The Plaintiff s Attorney in the Liability Insurance Claims Settlement Process: A Game Theoretic Approach

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "The Plaintiff s Attorney in the Liability Insurance Claims Settlement Process: A Game Theoretic Approach"

Transcription

1 The Plaintiff s Attorney in the Liability Insurance Claims Settlement Process: A Game Theoretic Approach Lisa L. Posey * Abstract: The decision of a claimant to obtain legal counsel, the timing of this decision, and the impact on the settlement amount an insurer successfully can offer are the focus of this study. This paper draws on strategic models of litigation/settlement with endogenous settlement amounts in the law and economics literature, but differs by endogenizing the decision to hire an attorney and its timing. The main results are that under symmetric damage information the claimant gains bargaining power over the insurer and a higher net payoff by retaining an attorney on a contingency fee basis before the insurer makes an offer. Hourly fees never appear in equilibrium under symmetric information. Under asymmetric information when only contingency fees are available, there exists a separating equilibrium where the insurer can deduce the expected damage award of each claimant by his attorney-hiring strategy and offer a settlement appropriate for each type. There is no separating equilibrium if the possibility of hourly fees is included. L INTRODUCTION iability insurers settle over 98% of all third-party claims out of court (Litan, Swire, and Winston, 1988). Claimants may enter the settlement process with an attorney or deal directly with the insurer. What can those who hire an attorney at the beginning of the process gain from doing so * Lisa L. Posey is Assistant Professor, Department of Insurance and Real Estate, Penn State University. 119 Journal of Insurance Issues, 1998, 21, 2, pp Copyright 1998 by the Western Risk and Insurance Association. All rights reserved.

2 120 LISA L. POSEY and can insurers infer anything about claimants from their decision to hire an attorney? These questions are addressed in this paper using a game theoretic approach to the settlement process. The decision of a claimant to obtain legal counsel, the timing of this decision, the type of fee arrangement used, and the impact that all these factors have on the settlement amount an insurer can offer and expect to have accepted are the focus of this study. The main results are that under symmetric damage information the claimant gains bargaining power over the insurer and a higher net payoff by retaining an attorney on a contingency fee basis before the insurer makes an offer. Hourly fees never appear in equilibrium under symmetric information. Under asymmetric information when only contingency fees are available, there exists a separating equilibrium where the insurer can deduce the true damage type of each claimant by his attorney-hiring strategy and offer a settlement appropriate for each type. There is no separating equilibrium if the possibility of hourly fees is included. This paper draws on strategic models of litigation versus settlement with endogenous settlement amounts developed in the law and economics literature (see Bebchuck, 1984; Nalebuff, 1987; Salant, 1984; Reinganum and Wilde, 1986). The litigation versus settlement issue was first analyzed in the 1970s by Landes (1971) and Gould (1973). 1 These early papers focus on why some cases end up in court and some settle out of court. They do not model the pre-trial bargaining process explicitly and are unable to make predictions about settlement amounts. A second generation of papers (e.g., Bebchuck, 1984; Nalebuff, 1987; Salant, 1984; Reinganum and Wilde, 1986) uses game theoretic bargaining models to address the litigation versus settlement issue. In these models, informational asymmetries between the parties are made explicit and equilibrium settlement amounts can be derived. One party makes a take-it-or-leave-it settlement offer to the other party, who must decide whether to accept or reject the offer. If the offer is rejected, the plaintiff decides whether to pursue the case in court. It is the threat of litigation and the expected payoffs at trial that determine the optimal settlement amount. If the parties are symmetrically informed about the level of damages and the probability of winning at trial, and the defendant makes a settlement offer, then the plaintiff will accept any offer that is greater than or equal to his or her expected payoff at trial net of litigation costs. Therefore, the defendant s optimal offer is the plaintiff s expected net payoff at trial. In symmetric information models, the equilibrium concept used is subgame perfect Nash equilibrium. When the parties are asymmetrically informed about either the level of damages or the probability of winning at trial, it is important whether it is the informed party or uninformed party that makes the offer. The

3 PLAINTIFF S ATTORNEY IN LIABILITY CLAIMS SETTLEMENT PROCESS 121 informed party s offer may convey some information to the other party, who must then decide whether or not to accept. Bebchuck (1984) and Nalebuff (1987) develop models where the uninformed party makes the settlement offer, while Salant (1984) and Reinganum and Wilde (1986) have the party with private information about the level of damages making the settlement offer. In these models of asymmetric information, the equilibrium concepts used are the perfect Bayesian equilibrium or the sequential equilibrium. Three more recent papers explore the effects of relaxing the assumption (made in the previous bargaining models of settlement and litigation) that only one party makes a take-it-or-leave-it offer and the other party must accept it or reject it and face costly litigation. Cheung (1988) develops a sequential bargaining model under symmetric damage information, where each party has the option to make a counteroffer after rejecting the previous offer and the plaintiff has the outside option of going to trial. He finds that the unique subgame perfect Nash equilibrium in this model is the same as that under a model where only the defendant makes an offer and the plaintiff can either accept it or reject it and go to court. In particular, the parties will settle immediately for the plaintiff s expected judgment at trial less litigation costs. Wang, Kim, and Yi (1994) consider a model where the defendant and plaintiff can exchange an infinite number of offers and counteroffers and the plaintiff has private information about actual damages. They find that there is a unique sequential equilibrium where the defendant makes an offer that is accepted by plaintiffs with expected net payoffs from litigation less than the offer and rejected by any other plaintiffs, who then proceed to trial rather than making counteroffers. This too mirrors the outcome under the single take-it-or-leave-it offer models of previous research. Finally, Daugherty and Reinganum (1993) study a model with endogenous sequencing of settlement offers. They allow either the plaintiff or the defendant or both to make the first offer, and it is endogenously determined who actually decides to make an offer. They show that the equilibrium payoffs that arise in their model coincide with those in the standard models of litigation and settlement where one party or the other is assumed to make an offer. These results support the use of the more simple static models of the settlement negotiation process in previous work. This growing body of literature is directly applicable to the study of insurance claims settlement practices. Many of the above studies cite statistics on insurers settlement versus litigations ratios to motivate their analysis. Although these researchers intend for their models to represent the insurance claims settlement process, insurance researchers can add to

4 122 LISA L. POSEY this literature by incorporating additional characteristics of the insurance claims settlement process into the existing models. That is one of the goals of the current paper. This paper adds the role of the plaintiff s attorney into the settlement process. In the present setting, the plaintiff is referred to as the claimant and the defendant is represented by the insurer. The claimant has the option of either hiring an attorney at a competitively determined fee at the beginning of the settlement process or delaying such action until and unless the case proceeds to trial. An attorney is necessary for the trial phase but the settlement negotiations may be performed by either the claimant or the attorney. The model is analyzed under various assumptions about the type of fee arrangements available to the claimant, first under symmetric information and then under asymmetric information where only the claimant and his or her attorney (if one is hired) know the true expected value of the damages to be awarded at trial. It is assumed that the insurer makes a settlement offer and the claimant must either accept the offer or reject it and proceed to trial. 2 Therefore, under asymmetric information, it is the uninformed party that makes the settlement offer but it is the informed party that moves first in the game by choosing whether or not to hire an attorney. In the typical asymmetric information models of litigation and settlement, either it is assumed that the informed party makes the settlement offer, in which case the settlement offer signals some information to the other party, or else it is assumed that the uninformed party makes the settlement offer. A goal of this paper is to see if something other than a settlement offer, namely the decision to hire an attorney, can be used by a claimant to signal information about expected damages and whether insurers can in fact infer anything about a claimant from his or her decision to hire an attorney. This can be analyzed best with a model in which the claimant makes the first move (deciding whether to hire an attorney) and the insurer makes the settlement offer. Although this paper is unique in endogenizing the decision to hire an attorney, there is a body of literature on plaintiffs attorneys in the litigation process with an emphasis on the role of various fee structures such as contingency fees and hourly fees (see, for example, Clermont and Currivan, 1970; Schwartz and Mitchell, 1978; Danzon, 1983; Miller, 1987; Halpern and Turnbull, 1983; Miceli and Segerson, 1991; Miceli, 1994; Hay, 1997). A few studies have looked at plaintiffs attorneys as providing specific expertise. Watts (1994) assumes that attorneys are able to learn part of the defendant s private information at a lower cost than plaintiffs can and Dana and Spier (1993) consider the case where attorneys can more accurately determine

