a predictable manner, for example, with the business cycle. In order to test for time-varying risk exposures, the unconditional version of the model is taken as the null hypothesis, and different specifications of the conditional model, where risk exposures are allowed to be time-varying, are set as the alternative. To proceed, I must specify the risk factors. Two sets of factors are used to explain the cross-section of returns in Mexico. The first set correspond to the hypothesis of segmentation of the Mexican stock exchange to the U.S. stock market. Under this hypothesis, risk exposures on the Mexican stock market are represented only by local factors. The vector of local factors is composed by the local stock market return, the exchange rate risk and a proxy of political risk. The second set of factors, correspond to the hypothesis of integration between the Mexican stock exchange and the U.S. market. Given the ability of Fama and French (1993) factors to explain the cross-section of expected returns in the U.S., under the hypothesis of integration, these factors appear as good candidates to synthesize risk exposures in the Mexican stock market. Therefore, not only the pricing performance of the two sets of factors is evaluated, but also the hypothesis of integration measured by the ability of the Fama and French factors to explain the pattern of returns in Mexico. Consequently, I conclude that the Mexican stock market is highly integrated if its risk exposures are better summarized by the Fama and French factors than by the local factors Scaled Factors Approach 12

14 A popular and simple approach to incorporate conditioning information is based on scaled factors. As shown above (equation (5)), in a conditional setting, the coefficients associated with the discount factor m t+1 are time-varying and depend on the time-t information set. A partial solution is to model the dependence of the betas in (8) with a subset of variables that belong to the time-t information set. Furthermore, if a linear specification is assumed, we can write β t,i = D iz t (9) c t,i = c iz t where Z t is an L 1 vector of information variables (including a constant) known at time t, and the elements of the matrix D i are fixed parameters to be estimated. In choosing the instruments, Z t, I focus only on variables that can forecast conditional returns 7. Conversely, the unconditional factor model is characterized by fixed betas and is a special case of equation (9), in particular when Z t is only a constant. Combining equations (7) and (9), the time series regressions to obtain betas is given by r t+1,i = c iz t + d i(z t f t+1 ) + ɛ t+1,i (10) where every factor is multiplied by every instrument, and d i is given by V ec(d i ) 8. It is worth mentioning that the coefficients d i in expression (10) are linear and fixed 7 As shown in equation (5), a t and b t are functions of conditional returns, therefore variables that can summarize variation in conditional moments are used as instruments Z t. 8 V ec(a) is the operation represented by the vectorization columnwise of matrix A. 13

15 on the scaled factors (Z t f t+1 ), so the conditional version of the factor model can be viewed as an unconditional factor model over scaled factors. In order to evaluate the ability of the scaled-factor model to explain the crosssection of returns, time-varying betas are recovered using the estimated version of equation (9), β t,i = D Z t and cross-section regressions of returns on β t,i are estimated. 14

16 3 Data The sample is limited to the period following the devaluation suffered by the Mexican peso at the end of 1994; it runs from May 1995 to October Mexican stock prices and Mexican bond returns were obtained from Infosel Financiero 9. The rest of the variables were obtained from the Central Bank of Mexico, the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System web page, and the Fama and French web page. The data comprise two types of series: financial and macro variables, and are used to construct portfolio returns, risk factors, and information variables. 3.1 Returns on Mexican Portfolios To construct monthly returns, log differences of end-of-month closing prices were calculated. If the end-of-month price was not available, the closest quote preceding the end-of-month was used. There are a total of 101 months in the sample. Stock prices were adjusted for splits and dividends 10. I compute returns for all Mexican stocks that traded between 1995 and 2003 and the Mexican stock index. The average number of firms listed in the Mexican stock exchange during the sample is of 124, peaking in 1998 with 131 stock series 11, and the Mexican stock index. I applied some 9 Mexican electronic provider of financial information. 10 In the sample analyzed, very few stocks payed dividends before However, by the end of the sample a high proportion of stocks were paying dividends. 11 The average number of series traded daily in the Mexican Stock Exchange between 2000 and 2003 is around 70 stocks. However, the total number of firms listed in 1995 is 185, reaching its maximum of 195 listed firms in 1998 and falling to 158 for Only about 60 percent of these stocks trades at least once per week. 15

17 filtering rules and summarized the stock returns by returns on industry portfolios. In order to evaluate the pricing performance of different sets of factors (in a common currency, and from a U.S. perspective), nominal log returns in Mexican pesos were converted to U.S. dollar returns. Excess returns of Mexican industrial portfolios were computed and are defined as the difference between its log U.S. return and the 30-days T-bill return. Given the thinness of trading in many of the Mexican stocks in the sample, and in order to help address potential problems such as survivorship bias, missing observations for individual stocks, and noise in individual security returns, I aggregated individual stocks into industrial portfolios. The industrial categories resemble the official categories defined by the Mexican Stock Exchange and are given by: 1) Beverages, Food Products and Tobacco, 2) Financial Services, 3) Building Products, that includes engineering, construction and the real state sectors, 4) Conglomerates, 5) Media, entertainment and telecommunications, 6) Chemical and Metal Production, 7) Industrial, that contains the paper and pulp products industry, textiles industry, glass production and tubes production, 8) Machinery and Equipment, 9) Retail Services and 10) Transportation. Table I presents a summary of the number of firms that comprise each portfolio, as well as the relative annual average liquidity, measured as the value of the transactions of the portfolio to the value of all transactions of the market. Industrial portfolios are formed using weights based on the previous year s annual average liquidity and are re-balanced each January. The weights for each stock in each industrial portfolio are given by the relative annual average volume of the stock to the annual average volume of the portfolio. The 16

18 cross-section of the sample includes many industries and all of the components of the IP C index Risk Factors As mentioned above, I specify two sets of factors, f t+1, that represent potential sources of rewarded risk in the Mexican stock. The choice of each set of factors is based on different assumptions concerning the degree of integration of the Mexican market to the North American market. In what follows, the factors will be divided into two categories: a) Local Factors and b) Foreign Risk Factors. Local Factors: IP C is the monthly log-difference of the Mexican market index expressed in U.S. dollars, and in excess of the 30-day T-bill. The IP C is the most important index of the Mexican Stock Market (BMV) and is computed as the weighted average price of 35 of the most liquid stocks listed on the BMV. It represents a broad sample of industries. Exchange rate risk, Exch, is computed as the log-difference of the fix exchange rate (in terms of U.S. dollars/ Mexican pesos). The fix rate is determined on a daily basis by the central bank and is computed as the interbank market exchange rate at the close. As a proxy of political risk, the spread between the 5 year yield of the UMS and the matching maturity of a U.S. Treasury note, Dif f, was computed. To obtain this spread, I calibrated a time series of a zero-coupon term structure at fixed terms from the observed prices of Mexican government bond issued in US 12 The IPC is the most important market index and is comprised of 35 stocks (see nex section). 17