5 PLAINTIFF S ATTORNEY IN LIABILITY CLAIMS SETTLEMENT PROCESS 123 the merits of the case than plaintiffs can. In none of these models has the timing of the decision to hire an attorney or the decision itself been endogenized, as is the case in the current model. These previous studies take the decision to hire an attorney and the time the attorney enters the process as given. BASIC MODEL WITH SYMMETRIC DAMAGE INFORMATION Contingency Fee Arrangements Only Assume that an injury has occurred and that the victim has filed a claim with the insurer s liability insurance company. The insurer has routinely performed a preliminary investigation and determined that the policyholder is liable and that the expected value of the damages to be awarded at trial is d. All parties are assumed to observe d in this section. 3 At this point the claimant faces the decision of whether or not to hire an attorney for the settlement process or delay such action until and unless it is necessary to proceed to trial. The claimant s attorney-hiring decision is denoted A; A = 0 indicates that the claimant does not hire an attorney for the settlement phase and A = 1 indicates that the claimant does hire an attorney. It is assumed that an attorney must be hired if a trial ensues and that those who hire an attorney earlier in the process continue with this attorney through trial if settlement is not reached. The market for attorneys is assumed to be competitive. It is first assumed that claimants can afford an attorney only if a contingency fee arrangement is used (i.e., if they had to pay out of their own wealth before they received a judgment, they would not be able to afford an attorney). F S is the cost incurred by an attorney for providing services to a claimant during the settlement phase and F T is the cost incurred by an attorney for providing services to a claimant during a trial. If an attorney is hired before the settlement phase begins and ends up in a trial, the total costs incurred by the attorney will be F S + F T. The market for attorneys is competitive, so that the equilibrium fees are a function of these costs, and the costs are assumed to be known by all. If an attorney is hired, the claimant and attorney agree on a contingency fee rate at the onset of their relationship. In equilibrium, the zero expected profit contingency fee rate, determined at the onset of the relationship, will incorporate the expectation of trial versus settlement as well as the insurer s optimal settlement offer strategy. Once the claimant has entered the settlement phase, the insurer can observe whether an attorney has been hired. The

6 124 LISA L. POSEY Figure 1. insurer then makes a settlement offer to the claimant and the claimant may accept or reject the offer. If the offer is rejected, the claimant takes the case to trial using either a newly hired attorney or one hired at the earlier phase. The amount of damages awarded at trial is a random variable with an expected value equal to d. Figure 1 presents a game tree representing the situation considered here. 4 At the first node, the claimant decides whether or not to hire an attorney. If so, the claimant and attorney set their zero expected profit contingency fee rate. At the second set of nodes, the insurer decides what settlement offer to make. At the third set of nodes, the claimant either accepts or rejects the offer. If it is rejected, the claimant hires an attorney and sets a fee if he has not hired one earlier, and then proceeds to trial. The equilibrium concept for the game in this section is subgame perfect Nash equilibrium. Beginning at the bottom of the tree, consider first the zero expected profit contingency fee if an attorney is hired just before trial (node 3B). The cost of trial to the attorney is F T and the contingency fee rate, α 0, is set so that the attorney s share is α 0 d = F T or α 0 =F T /d, where 0 signifies that an attorney was not hired at the beginning of the settlement process (A = 0). So the claimant will obtain an expected net payoff of (1 α 0 )d = d F T if he goes to trial. Therefore, the claimant will accept any settlement offer from the insurer that is greater than or equal to d F T, and the insurer s optimal strategy is to make the lowest acceptable offer, S 0 = d F T. The insurer prefers this amount to going to trial since the insurer s expected net payout at trial is d + C (C is the insurer s litigation cost), which is greater than d F T. Next consider the claimant s decision to accept or reject the offer if an attorney has been hired earlier in the process. The claimant and attorney have set the contingency fee rate, α 1, at the onset of their relationship, before an offer has been made (the 1 signifies that A = 1, i.e., that an attorney has been hired for the settlement phase). When such a claimant considers a

7 PLAINTIFF S ATTORNEY IN LIABILITY CLAIMS SETTLEMENT PROCESS 125 settlement offer, his expected damage award at trial is d, and he expects to retain (1 α 1 )d. The claimant likewise will retain (1 α 1 )S 1 of any settlement offer S 1 made. Therefore, he will not accept any offer less than the true expected damages d. So the insurer s optimal strategy is to offer S 1 = d. How will α 1 be set? The insurer s optimal strategy is to offer d, which will be accepted. The expectation is that they will settle out of court and the attorney s cost for participating in the settlement part of the process is F S. This implies that the zero expected profit contingency fee rate satisfies α 1 d = F S or α 1 = F S /d. The net payoff to the claimant in this case is (1 α 1 )d = d F S. Since F S < F T, the claimant obtains a larger net payoff by hiring an attorney earlier in the settlement stage, before an offer is made. So at node 1, the optimal strategy is to hire an attorney. Result: In equilibrium, the claimant hires an attorney on a contingency fee basis and is able to obtain a net payoff of d F S, which is greater than the net payoff of d F T, which would have been obtained if no attorney were hired. By retaining an attorney on a contingency fee basis before the insurer makes an offer, the claimant gains some bargaining power and a higher net payoff. The threat of trial governs the smallest amount the insurer can offer and avoid a trial. When a claimant does not have an attorney yet, the threat of trial is accompanied by a need to hire an attorney at a rate appropriate for trial costs; such costs can be subtracted from the expected judgment at trial to obtain an acceptable offer, with the insurer extracting all of the surplus. By hiring an attorney early on and pre-committing to a zero expected profit contingency fee rate with the expectation of settlement, the claimant has the ability to reject any offer that does not equal the true expected damage award at trial and the insurer cannot extract as much of the surplus. The attorney need not do anything but enter into a contingency fee arrangement with the claimant and make his or her presence known to the insurer to aid the claimant in increasing the net payoff obtained. Contingency Fee and Hourly Fee Arrangements Available In this section, all of the previous assumptions remain, except for those regarding the potential fee arrangements between the claimants and their attorneys. Here, claimants may enter into one of two types of contracts with their attorneys, either hourly fee contracts or contingency fee contracts where the rate is agreed upon at the onset of the relationship. If an hourly fee is used, the competitive total fee for the attorney is F S if the case is settled out of court, F S + F T if the case goes to court and the attorney had been hired at the beginning of the process, and F T if the case goes to trial with an attorney hired only for the trial phase. The zero expected profit contingency

8 126 LISA L. POSEY fee rate is set in a manner similar to that in the previous section. Once the claimant has entered the settlement phase, either with or without an attorney, the insurer can observe only whether an attorney has been hired, not the type of fee arrangement or the amount of the fee. Therefore, the insurer must specify beliefs about which fee arrangement the claimant has entered into, given that an attorney is present. The equilibrium concept used for the game in this section is the perfect Bayesian equilibrium, which, in this setting, is characterized by (1) a strategy for the claimant for hiring an attorney at the beginning of the settlement process: the claimant must specify whether he will hire an attorney under a contingency fee arrangement, hire an attorney under an hourly fee arrangement, or not hire an attorney, given the competitively determined fees; (2) a probability distribution representing the insurer s set of beliefs about which type of fee arrangement the claimant and attorney entered into if an attorney has been hired; (3) a settlement strategy for the insurer specifying two out-of-court settlement offers S A, A = 0,1, one for claimants with attorneys and one for claimants without attorneys; (4) an accept or reject strategy for the settlement offer for the claimant for each attorney strategy, where these strategies and beliefs satisfy the following requirements: (a) Pr(Contingency Fee Attorney) 0, Pr(Hourly Fee Attorney) 0, and Pr(Contingency Fee Attorney) + Pr(Hourly Fee Attorney) = 1; (b) the players strategies are sequentially rational; 5 (c) for each claimant strategy, given the fee structure, the insurer s beliefs at the information set corresponding to that strategy must follow from Bayes Rule and the claimant s strategy. Figure 2 presents a game tree representing the situation where both types of fee arrangements are available and information about the expected damage award is symmetric. At the first node, the claimant decides whether or not to hire an attorney and what type of fee arrangement to enter into if an attorney is hired. The claimant and attorney set their zero expected profit fees at this stage as well. At the second set of nodes, the insurer decides what settlement offer to make. The insurer knows if it

9 PLAINTIFF S ATTORNEY IN LIABILITY CLAIMS SETTLEMENT PROCESS 127 Figure 2. is at node 2C but cannot distinguish between 2A and 2B. At the third set of nodes, the claimant either accepts or rejects the offer. If it is rejected, the claimant hires an attorney and sets a fee if he has not done so earlier, and then proceeds to trial. Beginning at the bottom of the tree, consider the zero expected profit fee if an attorney is hired just before trial (node 3C). The total hourly fee will be F T since the cost to the attorney is F T. If a contingency fee is used, the rate, α 0, is set so that the attorney s share α 0 d = F T or α 0 = F T /d. So the payment to the attorney will be F T whether a contingency fee or hourly fee arrangement is used and the claimant will obtain an expected net payoff of d F T. Therefore, the claimant will accept any settlement offer from the insurer that is greater than or equal to d F T (regardless of the fee arrangement), and the insurer s optimal strategy (at node 2C) is to make the lowest acceptable offer, S 0 = d F T. The insurer prefers this to going to trial since the insurer s expected net payout at trial is d + C, which is greater than d F T. If the claimant hires an attorney under an hourly fee arrangement at the beginning of the settlement process, then once node 3B is reached, the claimant has paid the attorney F S and must pay an additional F T if they proceed to trial. Just as is the case where no attorney is hired until trial, the claimant will accept any offer greater than or equal to d F T if he has previously retained an attorney on an hourly fee basis, since this is the net payoff he can expect from the trial phase. If, on the other hand, the claimant hires an attorney under a contingency fee arrangement, as before he will only accept a settlement offer that is not less than the true expected damage

10 128 LISA L. POSEY award. The reasoning for this follows the previous model: the percentage of the insurer s payment given to the attorney is fixed at the beginning of the process and nothing less than the true expected value of the damages that will be awarded at trial will be an acceptable offer. The insurer must determine its optimal settlement offer strategy if the claimant hires an attorney. If the attorney is hired on an hourly fee basis, the optimal offer is d F T, and if the attorney is hired on a contingency fee basis, the optimal offer is d. Knowing only that either node 2A or node 2B has been reached, the insurer must specify beliefs about which node has been reached and then determine which of these two offers is the optimal offer, given those beliefs. Only the offers that are optimal for each of the two fee arrangements need to be considered by the insurer, since any offer between the two will not be accepted by the claimant with a contingency fee arrangement and will pay the claimant with an hourly fee arrangement more than is necessary to get him to accept the offer. Since the beliefs should follow Bayes Rule given the claimant s strategies in equilibrium, the various potential equilibria will be considered at this point. As will be shown, an equilibrium exists where the claimant hires an attorney on a contingency fee basis, there is no equilibrium where an attorney is hired on an hourly fee basis, but there is an equilibrium where no attorney is hired. The first potential equilibrium to be considered is the one that arises in the previous section: (i) the claimant hires an attorney at the beginning of the settlement process on a contingency fee basis; (ii) the insurer offers d to claimants with attorneys and d F T to claimants without attorneys; (iii) the claimant, who has an attorney, accepts the offer; (iv) the contingency fee is α 1 = F S /d, the claimant has a net payoff of d F S ; (v) the insurer s beliefs are characterized by putting probability = 1 on being at node 2A and probability = 0 on being at node 2B (this follows from Bayes Rule and the equilibrium strategies). The claimant has no incentive to deviate from this strategy, since he will obtain a net payoff of d F T without an attorney and d F S F T with an attorney on an hourly fee basis. So the equilibrium where the claimant hires an attorney on a contingency fee basis, which is the unique equilibrium in the previous section (with no possibility of hourly fees), also exists when the possibility of hourly fees is included.

11 PLAINTIFF S ATTORNEY IN LIABILITY CLAIMS SETTLEMENT PROCESS 129 Result: There is no equilibrium where the claimant hires an attorney on an hourly fee basis with symmetric information about the expected damage award. This can be shown as follows. If the claimant hires an attorney on an hourly fee basis, the insurer must place probability = 1 on the event of being at node 2B and will, therefore, offer d F T. The claimant will obtain net payoff of d F S F T and can improve upon this by not hiring an attorney and obtaining d F T, which is the insurer s optimal offer if no attorney is hired. Finally, consider the potential equilibrium where no attorney is hired. Here the claimant receives offer d F T and accepts and retains the entire offer. Whether the claimant has an incentive to deviate depends upon what the insurer offers if an attorney is hired. Because nodes 2A and 2B are off the equilibrium path, the insurer can place any probabilities on them under the concept of perfect Bayesian equilibrium, provided that they sum to one. In any event, only one of two offers will be made to a claimant with an attorney, either d or d F T. If the offer is d, the claimant will prefer to deviate and hire an attorney on a contingency fee basis, obtain a rate appropriate for the expectation of settlement, accept the offer and net d F S. Therefore, if the insurer s beliefs are such that the optimal offer to make to a claimant with an attorney is d, then an equilibrium where no attorney is hired cannot be sustained. But if the insurer s beliefs are such that it is optimal to offer d F T to a claimant with an attorney (in which case the claimant will net d F T F S if an attorney is hired), then the claimant will have no incentive to deviate from the strategy of not hiring an attorney. Result: An equilibrium where no attorney is hired and the net payoff to the claimant is d F T can be sustained when the possibility of hourly fee arrangements is included in the model even though such fee arrangements never appear in equilibrium. This net payoff is less than the net payoff of d F S that would be obtained under a contingency fee equilibrium. ASYMMETRIC DAMAGE INFORMATION Contingency Fee Arrangements Only Next, consider the case where there are two types of claimants high damage and low damage and a claimant is high damage with probability λ and low damage with probability 1 λ. A high (low) damage claimant has private information about the case and knows that the true expected value of the damage award at trial is d H (d L ), while the insurer has only the