19 dollars (UMS) 13. Diff reflects perceived national credit risk, and is assumed to be highly correlated with political risk. Changes in sovereign yield spreads, like credit ratings, generally reflect changes in bond markets perceptions of an indebted country s credit worthiness. Sudden increases are usually followed by a drying up of liquidity and a flow out of national equity markets. Alder and Qi (2003) interpret sovereign default risk as a measure of relative segmentation. Their rationale is that when sovereign default risk cannot be completely diversified, and hence is a priced factor, international investors will respond to an unexpected increase in default risk by liquidating their positions of assets subject to default risk. The same effect, they argue, will occur if the market becomes suddenly segmented. Foreign Factors: If the Mexican Stock Exchange is integrated to the U.S. stock markets, a linear pricing representation that has been successful in explaining the cross-section of different sorts of U.S. portfolios should be successful in explaining the cross-section of Mexican portfolios 14. Following this line of thought, the U.S. Fama and French factors are assumed to be the relevant risk exposures in Mexican industrial portfolios if these markets are integrated 15. The Fama and French mimicking portfolios related to market, size and book-to-market equity ratios are: a) Market risk, Mkt, that is 13 These bonds pay a fixed semi-annual coupon. The maturity of the bonds that I used to estimate a zero coupon structure are: 06-Apr Jan Mar Feb Sep May One of the most questionable issues in the empirical international finance literature seeking to measure integration of national stock markets, is the use of the CAPM or ICAPM to explain international returns. Given the documented empirical failure of the CAPM in a domestic environment, a multi-factor approach appears to be more appropiate in an international setting. 15 Given the differences in size between U.S. stock markets and the Mexican stock exchange, the U.S. Fama and French factors are a good proxy of a weighted portfolio of Mexican and U.S. factors, where the weights are proportional to the capitalization of the U.S. and Mexican markets. 18

20 the monthly return of the U.S. market portfolio in excess of the 30-days T-bill, b) SMB (Small Minus Big) is the average return on three small portfolios minus the average return on three big portfolios, and c) HML (High Minus Low) is the average return on two value portfolios minus the average return on two growth portfolios Information Variables In order to evaluate the scaled factor model, I must specify the relevant information variables Z t that track variation in risk exposures to explain returns in time t + 1. These variables are assumed to be known by investors in time t, and are used to assess the significance of time-varying market risk premiums. In the BMV three information variables are useful predictors of one-period ahead expected returns. The first variable, y, represents the monthly real growth rate of seasonally adjusted labor income. The second variable, F A is the monthly real growth of holdings of financial assets, and at last, the third information variable is Cet Sp that measures the term premium of the Mexican government term structure, and is given by the spread between the one year Cetes(Certificados de la Tesoreria) and the 28 days Cetes 17. Following previous studies (see Campbell (1987), Harvey (1989)), I also explored various other candidates. For example, the ex-post real return of the 28-days Cetes, the lagged exchange rate, lagged Diff, lagged Fama and French fac- 16 See Fama and French (1993) for a detailed explanation of these portfolios. 17 The Cetes is a zero coupon bond auctioned weekly by the Mexican Treasury that represents the leading interest rate in Mexico. Typically, the term structure is composed of bonds with maturities of 28, 91, 182, 364 and occasionally of 724 days 19

21 tors, lagged U.S. Momentum factor, the U.S. term premium, measured by the spread between the five-year and one-month Treasuries rates, and a short term spread between a T-bill and Cetes were evaluated. None of these variables appeared to have strong forecasting power on returns, except the spread between T-bill and 28-days Cetes that has explanatory power in the Beverage, Food and Tobacco portfolio. 20

22 4 Empirical Evidence 4.1 Summary Statistics Table II presents summary statistics for the portfolios excess returns, risk factors and information variables; the means and standard deviations for returns are annualized. The Media & Telecoms portfolio is not only the most liquid portfolio, but also the one with the highest average excess return over the sample, with an annualized average excess return in U.S. dollars of percent. This sector is dominated by the telephone company monopoly, privatized at the beginning of the 90 s. It represents the most active stock in the BMV, and is the leading stock in the composition of the IP C. Diff, the risk premium of Mexican sovereign debt measured by the spread between the 5 years yield of the UMS and the U.S. Treasury note of the same maturity, has an average of 3.08 percent. Autocorrelation coefficients for this variable suggest that Diff follows an AR(1) 18. Cross-correlations are presented in panel D of Table II. IP C is highly correlated with both Mkt and Exch The first order autocorrelation is 0.81 while the second autocorrelation is of Remember that Exch is measured as the price of Mexican Pesos in U.S. dollars 21

23 4.2 Predictability and Description of Stock Portfolio Returns To implement the conditional asset pricing model, a set of instrument variables Z t 1 that capture the dependence of a t and b t on the information set Ω t has to be defined. Since only variables that forecast returns and/or the stochastic discount factor, m t+1, add information to the pricing problem (see equation (5)), I concentrate on a small set of variables that have the ability to forecast future returns. Table III summarizes the results of forecasting time-series regressions of the excess returns on the 10 industrial portfolios and the Mexican market index IP C on lagged information variables Z t 1. The regressions produce significant t-statistics in many cases. The R 2 in the case of the IP C is of 16 percent. The F -statistic for the joint hypothesis of zero coefficients is rejected in 10 of the 11 portfolios. In addition, the F -test associated with the joint hypothesis of zero coefficients in all portfolios was rejected with a p-value of To further evaluate the ability of these information variables Z t 1 to forecast returns, and to mitigate possible problems concerning data mining, I conducted the forecasting exercise with out-of-sample returns on the IP C using a sample from January of 1982 to August of An R 2 of 5 percent was obtained for the whole sample and of 10 percent using a subsample from January of 1982 to January of Despite the structural transformation experienced in Mexico during the last 20 years, Z t 1 appears to have forecasting power on stock returns over these years. The hypothesis of a change in the value of the coefficients associated with the forecasting variables 22

24 between and was conducted. Statistical evidence of parameter constancy between samples was rejected. 4.3 Unconditional Factor Models Time-Series Evidence of the Factor Model Results for time-series regressions on contemporaneous factors f t+1, as described in equation (7), assuming that both a t,i and β t,i are constant, are presented from Table IV to Table VI for the the local-factor model, the Fama and French model and an extended version of the Fama and French with exchange rate respectively. The objective of regressions on contemporaneous factors is to measure risk exposures to the proposed factors. In other words, we are trying to measure if risk factors can account for the variability in the cross-section of returns. In the next section I evaluate if these risks are priced. Table IV presents results for the local-factor model 20. Excluding the transportation sector 21, the R 2 coefficients for the local-factor model range from 51 percent in the Industrial sector to 87 percent for the Beverage, Food and Tobacco sector. The two most important factors in the local-factor model are the market return IP C 20 I included the local market stochastic volatility (that is a measure of market idiosyncratic risk, measured as both the squared sum and absolute value of daily returns in both U.S. dollars and Mexican pesos) as an additional local risk factor. This was motivated by the international finance literature that explores integration with a weighted average of the ICAPM and CAPM, where systematic risk, under the hypothesis of segmentation, is quantify by the variance of the local market. However, risk exposures for idiosyncratic risk were not significant in any of the industrial portfolios. 21 As noted in table 1, the transportation sector accounts for less than 2.4 percent of total transactions in the BMV. 23

25 and the exchange rate (Exch). For all portfolios, the constant term appears not significant. Table V shows the results for the Fama and French factor model. The slope on the U.S. market factor, M kt, appears uniformly significant and positive for all industrial portfolios. Risk exposures to SM B and HM L, are also significant in several industrial portfolios. An interpretation for HM L, not universally accepted, is provided by Fama and French (1995). They showed that HML acts as a proxy for relative distress. Weak firms, with low earnings, tend to have low book-to-market ratios and positive loadings on HM L, whereas the contrary effect is observed for strong firms. Therefore, slopes on HML can be interpreted as a measure of financial distress. In all industrial portfolios, slopes on HM L are positive giving evidence that financial distress is an important risk factor to explain the cross-section of industrial returns in Mexico. With respect to the SMB factor, coefficients are positive in all portfolios. A common interpretation for SM B is that is a factor that captures common variation of small stocks, not explained by the market portfolio. Given the size of Mexican stocks relative to U.S. firms, under the integration hypothesis, it is not surprising that the U.S. portfolio SM B is an important factor. Compared to the local-factor model, the R 2 for the Fama and French model are often lower, however, constant terms appear insignificant in almost all portfolios. Finally, and following the international finance literature where the exchange rate has proven to be an important risk factor within an international setting, I extended the Fama and French model by including exchange rate risk. In general, the coefficients associated with the Fama and French factors are very similar when 24