12 130 LISA L. POSEY ex ante belief that the expected award at trial is the average expected award, λd H + (1 λ)d L. 6 We return, temporarily, to the assumption that the claimant can only afford to enter into a contingency fee arrangement and hourly fee arrangements are not offered by attorneys. This situation is depicted in Figure 3. The equilibrium concept used for this game with asymmetric damage information is again the perfect Bayesian equilibrium. In this context, the perfect Bayesian equilibrium is defined as: (1) an attorney-hiring strategy for the claimant for the settlement phase; for each type j the claimant may turn out to be, he must specify whether or not he will hire an attorney for the settlement phase, given the competitively determined contingency fees; (2) a probability distribution representing the insurer s set of beliefs about which type the claimant is, given whether or not he hired an attorney. Let µ(j A) be the insurer s belief about the probability of the claimant being of type j, given A, where A = 1 means that an attorney has been hired for the settlement phase and A = 0 means an attorney has not been hired; (3) a settlement strategy for the insurer specifying two out-of-court settlement offers, one for the case where an attorney is present, the other for the case where no attorney is present; (4) an accept or reject strategy for the settlement offer for each claimant type, where these strategies and beliefs satisfy the following requirements: (a) µ(j A) 0 and µ(h A) + µ(l A) = 1; (b) the players strategies are sequentially rational; (c) for each claimant strategy, given the fee structure, the insurer s beliefs at the information set corresponding to that strategy must follow from Bayes Rule and the claimant s strategy. The decisions of each claimant type regarding acceptance or rejection of the settlement offer at the fourth set of nodes are the same as was the case under symmetric damage information with only contingency fees (the third set of nodes in Figure 1). For a claimant of type j, j = L,H, the true expected damage award is denoted d j, and the contingency fee is denoted α j A.7 Without having hired an attorney in the earlier stage, the claimant must hire one to proceed to trial at contingency fee rate α j 0 = F T /d j and, therefore, will accept any offer greater than or equal to d j F T. On the other hand, if an attorney has been hired early on, the claimant will net (1 α j 1 )d j

13 PLAINTIFF S ATTORNEY IN LIABILITY CLAIMS SETTLEMENT PROCESS 131 at trial and (1 α j 1)S 1 through settlement and, therefore, only will accept offers at least as great as the true expected damage award, d j. Parameter conditions exist that support a pooling equilibrium with attorneys and a pooling equilibrium without attorneys. Our attention will be focused on the potential separating equilibrium in this setting. A separating equilibrium would allow the insurer to infer the claimant s damage type by the presence or absence of an attorney. In this setting of asymmetric damage information and contingency fees only, the following can be shown. Result: There exists a separating equilibrium where the low damage claimant hires an attorney on a contingency fee basis, the high damage claimant does not hire an attorney, and the insurer can deduce the expected damage award of each claimant and offer a settlement of d H F T to the high damage claimant and d L to the low damage claimant, both of which will be accepted. To see this, consider Figure 3. If the claimant s strategy is to hire an attorney if damages are low and not hire an attorney if damages are high, then the insurer must place probability = 1 of being at node 3B if an attorney is not hired and probability = 1 of being at node 3C if an attorney is hired. Therefore, the optimal settlement offer is d H F T if an attorney is not hired and d L if an attorney is hired. Both claimant types will accept their offers, the low damage type will have a net payoff of d L F S and the high damage type will have a net payoff of d H F T. When d H F T d L F S, the claimants have no incentive to deviate and this will be a separating equilibrium. In this case, the low damage claimant will have no incentive to deviate because he has a greater net payoff, d L F S, than if he deviated by not hiring an attorney and obtained d H F T. But why doesn t the high damage type deviate, given that the low damage type is obtaining a greater net payoff than he is? If the high damage type deviates and hires an attorney on a contingency fee basis, the attorney knows that the claimant will not accept the insurer s offer since he can do better by going to trial. Therefore, he cannot obtain a contingency fee based on the expectation of accepting the settlement offer d L. Instead, deviating to a contingency arrangement would give the high damage claimant a net payoff of d H F S F T, which is worse than remaining without an attorney. So the very pre-commitment to a contingency fee that gave the claimant additional bargaining power over the insurer with symmetric damage information prevents the claimant from credibly promising to settle for less than the true expected damage award, thereby leaving him with a high attorney s fee in this setting of asymmetric damage information. In this setting, it is the insurer who

14 132 LISA L. POSEY Figure 3. benefits from the lack of an hourly fee arrangement since the insurer can accurately deduce each claimant s type and reduce the high damage claimant s offer by the full cost of a trial. In the next section, the effect of adding an hourly fee arrangement under asymmetric information on the existence of the separating equilibrium, as well as the potential use of hourly fees in equilibrium, will be analyzed. Contingency Fee and Hourly Fee Arrangements Available The circumstances of the preceding separating equilibrium raise a few issues. The high damage claimant is locked into a fee appropriate for trial under contingency fees even though the payoff would be greater if the offer of d L < d H could be accepted and trial avoided. Including the potential of an hourly fee arrangement would allow the claimant to confine attorney s fees to those appropriate for settlement, since the claimant would have no incentive to proceed to trial and would accept d L. Result: There is no separating equilibrium if the possibility of an hourly fee arrangement is included in the model with asymmetric damage information, so the insurer cannot deduce the true damage type of the claimant.

15 PLAINTIFF S ATTORNEY IN LIABILITY CLAIMS SETTLEMENT PROCESS 133 To see this, consider Figure 4. If the claimant hires an attorney, the insurer does not know if node 3A, 3B, 3D, or 3E has been reached. The optimal strategies of the claimant at the fourth set of nodes are identical to the accept/reject strategies for the game in Figure 2. Now consider the potential separating equilibrium similar to the one noted above, where the low damage claimant hires an attorney on a contingency fee basis, the high damage claimant does not hire an attorney, the insurer offers d L to the claimant with an attorney and d H F T to the claimant without an attorney, and d H F T < d L F S. The high damage claimant now has an incentive to deviate, hire an attorney on an hourly fee basis, and settle out of court, accepting d L and getting net payoff d L F S. In addition, no separating equilibrium exists where one claimant hires an attorney on an hourly fee basis and the other does not hire an attorney. The best either claimant type can do by separating themselves, by hiring an attorney on an hourly fee basis while the other claimant type hires no attorney, is to obtain d j F S F T, which is less than the minimum they could obtain by not hiring an attorney earlier in the process, going to trial, and netting d j F T. So separation is not possible when hourly fees are possible. A logical next question is whether any claimant would hire an attorney on an hourly fee basis in equilibrium, if such fee arrangements were available. The answer is a qualified yes. More specifically, we have the following two results. Result: Under the assumptions of asymmetric damage information and availability of both continency fee and hourly fee arrangements, there is no equilibrium where hourly fees are used by both claimant types. To see this, note that if both claimant types hired attorneys on an hourly fee basis, then the best offer they could get from the insurer is d H F T, with a net payoff of d H F S F T. The high damage claimant would always prefer to deviate and not hire an attorney and obtain net payoff d H F T. Result: Under the assumptions of asymmetric damage information and availability of both continency fee and hourly fee arrangements, there are parameter conditions that support an equilibrium where one type of claimant hires an attorney on an hourly fee basis and the other type of claimant hires an attorney on a contingency fee basis. Consider the case noted earlier, where a separating equilibrium would be supported without hourly fees, but not when hourly fees are available (i.e., d H F T < d L F S ). An equilibrium with the following characteristics can be sustained if d L < λ[d H F T ] + (1 λ)[d L + C]: (i) the high damage claimant hires an attorney on an hourly fee basis and the low damage claimant hires

16 134 LISA L. POSEY Figure 4. an attorney on a contingency fee basis, (ii) the insurer offers d L to those with an attorney, (iii) the attorney sets contingency fees based on acceptance of the offer for L types and going to trial for H types, but the H types do not use contingency fees, and (iv) both claimant types accept the offer. Returning to Figure 4, the insurer doesn t know whether it is at node 3B or 3D. The two settlement offers to consider are d H F T (appropriate for node 3B) and d L (appropriate for node 3D). If the insurer chooses to offer d L, which will be the case if d L < λ[d H F T ] + (1 λ)[d L + C], then neither H s nor L s will have an incentive to deviate. Their net payoff by accepting d L is d L F S, while the most they can obtain by not hiring an attorney is d H F T. L s are indifferent to hiring an attorney on an hourly fee basis and H s would do worse by deviating to a contingency fee. This differs from the result under symmetric damage information, where hourly fees would never be observed in equilibrium. There, contingency fees always give the claimant additional bargaining over the insurer relative to hourly fees. But in this setting, the asymmetry of damage information means that a claimant with an hourly fee arrangement may get a more attractive offer targeting the other claimant type who is using a contingency fee arrangement, leaving no incentive to deviate from an hourly fee arrangement.

17 PLAINTIFF S ATTORNEY IN LIABILITY CLAIMS SETTLEMENT PROCESS 135 SUMMARY The decision of a claimant in the liability insurance claims settlement process to obtain legal counsel, the timing of this decision, the type of fee arrangement used, and the impact that all these factors have on the settlement amount an insurer can offer and expect to have accepted are the focus of this study. This paper draws on strategic models of litigation versus settlement with endogenous settlement amounts developed in the law and economics literature, but differs from previous studies by endogenizing the decision to hire an attorney and the time the attorney enters the process. The main results are that under symmetric damage information the claimant gains bargaining power over the insurer and a higher net payoff by retaining an attorney on a contingency fee basis before the insurer makes an offer, and thus this is the unique equilibrium strategy for the claimant when only contingency fees are available and an equilibrium strategy when hourly fees are also available. An equilibrium where no attorney is hired and the claimant accepts a lower settlement from the insurer than under contingency fees can be sustained when the possibility of hourly fees is included in the model even though such fee arrangements never appear in equilibrium. Under asymmetric damage information and only contingency fees, there exists a separating equilibrium where the low (high) damage claimant hires an attorney on a contingency fee basis (does not hire an attorney), and the insurer can deduce the true expected damage award of each claimant and offer and have accepted a settlement appropriate for each type. There is no separating equilibrium if the possibility of hourly fees is included in the model with asymmetric information, so the insurer cannot deduce the damage type of the claimant. The possibility of an hourly fee breaks the separating equilibrium, and there are parameter conditions that support an equilibrium where one type of claimant hires an attorney on an hourly fee basis and the other type hires one on a contingency fee basis, but there is no equilibrium where hourly fees are used by both claimant types. NOTES 1 See Cooter and Rubinfeld (1989) for a detailed review of the litigation versus settlement literature. 2 As noted above, use of this take-it-or-leave-it offer model of the bargaining process is supported by analysis of more complex models by Cheung (1988), Daugherty and Reinganum (1993), and Wang, Kim, and Yi (1994). 3 In a later section, it will be assumed that the insurer cannot observed.

18 136 LISA L. POSEY 4 Certain aspects of the game are not made explicit in this tree, since it is meant as a clarifying aid. This is true of all the figures that follow. 5 A strategy is sequentially rational if, at each information set, the action taken by the player is optimal given his beliefs at that information set and the other players subsequent strategies, where a subsequent strategy is a complete plan of action covering every contingency that might arise after the given information set is reached (see Gibbons, 1992). 6 This assumption is quite similar to the informational assumption made in the typical Rothchild-Stiglitz type of adverse selection model where the policyholder knows his or her expected loss (probability of loss with a fixed severity), but the insurer knows only the average expected loss. 7 Note that the settlement offer of the insurer does not depend on j since the insurer cannot observe d j. The settlement offer depends only upon the attorney-hiring strategy of the claimant, A, and the insurer s beliefs about the claimant s type. REFERENCES Bebchuck, Lucian (1984) Litigation and Settlement Under Imperfect Information, Rand Journal of Economics, 15, p Cheung, Rayner (1988) A Bargaining Model of Pretrial Negotiation, Working Paper No. 49, John M. Olin Program in Law and Economics, Stanford Law School. Clermont, Kevin, and John Currivan (1970) Improving on the Contingency Fee, Stanford Law Review, 22, p Cooter, R.D., and D.L. Rubinfeld (1989) An Economic Analysis of Legal Disputes and their Resolution, Journal of Economic Literature, 27, pp Dana, James, Jr., and Kathryn Spier (1993) Expertise and Contingency Fees: The Role of Asymmetric Information in Attorney Compensation, Journal of Law, Economics and Organization, 9, p Danzon, Patricia (1983) Contingency Fees for Personal Injury Litigation, Bell Journal of Economics, 14, p Daugherty, Andrew F., and Jennifer F. Reinganum (1993) Endogenous Sequencing in Models of Settlement and Litigation, Journal of Law, Economics and Organization, 9, p Gibbons, Robert (1992) Game Theory for Applied Economists. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Gould, John (1973) The Economics of Legal Conflicts, Journal of Legal Studies, 2, p Halpern, P., and S. Turnbull (1983) Legal Fees Contracts and Alternative Cost Rules: An Economic Analysis, International Review of Law and Economics, 3, p. 3. Hay, Bruce (1997) Optimal Contingency Fees in a World of Settlement, Journal of Legal Studies, 26, p Landes, William (1971) An Economic Analysis of the Courts, Journal of Law and Economics, 14, p. 61. Litan, Robert W., Peter Swire, and Clifford Winston (1988) The U.S. Liability System: Background and Trends, in R.E. Litan and C. Winston, eds., Liability: Perspectives and Policy. Washington, DC: The Brookings Institution.

19 PLAINTIFF S ATTORNEY IN LIABILITY CLAIMS SETTLEMENT PROCESS 137 Miceli, Thomas (1994) Do Contingency Fees Promote Excessive Litigation? Journal of Legal Studies, 23, p Miceli, Thomas, and Kathleen Segerson (1991) Contingency Fees for Lawyers: The Impact on Litigation and Accident Prevention, Journal of Legal Studies, 20, p Miller, Geoffrey (1987) Some Agency Problems in Settlement, Journal of Legal Studies, 16, p Nalebuff, Barry (1987) Credible Pretrial Negotiation, Rand Journal of Economics, 18, p Reinganum, Jennifer, and Louis Wilde (1986) Settlement, Litigation and the Allocation of Litigation Costs, Rand Journal of Economics, 17, p Salant, Stephen W. (1984) Litigation of Settlement Demands Questioned by Bayesian Defendants, Social Science Working Paper No. 516, California Institute of Technology. Schwartz, Murray, and Daniel Mitchell (1978) An Economic Analysis of the Contingent Fee, Cornell Law Review, 63, p Wang, Gyu Ho, Jeong-Yoo Kim, and Jong-Goo Yi (1994) Litigation and Pretrial Negotiation under Incomplete Information, Journal of Law, Economics and Organization, 10, p Watts, Alison (1994) Bargaining Through an Expert Attorney, Journal of Law, Economics and Organization, 10, pp

Published in Journal of Legal Economics, Volume 5, Number 2, Fall 1995 pp.57-65.