26 Exch is included (Table V and Table VI). Exch appears significant and positive in all portfolios, resulting in a significant improvement of R 2 s in all portfolios. From a time-series perspective, it appears that the local-factor model measured by R 2 s, does a better job in explaining the pattern of industrial returns in Mexico. In the following section, however, cross-section regressions give evidence that regardless the high R 2 in time-series regression for the local-factor model, betas from the Fama and French model do a better job in explaining the cross-section of returns in Mexico. To complement these results and to assess the relative importance of each risk factor, I performed F -tests 22 to test the joint significance of each risk factor in all industrial portfolios. Table VII presents results of the different specifications (local factor, Fama and French and Fama and French with Exchange rate). In the local-factor model, and as observed in the time-series regressions (Table IV), Dif f factor is statistically insignificant. These results do not differ from a previous study by Bailey and Chung (1995). These authors, using a sample from where Mexico had a fixed exchange rate regime, observed that the official exchange rate and the sovereign default risk were not significant factors in explaining portfolio returns. However, the spread between the official and a market exchange rate 23 appeared to be driving returns. For the Fama and French model and Fama and French that 22 For testing linear restrictions in a SURE representation, the analogous F -statistic under GLS assumptions is: F = (R β r) [RV ar(β)r ] 1 (R β r)/q ê V, where V = Σ I; Σ is the FGLS estimate of ê/(n K) the covariance matrix. N is the number of observations of each equation times the number of equations and K stands for the number of parameters estimated in the system. An alternative test statistic (Wald test), under the hypothesis that ê V ê/(n K) converges to one, that measures the distance between R β and r is given by q F. This test statistic has a limiting χ 2 (q) distribution. 23 Mexico implemented a dual exchange rate regime during the 1980 s and a semi-fixed exchange parity starting in the 1990 s that ended at the end of

27 includes exchange, all factors are jointly significant. Panel B of Table VII tests the hypothesis of zero intercept (omitted risk factors). Interesting and surprising, the test of zero intercept in not rejected for any of the three specifications Cross-Section of Expected Returns To evaluate the performance of the different models (i.e. local-factor vs. Fama and French) in explaining expected returns, cross-sectional regressions were performed. First pass time-series regressions are sufficient when factors are portfolio returns in the asset space. If this is the case, the estimate of the factors risk premia is just λ = E T (f t+1 ) where the notation E T refers to the sample mean. However, when risk factors are not returns in the space of the tested portfolios, cross-sectional regressions must be performed in order to estimate risk premia for each factor and the respective pricing error (equation (8)). The cross-section regressions are given by: R t+1,i = β iλ t+1 + α t+1,i i = 1,..., N, where λ t+1 is the vector of risk prices, α t+1,i is the pricing error. The β i are the betas from time-series regressions using information up to time t. Table VIII summarizes the results for the cross-sectional regressions for the unscaled factor model. Time-series averages of the cross-sectional regressions coefficients λ t+1, Fama-MacBeth t-statistics for the coefficients and the time-series average of R 2 s for the cross-sectional regressions are presented. The betas were estimated using expanding samples and moving windows of 36-months prior to the estimation 26

28 period. To form a basis of comparison of the different factor models, results for the domestic CAPM are also showed. The first four rows of Table VIII presents results for the CAPM where the IP C is used as a proxy for the unobservable market return. The low average of the R 2 reflects the bad performance of the CAPM in explaining the cross-section of returns. With the inclusion of exchange rate, Exch, and political risk Dif f as additional factors, Local-factor model, there is a significant improvement in the performance of the pricing model. On average, 60 percent of the cross-sectional variation in returns is explained by local factors. Fama and French factors explain on average 55 percent of the cross-sectional variation in returns. Finally, the last columns correspond to the results for the Fama and French model with Exch. For these factors, on average 65 percent of the cross-sectional variation in returns in Mexico is explained. Figure 1 summarizes the above results for the different factor models. In particular, cross- section regressions of the form: E(R t+1,i ) = β iλ i = 1,..., N, were computed, where E(R t+1,i ) is the sample average of industrial returns, β i are the betas of time-series regressions using the whole sample. If the proposed model fit perfectly expected returns, all the points in the figure would lie along the 45- degree line. The figure shows clearly that few do, and that both local factor models (CAPM and local-factor) have small power in explaining returns in Mexico 24. The 24 The Fama-French model performs better than the local-factor model when the betas used in the cross-section regressions are estimated using the whole sample, and where the dependent 27

29 above results give support that the Fama and French factor model with exchange rate does a better job in capturing the pattern of average returns in Mexico than the other specifications, therefore, supporting the hypothesis of integration of the Mexican stock exchange with the U.S. market. In other words, and in the context of linear pricing methodology, a linear pricing kernel with fixed coefficient that is approximated by the Fama and French factors and exchange rate, does a better job in pricing the cross-section of returns in Mexico than a specification that uses local risk factors. 4.4 Conditional Factor Models Time-Series Evidence of the Factor Model As mentioned above, lagged instruments track variation in expected returns. In this context, conditional asset pricing presumes the existence of some return predictability. That is, there should exist some instruments Z t for which E(R t+1 Z t ) or E(m t+1 Z t ) 25 are not constant. In the context of industrial portfolio returns, Fama and French (1994) argue that since industries wander between growth and distress, it is critical to allow risk exposures to be time-varying. In this paper, and as mentioned above, time-variation in conditional betas was achieved by allowing betas to depend linearly on instruments Z t. variable is the sample average of industrial returns, than using Fama-MacBeth methodology. 25 Equation 2 suggests that in the case of a risk free asset, all we require is realized risk free asset prices to vary over time. 28

30 Tables IX to XI present results from testing the hypothesis of time varying betas for the local-factor model and both versions of Fama and French model. These tests summarize the power of the instruments Z t to track variation in risk exposures. I performed F -tests for the hypothesis of time-varying betas. Under the null, the coefficients associated with the scaled factors, (Z t f t+1 ) in equation (10), are restricted to be jointly equal to zero. Panel A of tables IX to XI present results from testing the hypothesis of time-varying betas when the constant is allowed to be time-varying. R 2 of the unrestricted and restricted models are presented in the first two columns, together with the p-values of the F -tests that compares both models (restricted and unrestricted) in the third column. The hypothesis of fixed betas, conditional on time-varying intercepts, is not rejected for all industrial portfolios in the local-factor model. For Fama and French factor model, strong evidence on timevarying betas conditional on time-varying intercepts is observed. Panel B presents results to test the hypothesis of time-varying betas conditional on a fixed intercept. Evidence on time-varying betas is found only for the Fama and French factors. These results give evidence that it may be appropriate to allow for time-varying risk exposures in the case of Fama and French factors. Table XII extend the above results by testing the joint hypothesis of zero coefficients associated with scaled factors. Results for the local factor model are consistent with those obtained in Table IX. That is, the hypothesis of zero coefficients associated with scaled factors, and therefore time-varying coefficients, for all portfolios is not rejected. However, for the the Fama and French factors, the hypothesis of time-variation is not rejected. 29