Published in Journal of Legal Economics, Volume 5, Number 2, Fall 1995 pp.57-65. Published in Journal of Legal Economics, Volume 5, Number 2, Fall 1995 pp.57-65. The Defense Economist s Role in Litigation Settlement Negotiations Lawrence M. Spizman Professor of Economics State University

More information

Boalt Hall UC Berkeley

Boalt Hall UC Berkeley Boalt Hall UC Berkeley Title: A Note on Settlements under the Contingent Fee Method of Compensating Lawyers Author: Polinsky, A. Mitchell, Stanford Law School Rubinfeld, Daniel L., University of California,

More information

HARVARD. Lucian Arye Bebchuk. Discussion Paper No. 226 12/1997. As published in 3 The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics and the Law 551-554 (1998)

HARVARD. Lucian Arye Bebchuk. Discussion Paper No. 226 12/1997. As published in 3 The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics and the Law 551-554 (1998) ISSN 1045-6333 HARVARD JOHN M. OLIN CENTER FOR LAW, ECONOMICS, AND BUSINESS SUITS WITH NEGATIVE EXPECTED VALUE Lucian Arye Bebchuk Discussion Paper No. 226 12/1997 As published in 3 The New Palgrave Dictionary

More information

Credible Discovery, Settlement, and Negative Expected Value Suits

Credible Discovery, Settlement, and Negative Expected Value Suits Credible iscovery, Settlement, and Negative Expected Value Suits Warren F. Schwartz Abraham L. Wickelgren Abstract: This paper introduces the option to conduct discovery into a model of settlement bargaining

More information

THE EFFECT OF SETTLEMENT IN KAPLOW S MULTISTAGE ADJUDICATION

THE EFFECT OF SETTLEMENT IN KAPLOW S MULTISTAGE ADJUDICATION THE EFFECT OF SETTLEMENT IN KAPLOW S MULTISTAGE ADJUDICATION Abraham L. Wickelgren Professor Louis Kaplow s article, Multistage Adjudication, presents an extremely useful framework for thinking about how

More information

Why Plaintiffs Attorneys Use Contingent and Defense Attorneys Fixed Fee Contracts

Why Plaintiffs Attorneys Use Contingent and Defense Attorneys Fixed Fee Contracts Why Plaintiffs Attorneys Use Contingent and Defense Attorneys Fixed Fee Contracts Winand Emons 1 Claude Fluet 2 1 Department of Economics University of Bern, CEPR, CIRPEE 2 Université du Québec à Montréal,

More information

PLEASE DO NOT QUOTE OR CIRCULATE VERY PRELIMINARY VERSION The Economics of Reverse Contingent Fees

PLEASE DO NOT QUOTE OR CIRCULATE VERY PRELIMINARY VERSION The Economics of Reverse Contingent Fees PLEASE DO NOT QUOTE OR CIRCULATE VERY PRELIMINARY VERSION The Economics of Reverse Contingent Fees Albert CHOI University of Virginia Nuno GAROUPA Universidade Nova de Lisboa CEPR, London June 2005 Abstract

More information

Switching Cost, Competition, and Pricing in the Property/Casualty Insurance Market for Large Commercial Accounts

Switching Cost, Competition, and Pricing in the Property/Casualty Insurance Market for Large Commercial Accounts Switching Cost, Competition, and Pricing in the Property/Casualty Insurance Market for Large Commercial Accounts Lisa L. Posey * Abstract: With large commercial accounts, a small number of insurers negotiate

More information

Each copy of any part of a JSTOR transmission must contain the same copyright notice that appears on the screen or printed page of such transmission.

Each copy of any part of a JSTOR transmission must contain the same copyright notice that appears on the screen or printed page of such transmission. Contingent Fees for Lawyers: The Impact on Litigation and Accident Prevention Author(s): Thomas J. Miceli and Kathleen Segerson Source: The Journal of Legal Studies, Vol. 20, No. 2 (Jun., 1991), pp. 381-399

More information

Perfect Bayesian Equilibrium

Perfect Bayesian Equilibrium Perfect Bayesian Equilibrium When players move sequentially and have private information, some of the Bayesian Nash equilibria may involve strategies that are not sequentially rational. The problem is

More information

CHICAGO. Settlement Escrows. Robert H. Gertner and Geoffrey P. Miller JOHN M. OLIN LAW & ECONOMICS WORKING PAPER NO.

CHICAGO. Settlement Escrows. Robert H. Gertner and Geoffrey P. Miller JOHN M. OLIN LAW & ECONOMICS WORKING PAPER NO. CHICAGO JOHN M. OLIN LAW & ECONOMICS WORKING PAPER NO. 25 (2D SERIES) Settlement Escrows Robert H. Gertner and Geoffrey P. Miller THE LAW SCHOOL THE UNIVERSITY OF CHICAGO SETTLEMENT ESCROWS Robert H. Gertner

More information

21. Unverifiable Investment, Hold Up, Options and Ownership

21. Unverifiable Investment, Hold Up, Options and Ownership 21. Unverifiable Investment, Hold Up, Options and Ownership This chapter applies the tools of games with joint decisions and negotiation equilibrium to study the hold up problem in economics. We first

More information

CASHING BY THE HOUR: WHY LARGE LAW FIRMS PREFER HOURLY FEES OVER CONTINGENT FEES Nuno GAROUPA and Fernando GOMEZ-POMAR This Version: July, 2002

CASHING BY THE HOUR: WHY LARGE LAW FIRMS PREFER HOURLY FEES OVER CONTINGENT FEES Nuno GAROUPA and Fernando GOMEZ-POMAR This Version: July, 2002 CASHING BY THE HOUR: WHY LARGE LAW FIRMS PREFER HOURLY FEES OVER CONTINGENT FEES Nuno GAROUPA and Fernando GOMEZ-POMAR This Version: July, 2002 Abstract Large law firms seem to prefer hourly fees over

More information

Revelation and Suppression of Private Information in Settlement Bargaining Models*

Revelation and Suppression of Private Information in Settlement Bargaining Models* Revelation and Suppression of Private Information in Settlement Bargaining Models* Andrew F. Daughety and Jennifer F. Reinganum** Department of Economics and Law School Vanderbilt University First version:

More information

Expertise, Contingent Fees, and Insufficient Attorney

Expertise, Contingent Fees, and Insufficient Attorney forthcoming in The International Review of Law and Economics Expertise, Contingent Fees, and Insufficient Attorney Effort Winand Emons University of Bern and CEPR Revised June 1999 Abstract Plaintiffs

More information

CONDITIONAL AND CONTINGENT FEES: A SURVEY OF SOME RECENT RESULTS

CONDITIONAL AND CONTINGENT FEES: A SURVEY OF SOME RECENT RESULTS CONDITIONAL AND CONTINGENT FEES: A SURVEY OF SOME RECENT RESULTS A. Introduction B. Review of the earlier literature C. The client has private information about her case D. The attorney as the client s

More information

Fee-Shifting Rules in Litigation with Contingency Fees

Fee-Shifting Rules in Litigation with Contingency Fees Fee-Shifting Rules in Litigation with Contingency Fees Kong-Ping Chen Academia Sinica kongpin@gate.sinica.edu.tw Jue-Shyan Wang National Cheng-Chi University jswang@nccu.edu.tw Abstract This paper theoretically

More information

Expertise, contingent fees, and insufficient attorney effort

Expertise, contingent fees, and insufficient attorney effort International Review of Law and Economics 20 (2000) 21 33 Expertise, contingent fees, and insufficient attorney effort Winand Emons* Universität Bern, Volkswirtschaftliches Institut, Abteilung für Wirtschaftstheorie,

More information

Patent Litigation with Endogenous Disputes

Patent Litigation with Endogenous Disputes Patent itigation with Endogenous Disputes Presentation at the AEA Annual Meeting January 6, 006 Session: Intellectual Property, itigation, and Innovation By James Bessen and Michael J. Meurer James Bessen

More information

FINANCIALLY-CONSTRAINED LAWYERS

FINANCIALLY-CONSTRAINED LAWYERS FINANCIALLY-CONSTRAINED LAWYERS CLAUDIA M. LANDEO and MAXIM NIKITIN July 7, 2015 Abstract Financial constraints reduce the lawyers ability to file lawsuits and bring cases to trial. As a result, access

More information

LITIGATION AND SETTLEMENT * Bruce L. Hay ** Kathryn E. Spier ***

LITIGATION AND SETTLEMENT * Bruce L. Hay ** Kathryn E. Spier *** JEL: K41 LITIGATION AND SETTLEMENT * Bruce L. Hay ** Kathryn E. Spier *** Abstract Perhaps the most widely discussed topic in the economics of legal procedure is the relation between litigation and settlement.