31 4.4.2 Cross-Section of Expected Returns To evaluate the ability of the different set of factors to explain the cross-section of industrial returns in Mexico, and to measure the performance of the scaled version of the factor model against the unconditional version, cross-sections regressions were performed. As in the unconditional version of the model presented above, crosssection regression for the scaled factor version are performed, where betas are timevarying: R t+1,i = β t,iλ + α t+1,i i = 1,..., N. Table XIII summarizes the different versions of the cross-sectional regressions. Timeseries averages of the cross-sectional coefficients are shown along with their Fama- MacBeth t-ratios. As in Table VIII, the betas were estimated either by using an expanding sample or a rolling window, 36-month prior estimation. In the context of the scaled factor model, conditional betas were used. An estimate of the explanation power of cross-section regressions R 2 is computed as the average of individual R 2 s of the above regressions. Results again reveal, as in the unconditional framework, that the Fama-French factors, together with the Exchange rate, perform the best in pricing the cross-section of returns in Mexico, supporting the hypothesis of integration of the Mexican stock exchange. Cross-section results confirm the time-series evidence obtained above concerning the hypothesis of time-varying risk exposures for the Fama and French factors. For the local-factor model, no significant differences are observed between the conditional and unconditional version of the models, i.e., average R 2 are very similar for both 30

Online appendix to paper Downside Market Risk of Carry Trades

Online appendix to paper Downside Market Risk of Carry Trades Online appendix to paper Downside Market Risk of Carry Trades A1. SUB-SAMPLE OF DEVELOPED COUNTRIES I study a sub-sample of developed countries separately for two reasons. First, some of the emerging countries

More information

Yao Zheng University of New Orleans. Eric Osmer University of New Orleans

Yao Zheng University of New Orleans. Eric Osmer University of New Orleans ABSTRACT The pricing of China Region ETFs - an empirical analysis Yao Zheng University of New Orleans Eric Osmer University of New Orleans Using a sample of exchange-traded funds (ETFs) that focus on investing

More information

Appendices with Supplementary Materials for CAPM for Estimating Cost of Equity Capital: Interpreting the Empirical Evidence

Appendices with Supplementary Materials for CAPM for Estimating Cost of Equity Capital: Interpreting the Empirical Evidence Appendices with Supplementary Materials for CAPM for Estimating Cost of Equity Capital: Interpreting the Empirical Evidence This document contains supplementary material to the paper titled CAPM for estimating

More information

CAPM, Arbitrage, and Linear Factor Models

CAPM, Arbitrage, and Linear Factor Models CAPM, Arbitrage, and Linear Factor Models CAPM, Arbitrage, Linear Factor Models 1/ 41 Introduction We now assume all investors actually choose mean-variance e cient portfolios. By equating these investors

More information

Does Mutual Fund Performance Vary over the Business Cycle?

Does Mutual Fund Performance Vary over the Business Cycle? Does Mutual Fund Performance Vary over the Business Cycle? Anthony W. Lynch New York University and NBER Jessica Wachter New York University and NBER Walter Boudry New York University First Version: 15

More information

Investing in Foreign Currency is like Betting on your Intertemporal Marginal Rate of Substitution.

Investing in Foreign Currency is like Betting on your Intertemporal Marginal Rate of Substitution. Investing in Foreign Currency is like Betting on your Intertemporal Marginal Rate of Substitution. Hanno Lustig UCLA and NBER Adrien Verdelhan Boston University December 13, 2005 Abstract Investors earn

More information

Stock market booms and real economic activity: Is this time different?

Stock market booms and real economic activity: Is this time different? International Review of Economics and Finance 9 (2000) 387 415 Stock market booms and real economic activity: Is this time different? Mathias Binswanger* Institute for Economics and the Environment, University

More information

C(t) (1 + y) 4. t=1. For the 4 year bond considered above, assume that the price today is 900$. The yield to maturity will then be the y that solves

C(t) (1 + y) 4. t=1. For the 4 year bond considered above, assume that the price today is 900$. The yield to maturity will then be the y that solves Economics 7344, Spring 2013 Bent E. Sørensen INTEREST RATE THEORY We will cover fixed income securities. The major categories of long-term fixed income securities are federal government bonds, corporate

More information

Models of Risk and Return

Models of Risk and Return Models of Risk and Return Aswath Damodaran Aswath Damodaran 1 First Principles Invest in projects that yield a return greater than the minimum acceptable hurdle rate. The hurdle rate should be higher for

More information

Financial Intermediaries and the Cross-Section of Asset Returns

Financial Intermediaries and the Cross-Section of Asset Returns Financial Intermediaries and the Cross-Section of Asset Returns Tobias Adrian - Federal Reserve Bank of New York 1 Erkko Etula - Goldman Sachs Tyler Muir - Kellogg School of Management May, 2012 1 The

More information

Does Mutual Fund Performance Vary over the Business Cycle?

Does Mutual Fund Performance Vary over the Business Cycle? Does Mutual Fund Performance Vary over the Business Cycle? Anthony W. Lynch New York University and NBER Jessica A. Wachter University of Pennsylvania and NBER First Version: 15 November 2002 Current Version:

More information

The Abnormal Performance of Bond Returns

The Abnormal Performance of Bond Returns The University of Reading THE BUSINESS SCHOOL FOR FINANCIAL MARKETS The Abnormal Performance of Bond Returns Joëlle Miffre ISMA Centre, The University of Reading, Reading, Berks., RG6 6BA, UK Copyright

More information

CHAPTER 10 RISK AND RETURN: THE CAPITAL ASSET PRICING MODEL (CAPM)

CHAPTER 10 RISK AND RETURN: THE CAPITAL ASSET PRICING MODEL (CAPM) CHAPTER 10 RISK AND RETURN: THE CAPITAL ASSET PRICING MODEL (CAPM) Answers to Concepts Review and Critical Thinking Questions 1. Some of the risk in holding any asset is unique to the asset in question.

More information

Discussion of Momentum and Autocorrelation in Stock Returns

Discussion of Momentum and Autocorrelation in Stock Returns Discussion of Momentum and Autocorrelation in Stock Returns Joseph Chen University of Southern California Harrison Hong Stanford University Jegadeesh and Titman (1993) document individual stock momentum:

More information

Do the asset pricing factors predict future economy growth? An Australian study. Bin Liu Amalia Di Iorio

Do the asset pricing factors predict future economy growth? An Australian study. Bin Liu Amalia Di Iorio Do the asset pricing factors predict future economy growth? An Australian study. Bin Liu Amalia Di Iorio Abstract In this paper we examine whether past returns of the market portfolio (MKT), the size portfolio

More information

A Panel Data Analysis of Corporate Attributes and Stock Prices for Indian Manufacturing Sector

A Panel Data Analysis of Corporate Attributes and Stock Prices for Indian Manufacturing Sector Journal of Modern Accounting and Auditing, ISSN 1548-6583 November 2013, Vol. 9, No. 11, 1519-1525 D DAVID PUBLISHING A Panel Data Analysis of Corporate Attributes and Stock Prices for Indian Manufacturing

More information

The term structure of equity option implied volatility

The term structure of equity option implied volatility The term structure of equity option implied volatility Christopher S. Jones Tong Wang Marshall School of Business Marshall School of Business University of Southern California University of Southern California

More information

8.1 Summary and conclusions 8.2 Implications

8.1 Summary and conclusions 8.2 Implications Conclusion and Implication V{tÑàxÜ CONCLUSION AND IMPLICATION 8 Contents 8.1 Summary and conclusions 8.2 Implications Having done the selection of macroeconomic variables, forecasting the series and construction