More information

Modeling the Civil Litigation Process in South Africa using Game Theory

Modeling the Civil Litigation Process in South Africa using Game Theory Modeling the Civil Litigation Process in South Africa using Game Theory T. Neuhaus, and A.L. Nel Abstract This paper reviews the historical background to civil litigation modeling from an economic perspective.

More information

Reputation in repeated settlement bargaining

Reputation in repeated settlement bargaining Reputation in repeated settlement bargaining Jihong Lee Birkbeck College, London and Yonsei University Qingmin Liu Cowles Foundation and University of Pennsylvania PRELIMINARY and INCOMPLETE commets welcome!

More information

ASYMMETRIC INFORMATION AND THE SETTLEMENT

ASYMMETRIC INFORMATION AND THE SETTLEMENT The Journal of Risk and Insurance, 2001, Vol. 68, No. 4, 615 630 ASYMMETRIC INFORMATION AND THE SETTLEMENT OF INSURANCE CLAIMS Paul Fenn Neil Rickman INTRODUCTION ABSTRACT The authors present a version

More information

Playing It Safe with Low Conditional Fees versus Being Insured by High Contingent Fees

Playing It Safe with Low Conditional Fees versus Being Insured by High Contingent Fees forthcoming in American Law and Economics Review Playing It Safe with Low Conditional Fees versus Being Insured by High Contingent Fees Winand EMONS Universität Bern and CEPR December 2005 Abstract Under

More information

Journal Of Financial And Strategic Decisions Volume 8 Number 1 Spring 1995 INTEREST RATE SWAPS: A MANAGERIAL COMPENSATION APPROACH

Journal Of Financial And Strategic Decisions Volume 8 Number 1 Spring 1995 INTEREST RATE SWAPS: A MANAGERIAL COMPENSATION APPROACH Journal Of Financial And Strategic Decisions Volume 8 Number 1 Spring 1995 INTEREST RATE SWAPS: A MANAGERIAL COMPENSATION APPROACH John L. Scott * and Maneesh Sharma * Abstract The market for interest

More information

Keeping Society in the Dark: On the Admissibility of Pretrial Negotiations as Evidence in Court* Andrew F. Daughety** and. Jennifer F.

Keeping Society in the Dark: On the Admissibility of Pretrial Negotiations as Evidence in Court* Andrew F. Daughety** and. Jennifer F. Keeping Society in the Dark: On the Admissibility of Pretrial Negotiations as Evidence in Court* by Andrew F. Daughety** and Jennifer F. Reinganum** August, 1991 Latest Revision: February, 1994 * Research

More information

Why Plaintiffs Attorneys Use Contingent and Defense Attorneys Fixed Fee Contracts

Why Plaintiffs Attorneys Use Contingent and Defense Attorneys Fixed Fee Contracts Cahier de recherche/working Paper 13-38 Why Plaintiffs Attorneys Use Contingent and Defense Attorneys Fixed Fee Contracts Winand Emons Claude Fluet Octobre/October 2013 Emons: Departement Volkswirtschaftslehre,

More information

Labor Economics, 14.661. Lecture 3: Education, Selection, and Signaling

Labor Economics, 14.661. Lecture 3: Education, Selection, and Signaling Labor Economics, 14.661. Lecture 3: Education, Selection, and Signaling Daron Acemoglu MIT November 3, 2011. Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Education, Selection, and Signaling November 3, 2011. 1 / 31 Introduction

More information

Patent Litigation Insurance

Patent Litigation Insurance Business School W O R K I N G P A P E R S E R I E S Working Paper 2015-621 Patent Litigation Insurance Anne Duchêne http://www.ipag.fr/fr/accueil/la-recherche/publications-wp.html IPAG Business School

More information

Third Party Contingency contracts in settlement and litigation.

Third Party Contingency contracts in settlement and litigation. Third Party Contingency contracts in settlement and litigation. by Roland Kirstein and Neil Rickman Center for the Study of Law and Economics Discussion Paper 2002-11 Abstract We present, for the first

More information

FORIS contracts: Litigation Cost Shifting and Contingent Fees in Germany

FORIS contracts: Litigation Cost Shifting and Contingent Fees in Germany FORIS contracts: Litigation Cost Shifting and Contingent Fees in Germany by Roland Kirstein and Neil Rickman Center for the Study of Law and Economics Discussion Paper 2001-04 Abstract This paper analyzes

More information

Common Myths About Personal Injury and Wrongful Death Cases 1. By B. Keith Williams

Common Myths About Personal Injury and Wrongful Death Cases 1. By B. Keith Williams Common Myths About Personal Injury and Wrongful Death Cases 1 By B. Keith Williams There are several myths about accident cases and the attorneys that handle them. It is important to keep these myths in

More information

How To Compare The Economics Of A Contingent And Conditional Fee

How To Compare The Economics Of A Contingent And Conditional Fee The Economics of US-style Contingent Fees and UK-style Conditional Fees Winand EMONS Universität Bern CEPR Nuno GAROUPA Universidade Nova de Lisboa CEPR revised June 2005 Abstract Under contingent fees

More information

Your Personal Guide To Your Personal Injury Lawsuit

Your Personal Guide To Your Personal Injury Lawsuit Your Personal Guide To Your Personal Injury Lawsuit Know How To Do Things Right When You ve Been Wronged You have questions. And most likely, you have a lot of them. The good news is that this is completely

More information

ARBITRATION ADVISORY 1997-03 FEE ARBITRATION ISSUES INVOLVING CONTINGENCY FEES. August 22, 1997

ARBITRATION ADVISORY 1997-03 FEE ARBITRATION ISSUES INVOLVING CONTINGENCY FEES. August 22, 1997 ARBITRATION ADVISORY 1997-03 FEE ARBITRATION ISSUES INVOLVING CONTINGENCY FEES August 22, 1997 Points of view or opinions expressed in this document are those of the Committee on Mandatory Fee Arbitration.

More information

Analytical Model for Analyzing Construction Claims and Opportunistic Bidding

Analytical Model for Analyzing Construction Claims and Opportunistic Bidding Analytical Model for Analyzing Construction Claims and Opportunistic Bidding S. Ping Ho, A.M.ASCE, 1 and Liang Y. Liu, M.ASCE 2 Abstract: Construction claims are considered by many project participants

More information

Why Plaintiffs Attorneys Use Contingent and Defense Attorneys Fixed Fee Contracts

Why Plaintiffs Attorneys Use Contingent and Defense Attorneys Fixed Fee Contracts Why Plaintiffs Attorneys Use Contingent and Defense Attorneys Fixed Fee Contracts Winand Emons Universität Bern CEPR, CIRPÉE Claude Fluet Université du Québec à Montréal, CIRPÉE Version: April 2014 Abstract

More information

The Reasonable Person Negligence Standard and Liability Insurance. Vickie Bajtelsmit * Colorado State University

The Reasonable Person Negligence Standard and Liability Insurance. Vickie Bajtelsmit * Colorado State University \ins\liab\dlirpr.v3a 06-06-07 The Reasonable Person Negligence Standard and Liability Insurance Vickie Bajtelsmit * Colorado State University Paul Thistle University of Nevada Las Vegas Thistle s research

More information

FACTS ABOUT LAWYERS' INCOME AND FEES

FACTS ABOUT LAWYERS' INCOME AND FEES CENTER FOR JUSTICE & DEMOCRACY 185 WEST BROADWAY NEW YORK, NY 10013 TEL: 212.431.2882 centerjd@centerjd.org http://centerjd.org FACTS ABOUT LAWYERS' INCOME AND FEES LAWYERS INCOME According to the most

More information

Litigation and Settlement: New Evidence from Labor Courts in Mexico

Litigation and Settlement: New Evidence from Labor Courts in Mexico Journal of Empirical Legal Studies Volume 5, Issue 2, 309 350, July 2008 Litigation and Settlement: New Evidence from Labor Courts in Mexico David S. Kaplan, Joyce Sadka, and Jorge Luis Silva-Mendez* Using