More information

B.3. Robustness: alternative betas estimation

B.3. Robustness: alternative betas estimation Appendix B. Additional empirical results and robustness tests This Appendix contains additional empirical results and robustness tests. B.1. Sharpe ratios of beta-sorted portfolios Fig. B1 plots the Sharpe

More information

Internet Appendix to CAPM for estimating cost of equity capital: Interpreting the empirical evidence

Internet Appendix to CAPM for estimating cost of equity capital: Interpreting the empirical evidence Internet Appendix to CAPM for estimating cost of equity capital: Interpreting the empirical evidence This document contains supplementary material to the paper titled CAPM for estimating cost of equity

More information

Review for Exam 2. Instructions: Please read carefully

Review for Exam 2. Instructions: Please read carefully Review for Exam 2 Instructions: Please read carefully The exam will have 25 multiple choice questions and 5 work problems You are not responsible for any topics that are not covered in the lecture note

More information

A Review of Cross Sectional Regression for Financial Data You should already know this material from previous study

A Review of Cross Sectional Regression for Financial Data You should already know this material from previous study A Review of Cross Sectional Regression for Financial Data You should already know this material from previous study But I will offer a review, with a focus on issues which arise in finance 1 TYPES OF FINANCIAL

More information

Trading Probability and Turnover as measures of Liquidity Risk: Evidence from the U.K. Stock Market. Ian McManus. Peter Smith.

Trading Probability and Turnover as measures of Liquidity Risk: Evidence from the U.K. Stock Market. Ian McManus. Peter Smith. Trading Probability and Turnover as measures of Liquidity Risk: Evidence from the U.K. Stock Market. Ian McManus (Corresponding author). School of Management, University of Southampton, Highfield, Southampton,

More information

FORECASTING DEPOSIT GROWTH: Forecasting BIF and SAIF Assessable and Insured Deposits

FORECASTING DEPOSIT GROWTH: Forecasting BIF and SAIF Assessable and Insured Deposits Technical Paper Series Congressional Budget Office Washington, DC FORECASTING DEPOSIT GROWTH: Forecasting BIF and SAIF Assessable and Insured Deposits Albert D. Metz Microeconomic and Financial Studies

More information

Risk and Return Models: Equity and Debt. Aswath Damodaran 1

Risk and Return Models: Equity and Debt. Aswath Damodaran 1 Risk and Return Models: Equity and Debt Aswath Damodaran 1 First Principles Invest in projects that yield a return greater than the minimum acceptable hurdle rate. The hurdle rate should be higher for

More information

LIQUIDITY AND ASSET PRICING. Evidence for the London Stock Exchange

LIQUIDITY AND ASSET PRICING. Evidence for the London Stock Exchange LIQUIDITY AND ASSET PRICING Evidence for the London Stock Exchange Timo Hubers (358022) Bachelor thesis Bachelor Bedrijfseconomie Tilburg University May 2012 Supervisor: M. Nie MSc Table of Contents Chapter

More information

CHAPTER 11: ARBITRAGE PRICING THEORY

CHAPTER 11: ARBITRAGE PRICING THEORY CHAPTER 11: ARBITRAGE PRICING THEORY 1. The revised estimate of the expected rate of return on the stock would be the old estimate plus the sum of the products of the unexpected change in each factor times

More information

Is the Forward Exchange Rate a Useful Indicator of the Future Exchange Rate?

Is the Forward Exchange Rate a Useful Indicator of the Future Exchange Rate? Is the Forward Exchange Rate a Useful Indicator of the Future Exchange Rate? Emily Polito, Trinity College In the past two decades, there have been many empirical studies both in support of and opposing

More information

Chap 3 CAPM, Arbitrage, and Linear Factor Models

Chap 3 CAPM, Arbitrage, and Linear Factor Models Chap 3 CAPM, Arbitrage, and Linear Factor Models 1 Asset Pricing Model a logical extension of portfolio selection theory is to consider the equilibrium asset pricing consequences of investors individually

More information

Does the Spot Curve Contain Information on Future Monetary Policy in Colombia? Por : Juan Manuel Julio Román. No. 463

Does the Spot Curve Contain Information on Future Monetary Policy in Colombia? Por : Juan Manuel Julio Román. No. 463 Does the Spot Curve Contain Information on Future Monetary Policy in Colombia? Por : Juan Manuel Julio Román No. 463 2007 tá - Colombia - Bogotá - Colombia - Bogotá - Colombia - Bogotá - Colombia - Bogotá

More information

Chapter 5. Conditional CAPM. 5.1 Conditional CAPM: Theory. 5.1.1 Risk According to the CAPM. The CAPM is not a perfect model of expected returns.

Chapter 5. Conditional CAPM. 5.1 Conditional CAPM: Theory. 5.1.1 Risk According to the CAPM. The CAPM is not a perfect model of expected returns. Chapter 5 Conditional CAPM 5.1 Conditional CAPM: Theory 5.1.1 Risk According to the CAPM The CAPM is not a perfect model of expected returns. In the 40+ years of its history, many systematic deviations

More information

Does the Stock Market React to Unexpected Inflation Differently Across the Business Cycle?

Does the Stock Market React to Unexpected Inflation Differently Across the Business Cycle? Does the Stock Market React to Unexpected Inflation Differently Across the Business Cycle? Chao Wei 1 April 24, 2009 Abstract I find that nominal equity returns respond to unexpected inflation more negatively

More information

AFM 472. Midterm Examination. Monday Oct. 24, 2011. A. Huang

AFM 472. Midterm Examination. Monday Oct. 24, 2011. A. Huang AFM 472 Midterm Examination Monday Oct. 24, 2011 A. Huang Name: Answer Key Student Number: Section (circle one): 10:00am 1:00pm 2:30pm Instructions: 1. Answer all questions in the space provided. If space

More information

Market Efficiency and Behavioral Finance. Chapter 12

Market Efficiency and Behavioral Finance. Chapter 12 Market Efficiency and Behavioral Finance Chapter 12 Market Efficiency if stock prices reflect firm performance, should we be able to predict them? if prices were to be predictable, that would create the

More information

Answers to Concepts in Review

Answers to Concepts in Review Answers to Concepts in Review 1. A portfolio is simply a collection of investments assembled to meet a common investment goal. An efficient portfolio is a portfolio offering the highest expected return

More information

GOVERNMENT PENSION FUND GLOBAL HISTORICAL PERFORMANCE AND RISK REVIEW

GOVERNMENT PENSION FUND GLOBAL HISTORICAL PERFORMANCE AND RISK REVIEW GOVERNMENT PENSION FUND GLOBAL HISTORICAL PERFORMANCE AND RISK REVIEW 10 March 2014 Content Scope... 3 Executive summary... 3 1 Return and risk measures... 4 1.1 The GPFG and asset class returns... 4 1.2

More information

Mid-Term Spring 2003

Mid-Term Spring 2003 Mid-Term Spring 2003 1. (1 point) You want to purchase XYZ stock at $60 from your broker using as little of your own money as possible. If initial margin is 50% and you have $3000 to invest, how many shares

More information

CHAPTER 7: OPTIMAL RISKY PORTFOLIOS

CHAPTER 7: OPTIMAL RISKY PORTFOLIOS CHAPTER 7: OPTIMAL RIKY PORTFOLIO PROLEM ET 1. (a) and (e).. (a) and (c). After real estate is added to the portfolio, there are four asset classes in the portfolio: stocks, bonds, cash and real estate.

More information

The International Cost of Capital and Risk Calculator (ICCRC)

The International Cost of Capital and Risk Calculator (ICCRC) The International Cost of Capital and Risk Calculator (ICCRC) Campbell R. Harvey, Ph.D. J. Paul Sticht Professor of International Business, Duke University, Durham, North Carolina, USA 27708 Research Associate,

More information

Asian Economic and Financial Review THE CAPITAL INVESTMENT INCREASES AND STOCK RETURNS

Asian Economic and Financial Review THE CAPITAL INVESTMENT INCREASES AND STOCK RETURNS Asian Economic and Financial Review journal homepage: http://www.aessweb.com/journals/5002 THE CAPITAL INVESTMENT INCREASES AND STOCK RETURNS Jung Fang Liu 1 --- Nicholas Rueilin Lee 2 * --- Yih-Bey Lin

More information

The Stock Market s Reaction to Accounting Information: The Case of the Latin American Integrated Market. Abstract

The Stock Market s Reaction to Accounting Information: The Case of the Latin American Integrated Market. Abstract The Stock Market s Reaction to Accounting Information: The Case of the Latin American Integrated Market Abstract The purpose of this paper is to explore the stock market s reaction to quarterly financial

More information

CHAPTER 15: THE TERM STRUCTURE OF INTEREST RATES

CHAPTER 15: THE TERM STRUCTURE OF INTEREST RATES CHAPTER 15: THE TERM STRUCTURE OF INTEREST RATES 1. Expectations hypothesis. The yields on long-term bonds are geometric averages of present and expected future short rates. An upward sloping curve is

More information

Using Duration Times Spread to Forecast Credit Risk

Using Duration Times Spread to Forecast Credit Risk Using Duration Times Spread to Forecast Credit Risk European Bond Commission / VBA Patrick Houweling, PhD Head of Quantitative Credits Research Robeco Asset Management Quantitative Strategies Forecasting

More information

Asymmetry and the Cost of Capital

Asymmetry and the Cost of Capital Asymmetry and the Cost of Capital Javier García Sánchez, IAE Business School Lorenzo Preve, IAE Business School Virginia Sarria Allende, IAE Business School Abstract The expected cost of capital is a crucial

More information

EVALUATION OF THE PAIRS TRADING STRATEGY IN THE CANADIAN MARKET

EVALUATION OF THE PAIRS TRADING STRATEGY IN THE CANADIAN MARKET EVALUATION OF THE PAIRS TRADING STRATEGY IN THE CANADIAN MARKET By Doris Siy-Yap PROJECT SUBMITTED IN PARTIAL FULFILLMENT OF THE REQUIREMENTS FOR THE DEGREE OF MASTER IN BUSINESS ADMINISTRATION Approval

More information

The cross section of expected stock returns

The cross section of expected stock returns The cross section of expected stock returns Jonathan Lewellen Dartmouth College and NBER This version: August 2014 Forthcoming in Critical Finance Review Tel: 603-646-8650; email: jon.lewellen@dartmouth.edu.

More information

How To Value Bonds

How To Value Bonds Chapter 6 Interest Rates And Bond Valuation Learning Goals 1. Describe interest rate fundamentals, the term structure of interest rates, and risk premiums. 2. Review the legal aspects of bond financing

More information

CHAPTER 15: THE TERM STRUCTURE OF INTEREST RATES

CHAPTER 15: THE TERM STRUCTURE OF INTEREST RATES CHAPTER : THE TERM STRUCTURE OF INTEREST RATES CHAPTER : THE TERM STRUCTURE OF INTEREST RATES PROBLEM SETS.. In general, the forward rate can be viewed as the sum of the market s expectation of the future

More information

Predicting the US Real GDP Growth Using Yield Spread of Corporate Bonds

Predicting the US Real GDP Growth Using Yield Spread of Corporate Bonds International Department Working Paper Series 00-E-3 Predicting the US Real GDP Growth Using Yield Spread of Corporate Bonds Yoshihito SAITO yoshihito.saitou@boj.or.jp Yoko TAKEDA youko.takeda@boj.or.jp

More information

NIKE Case Study Solutions

NIKE Case Study Solutions NIKE Case Study Solutions Professor Corwin This case study includes several problems related to the valuation of Nike. We will work through these problems throughout the course to demonstrate some of the

More information

DIVIDEND POLICY, TRADING CHARACTERISTICS AND SHARE PRICES: EMPIRICAL EVIDENCE FROM EGYPTIAN FIRMS

DIVIDEND POLICY, TRADING CHARACTERISTICS AND SHARE PRICES: EMPIRICAL EVIDENCE FROM EGYPTIAN FIRMS International Journal of Theoretical and Applied Finance Vol. 7, No. 2 (2004) 121 133 c World Scientific Publishing Company DIVIDEND POLICY, TRADING CHARACTERISTICS AND SHARE PRICES: EMPIRICAL EVIDENCE

More information

Value, momentum, and short-term interest rates

Value, momentum, and short-term interest rates Value, momentum, and short-term interest rates Paulo Maio 1 Pedro Santa-Clara 2 First version: July 2011 This version: December 2011 3 1 Hanken School of Economics. E-mail: paulofmaio@gmail.com. 2 Millennium

More information

Do Direct Stock Market Investments Outperform Mutual Funds? A Study of Finnish Retail Investors and Mutual Funds 1

Do Direct Stock Market Investments Outperform Mutual Funds? A Study of Finnish Retail Investors and Mutual Funds 1 LTA 2/03 P. 197 212 P. JOAKIM WESTERHOLM and MIKAEL KUUSKOSKI Do Direct Stock Market Investments Outperform Mutual Funds? A Study of Finnish Retail Investors and Mutual Funds 1 ABSTRACT Earlier studies

More information

DOES IT PAY TO HAVE FAT TAILS? EXAMINING KURTOSIS AND THE CROSS-SECTION OF STOCK RETURNS

DOES IT PAY TO HAVE FAT TAILS? EXAMINING KURTOSIS AND THE CROSS-SECTION OF STOCK RETURNS DOES IT PAY TO HAVE FAT TAILS? EXAMINING KURTOSIS AND THE CROSS-SECTION OF STOCK RETURNS By Benjamin M. Blau 1, Abdullah Masud 2, and Ryan J. Whitby 3 Abstract: Xiong and Idzorek (2011) show that extremely

More information

No. 03/11 BATH ECONOMICS RESEARCH PAPERS

No. 03/11 BATH ECONOMICS RESEARCH PAPERS Sovereign Credit Default Swaps and the Macroeconomy Yang Liu and Bruce Morley No. 03/11 BATH ECONOMICS RESEARCH PAPERS Department of Economics 1 Sovereign Credit Default Swaps and the Macroeconomy Yang

More information

CONTENTS OF VOLUME IB

CONTENTS OF VOLUME IB CONTENTS OF VOLUME IB Introduction to the Series Contents of the Handbook Preface v vii ix FINANCIAL MARKETS AND ASSET PRICING Chapter 10 Arbitrage, State Prices and Portfolio Theory PHILIP H. DYBVIG and

More information

Sensex Realized Volatility Index

Sensex Realized Volatility Index Sensex Realized Volatility Index Introduction: Volatility modelling has traditionally relied on complex econometric procedures in order to accommodate the inherent latent character of volatility. Realized

More information

International Investments

International Investments 2008 AGI-Information Management Consultants May be used for personal purporses only or by libraries associated to dandelon.com network. International Investments Bruno Solnik H.E.C. SCHOOL of MANAGEMENT

More information

New Zealand mutual funds: measuring performance and persistence in performance

New Zealand mutual funds: measuring performance and persistence in performance Accounting and Finance 46 (2006) 347 363 New Zealand mutual funds: measuring performance and persistence in performance Rob Bauer a,rogér Otten b, Alireza Tourani Rad c a ABP Investments and Limburg Institute

More information

The Tangent or Efficient Portfolio

The Tangent or Efficient Portfolio The Tangent or Efficient Portfolio 1 2 Identifying the Tangent Portfolio Sharpe Ratio: Measures the ratio of reward-to-volatility provided by a portfolio Sharpe Ratio Portfolio Excess Return E[ RP ] r

More information

Testing for Granger causality between stock prices and economic growth

Testing for Granger causality between stock prices and economic growth MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Testing for Granger causality between stock prices and economic growth Pasquale Foresti 2006 Online at http://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/2962/ MPRA Paper No. 2962, posted

More information

CHAPTER 15: THE TERM STRUCTURE OF INTEREST RATES

CHAPTER 15: THE TERM STRUCTURE OF INTEREST RATES Chapter - The Term Structure of Interest Rates CHAPTER : THE TERM STRUCTURE OF INTEREST RATES PROBLEM SETS.. In general, the forward rate can be viewed as the sum of the market s expectation of the future

More information

Using Currency Futures to Hedge Currency Risk

Using Currency Futures to Hedge Currency Risk Using Currency Futures to Hedge Currency Risk By Sayee Srinivasan & Steven Youngren Product Research & Development Chicago Mercantile Exchange Inc. Introduction Investment professionals face a tough climate.

More information

Söhnke M. Bartram. Warwick Business School. Warwick Business School

Söhnke M. Bartram. Warwick Business School. Warwick Business School Söhnke M. Bartram International Stock Price Co- Movement Cash-flow based view of the world Common fundamentals as proxied by country or industry Roll (1992), Heston and Rouwenhorst (1994), Griffin and

More information

Why are Some Diversified U.S. Equity Funds Less Diversified Than Others? A Study on the Industry Concentration of Mutual Funds

Why are Some Diversified U.S. Equity Funds Less Diversified Than Others? A Study on the Industry Concentration of Mutual Funds Why are Some Diversified U.S. Equity unds Less Diversified Than Others? A Study on the Industry Concentration of Mutual unds Binying Liu Advisor: Matthew C. Harding Department of Economics Stanford University

More information

Real Estate Closed-end Funds and Exchange Traded Funds: A Style Analysis and Return Attribution. Marta Charrón, Ph.D.

Real Estate Closed-end Funds and Exchange Traded Funds: A Style Analysis and Return Attribution. Marta Charrón, Ph.D. Real Estate Closed-end Funds and Exchange Traded Funds: A Style Analysis and Return Attribution Marta Charrón, Ph.D. Real Estate Closed-end Funds and Exchange Traded Funds: A Style Analysis and Return

More information

Cost of Capital, Valuation and Strategic Financial Decision Making

Cost of Capital, Valuation and Strategic Financial Decision Making Cost of Capital, Valuation and Strategic Financial Decision Making By Dr. Valerio Poti, - Examiner in Professional 2 Stage Strategic Corporate Finance The financial crisis that hit financial markets in

More information

Is there Information Content in Insider Trades in the Singapore Exchange?

Is there Information Content in Insider Trades in the Singapore Exchange? Is there Information Content in Insider Trades in the Singapore Exchange? Wong Kie Ann a, John M. Sequeira a and Michael McAleer b a Department of Finance and Accounting, National University of Singapore

More information

Value versus Growth: The International Evidence

Value versus Growth: The International Evidence THE JOURNAL OF FINANCE VOL. LIII, NO. 6 DECEMBER 1998 Value versus Growth: The International Evidence EUGENE F. FAMA and KENNETH R. FRENCH* ABSTRACT Value stocks have higher returns than growth stocks

More information

Implied Volatility Skews in the Foreign Exchange Market. Empirical Evidence from JPY and GBP: 1997-2002

Implied Volatility Skews in the Foreign Exchange Market. Empirical Evidence from JPY and GBP: 1997-2002 Implied Volatility Skews in the Foreign Exchange Market Empirical Evidence from JPY and GBP: 1997-2002 The Leonard N. Stern School of Business Glucksman Institute for Research in Securities Markets Faculty

More information

VANDERBILT AVENUE ASSET MANAGEMENT

VANDERBILT AVENUE ASSET MANAGEMENT SUMMARY CURRENCY-HEDGED INTERNATIONAL FIXED INCOME INVESTMENT In recent years, the management of risk in internationally diversified bond portfolios held by U.S. investors has been guided by the following

More information

CFA Examination PORTFOLIO MANAGEMENT Page 1 of 6

CFA Examination PORTFOLIO MANAGEMENT Page 1 of 6 PORTFOLIO MANAGEMENT A. INTRODUCTION RETURN AS A RANDOM VARIABLE E(R) = the return around which the probability distribution is centered: the expected value or mean of the probability distribution of possible

More information

Chapter 9. The Valuation of Common Stock. 1.The Expected Return (Copied from Unit02, slide 39)

Chapter 9. The Valuation of Common Stock. 1.The Expected Return (Copied from Unit02, slide 39) Readings Chapters 9 and 10 Chapter 9. The Valuation of Common Stock 1. The investor s expected return 2. Valuation as the Present Value (PV) of dividends and the growth of dividends 3. The investor s required

More information

t = 1 2 3 1. Calculate the implied interest rates and graph the term structure of interest rates. t = 1 2 3 X t = 100 100 100 t = 1 2 3

t = 1 2 3 1. Calculate the implied interest rates and graph the term structure of interest rates. t = 1 2 3 X t = 100 100 100 t = 1 2 3 MØA 155 PROBLEM SET: Summarizing Exercise 1. Present Value [3] You are given the following prices P t today for receiving risk free payments t periods from now. t = 1 2 3 P t = 0.95 0.9 0.85 1. Calculate

More information

The comovement of US and German bond markets

The comovement of US and German bond markets The comovement of US and German bond markets Tom Engsted and Carsten Tanggaard The Aarhus School of Business, Fuglesangs alle 4, DK-8210 Aarhus V. E-mails: tom@asb.dk (Engsted); cat@asb.dk (Tanggaard).

More information

The VAR models discussed so fare are appropriate for modeling I(0) data, like asset returns or growth rates of macroeconomic time series.

The VAR models discussed so fare are appropriate for modeling I(0) data, like asset returns or growth rates of macroeconomic time series. Cointegration The VAR models discussed so fare are appropriate for modeling I(0) data, like asset returns or growth rates of macroeconomic time series. Economic theory, however, often implies equilibrium

More information

Marketing Mix Modelling and Big Data P. M Cain

Marketing Mix Modelling and Big Data P. M Cain 1) Introduction Marketing Mix Modelling and Big Data P. M Cain Big data is generally defined in terms of the volume and variety of structured and unstructured information. Whereas structured data is stored

More information

Broker-Dealer Leverage and the Cross-Section of Stock Returns 1

Broker-Dealer Leverage and the Cross-Section of Stock Returns 1 Broker-Dealer Leverage and the Cross-Section of Stock Returns 1 Tobias Adrian, Erkko Etula and Tyler Muir Federal Reserve Bank of New York and Northwestern University Bank of England, January -5, 11 1

More information

FRBSF ECONOMIC LETTER

FRBSF ECONOMIC LETTER FRBSF ECONOMIC LETTER 213-23 August 19, 213 The Price of Stock and Bond Risk in Recoveries BY SIMON KWAN Investor aversion to risk varies over the course of the economic cycle. In the current recovery,

More information

How To Understand And Understand Finance

How To Understand And Understand Finance Ill. i,t.,. QUANTITATIVE FINANCIAL ECONOMICS STOCKS, BONDS AND FOREIGN EXCHANGE Second Edition KEITH CUTHBERTSON AND DIRK NITZSCHE HOCHSCHULE John Wiley 8k Sons, Ltd CONTENTS Preface Acknowledgements 2.1

More information

Internet Appendix to Stock Market Liquidity and the Business Cycle

Internet Appendix to Stock Market Liquidity and the Business Cycle Internet Appendix to Stock Market Liquidity and the Business Cycle Randi Næs, Johannes A. Skjeltorp and Bernt Arne Ødegaard This Internet appendix contains additional material to the paper Stock Market

More information

What Drives the Performance of US Convertible Bond Funds?

What Drives the Performance of US Convertible Bond Funds? What Drives the Performance of US Convertible Bond Funds? Manuel Ammann, Axel Kind, and Ralf Seiz May 2006 Abstract This paper examines the return characteristics of US mutual funds investing primarily

More information

Estimating Risk Parameters. Aswath Damodaran

Estimating Risk Parameters. Aswath Damodaran Estimating Risk Parameters Aswath Damodaran Stern School of Business 44 West Fourth Street New York, NY 10012 adamodar@stern.nyu.edu Estimating Risk Parameters Over the last three decades, the capital

More information

Section A. Index. Section A. Planning, Budgeting and Forecasting Section A.2 Forecasting techniques... 1. Page 1 of 11. EduPristine CMA - Part I

Section A. Index. Section A. Planning, Budgeting and Forecasting Section A.2 Forecasting techniques... 1. Page 1 of 11. EduPristine CMA - Part I Index Section A. Planning, Budgeting and Forecasting Section A.2 Forecasting techniques... 1 EduPristine CMA - Part I Page 1 of 11 Section A. Planning, Budgeting and Forecasting Section A.2 Forecasting

More information

PITFALLS IN TIME SERIES ANALYSIS. Cliff Hurvich Stern School, NYU

PITFALLS IN TIME SERIES ANALYSIS. Cliff Hurvich Stern School, NYU PITFALLS IN TIME SERIES ANALYSIS Cliff Hurvich Stern School, NYU The t -Test If x 1,..., x n are independent and identically distributed with mean 0, and n is not too small, then t = x 0 s n has a standard

More information

Downside market risk of carry trades

Downside market risk of carry trades Downside market risk of carry trades Victoria Dobrynskaya 1 First version: March 2010 This version: March 2013 Abstract Carry trades consistently generate high excess returns with high Sharpe ratios. I

More information

Fixed Income Portfolio Management. Interest rate sensitivity, duration, and convexity

Fixed Income Portfolio Management. Interest rate sensitivity, duration, and convexity Fixed Income ortfolio Management Interest rate sensitivity, duration, and convexity assive bond portfolio management Active bond portfolio management Interest rate swaps 1 Interest rate sensitivity, duration,

More information

IMPACT OF SOCIAL MEDIA ON THE STOCK MARKET: EVIDENCE FROM TWEETS

IMPACT OF SOCIAL MEDIA ON THE STOCK MARKET: EVIDENCE FROM TWEETS IMPACT OF SOCIAL MEDIA ON THE STOCK MARKET: EVIDENCE FROM TWEETS Vojtěch Fiala 1, Svatopluk Kapounek 1, Ondřej Veselý 1 1 Mendel University in Brno Volume 1 Issue 1 ISSN 2336-6494 www.ejobsat.com ABSTRACT

More information

A Mean-Variance Framework for Tests of Asset Pricing Models

A Mean-Variance Framework for Tests of Asset Pricing Models A Mean-Variance Framework for Tests of Asset Pricing Models Shmuel Kandel University of Chicago Tel-Aviv, University Robert F. Stambaugh University of Pennsylvania This article presents a mean-variance

More information

Lecture 6: Arbitrage Pricing Theory

Lecture 6: Arbitrage Pricing Theory Lecture 6: Arbitrage Pricing Theory Investments FIN460-Papanikolaou APT 1/ 48 Overview 1. Introduction 2. Multi-Factor Models 3. The Arbitrage Pricing Theory FIN460-Papanikolaou APT 2/ 48 Introduction

More information

SAMPLE MID-TERM QUESTIONS

SAMPLE MID-TERM QUESTIONS SAMPLE MID-TERM QUESTIONS William L. Silber HOW TO PREPARE FOR THE MID- TERM: 1. Study in a group 2. Review the concept questions in the Before and After book 3. When you review the questions listed below,

More information

Chapter 3 - Selecting Investments in a Global Market

Chapter 3 - Selecting Investments in a Global Market Chapter 3 - Selecting Investments in a Global Market Questions to be answered: Why should investors have a global perspective regarding their investments? What has happened to the relative size of U.S.

More information

Cost of Capital Presentation for ERRA Tariff Committee Dr. Konstantin Petrov / Waisum Cheng / Dr. Daniel Grote April 2009 Experience you can trust.

Cost of Capital Presentation for ERRA Tariff Committee Dr. Konstantin Petrov / Waisum Cheng / Dr. Daniel Grote April 2009 Experience you can trust. Cost of Capital Presentation for ERRA Tariff Committee Dr. Konstantin Petrov / Waisum Cheng / Dr. Daniel Grote April 2009 Experience you can trust. Agenda 1.Definition of Cost of Capital a) Concept and

More information

Glossary of Investment Terms

Glossary of Investment Terms online report consulting group Glossary of Investment Terms glossary of terms actively managed investment Relies on the expertise of a portfolio manager to choose the investment s holdings in an attempt

More information

Life Cycle Asset Allocation A Suitable Approach for Defined Contribution Pension Plans

Life Cycle Asset Allocation A Suitable Approach for Defined Contribution Pension Plans Life Cycle Asset Allocation A Suitable Approach for Defined Contribution Pension Plans Challenges for defined contribution plans While Eastern Europe is a prominent example of the importance of defined

More information

Financial predictors of real activity and the financial accelerator B

Financial predictors of real activity and the financial accelerator B Economics Letters 82 (2004) 167 172 www.elsevier.com/locate/econbase Financial predictors of real activity and the financial accelerator B Ashoka Mody a,1, Mark P. Taylor b,c, * a Research Department,

More information

Fama and French Three-Factor Model: Evidence from Istanbul Stock Exchange

Fama and French Three-Factor Model: Evidence from Istanbul Stock Exchange Volume 4 Number 2 2013 pp. 11-22 ISSN: 1309-2448 www.berjournal.com Fama and French Three-Factor Model: Evidence from Istanbul Stock Exchange Veysel Eraslan a Abstract: This study tests the validity of

More information

Final Exam MØA 155 Financial Economics Fall 2009 Permitted Material: Calculator

Final Exam MØA 155 Financial Economics Fall 2009 Permitted Material: Calculator University of Stavanger (UiS) Stavanger Masters Program Final Exam MØA 155 Financial Economics Fall 2009 Permitted Material: Calculator The number in brackets is the weight for each problem. The weights

More information

Dividend yields, dividend growth, and return predictability. in the cross-section of stocks

Dividend yields, dividend growth, and return predictability. in the cross-section of stocks Dividend yields, dividend growth, and return predictability in the cross-section of stocks Paulo Maio 1 Pedro Santa-Clara 2 First version: June 2012 This version: November 2012 3 1 Hanken School of Economics.

More information

Investors and Central Bank s Uncertainty Embedded in Index Options On-Line Appendix

Investors and Central Bank s Uncertainty Embedded in Index Options On-Line Appendix Investors and Central Bank s Uncertainty Embedded in Index Options On-Line Appendix Alexander David Haskayne School of Business, University of Calgary Pietro Veronesi University of Chicago Booth School

More information