More information

Estimating a Bargaining Model with Asymmetric Information: Evidence from Medical Malpractice Disputes

Estimating a Bargaining Model with Asymmetric Information: Evidence from Medical Malpractice Disputes Estimating a Bargaining Model with Asymmetric Information: Evidence from Medical Malpractice Disputes Holger Sieg The Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 108, No. 5. (Oct., 2000), pp. 1006-1021. Stable

More information

Bayesian Nash Equilibrium

Bayesian Nash Equilibrium . Bayesian Nash Equilibrium . In the final two weeks: Goals Understand what a game of incomplete information (Bayesian game) is Understand how to model static Bayesian games Be able to apply Bayes Nash

More information

The Economics of US-style Contingent Fees and UK-style Conditional Fees

The Economics of US-style Contingent Fees and UK-style Conditional Fees The Economics of US-style Contingent Fees and UK-style Conditional Fees Winand EMONS Universität Bern CEPR Nuno GAROUPA Universidade Nova de Lisboa CEPR revised December 2004 Abstract Under contingent

More information

Why Plaintiffs Attorneys Use Contingent and Defense Attorneys Fixed Fee Contracts

Why Plaintiffs Attorneys Use Contingent and Defense Attorneys Fixed Fee Contracts Why Plaintiffs Attorneys Use Contingent and Defense Attorneys Fixed Fee Contracts Winand Emons Universität Bern CEPR, CIRPÉE Claude Fluet Université Laval CIRPÉE Version: July 2015 Abstract Victims want

More information

TEN WAYS TAXES IMPACT LEGAL FEES

TEN WAYS TAXES IMPACT LEGAL FEES TEN WAYS TAXES IMPACT LEGAL FEES By Robert W. Wood 1 No one likes paying legal fees, but tax deductions make them less painful. For example, if your combined state and federal tax rate is 40%, $10,000

More information

Conditional Fee Agreement: What You Need to Know

Conditional Fee Agreement: What You Need to Know Conditional Fee Agreement: What You Need to Know This document forms an important part of your agreement with us. Please read it carefully. Definitions of words used in this document and the accompanying

More information

The Effect of Lawyers Career Concerns on Litigation

The Effect of Lawyers Career Concerns on Litigation The Effect of Lawyers Career Concerns on Litigation Rosa Ferrer Universitat ompeu Fabra and Barcelona GSE September 2015 Abstract This article studies a model with two lawyers opposing each other in a

More information

Is What You Know About Injury Claims Accurate?

Is What You Know About Injury Claims Accurate? Is What You Know About Injury Claims Accurate? Presented by: Attorney Mark L. Krueger www.kh-law.net IS WHAT YOU KNOW ABOUT INJURY CLAIMS ACCURATE? Misconception No. 1 I have no claim if the responsible

More information

professional negligence:

professional negligence: professional negligence: Conditional Fee Agreements (CFAs) Explained For CFAs not involving personal injury or clinical negligence, entered into from 1 April 2013. There is no avoiding the fact that court

More information

Capital Structure. Itay Goldstein. Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania

Capital Structure. Itay Goldstein. Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania Capital Structure Itay Goldstein Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania 1 Debt and Equity There are two main types of financing: debt and equity. Consider a two-period world with dates 0 and 1. At

More information

Does Voluntary Disclosure of Medical Errors Prompt or Prevent Medical Malpractice Suits?

Does Voluntary Disclosure of Medical Errors Prompt or Prevent Medical Malpractice Suits? Does Voluntary Disclosure of Medical Errors Prompt or Prevent Medical Malpractice Suits? Lorens A. Helmchen School of Public Health University of Illinois at Chicago Institute of Government and Public

More information

IMPROVING SETTLEMENT SAVVY. Kathy Perkins Kathy Perkins LLC, Workplace Law & Mediation www.kathy-perkins.com

IMPROVING SETTLEMENT SAVVY. Kathy Perkins Kathy Perkins LLC, Workplace Law & Mediation www.kathy-perkins.com IMPROVING SETTLEMENT SAVVY Kathy Perkins Kathy Perkins LLC, Workplace Law & Mediation www.kathy-perkins.com In these difficult economic times, parties may be looking to reduce litigation costs and risk

More information

UNITED STATES OF AMERICA. DEPARTMENT OF JUSTICE Washington, DC 20580 Washington, DC 20530. September 20, 1996

UNITED STATES OF AMERICA. DEPARTMENT OF JUSTICE Washington, DC 20580 Washington, DC 20530. September 20, 1996 UNITED STATES OF AMERICA FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION DEPARTMENT OF JUSTICE Washington, DC 20580 Washington, DC 20530 September 20, 1996 The Honorable Thomas A. Edmonds Executive Director Virginia State Bar

More information

How to Reduce the Rate of Litigation

How to Reduce the Rate of Litigation JLEO, V21 N2 285 Against Compromise: A Mechanism Design Approach Alon Klement The Interdisciplinary Center, Herzliya Zvika Neeman Boston University and Hebrew University of Jerusalem A risk-neutral plaintiff

More information

Duke University School of Law

Duke University School of Law Duke University School of Law An Analysis of Discovery Rules Author(s): Joel Sobel Reviewed work(s): Source: Law and Contemporary Problems, Vol. 52, No. 1, Economics of Contract Law (Winter, 1989), pp.

More information

Determinants of Delay in Litigation: Theory and Evidence

Determinants of Delay in Litigation: Theory and Evidence Determinants of Delay in Litigation: Theory and Evidence Jun Zhou Legal disputes are often prolonged over time. I analyze the duration of litigation and the causes of delay using the Texas Department of

More information

Microeconomic Theory Jamison / Kohlberg / Avery Problem Set 4 Solutions Spring 2012. (a) LEFT CENTER RIGHT TOP 8, 5 0, 0 6, 3 BOTTOM 0, 0 7, 6 6, 3

Microeconomic Theory Jamison / Kohlberg / Avery Problem Set 4 Solutions Spring 2012. (a) LEFT CENTER RIGHT TOP 8, 5 0, 0 6, 3 BOTTOM 0, 0 7, 6 6, 3 Microeconomic Theory Jamison / Kohlberg / Avery Problem Set 4 Solutions Spring 2012 1. Subgame Perfect Equilibrium and Dominance (a) LEFT CENTER RIGHT TOP 8, 5 0, 0 6, 3 BOTTOM 0, 0 7, 6 6, 3 Highlighting

More information

RUHR. Commitment Problems and War in International Bargaining ECONOMIC PAPERS #403. Erwin Amann Nadine Leonhardt

RUHR. Commitment Problems and War in International Bargaining ECONOMIC PAPERS #403. Erwin Amann Nadine Leonhardt RUHR ECONOMIC PAPERS Erwin Amann Nadine Leonhardt Commitment Problems and War in International Bargaining #403 Imprint Ruhr Economic Papers Published by Ruhr-Universität Bochum (RUB), Department of Economics

More information

The Effect of Third-Party Funding of Plaintiffs on Settlement. Andrew F. Daughety and Jennifer F. Reinganum. Online Appendix

The Effect of Third-Party Funding of Plaintiffs on Settlement. Andrew F. Daughety and Jennifer F. Reinganum. Online Appendix 1 The Effect of Third-Party Funding of Plaintiffs on Settlement Andrew F. Daughety and Jennifer F. Reinganum Online Appendix See the main paper for a description of the notation, payoffs, and game form

More information

SUPERIOR COURT OF THE STATE OF WASHINGTON, KING COUNTY NOTICE OF PROPOSED CLASS ACTION SETTLEMENT

SUPERIOR COURT OF THE STATE OF WASHINGTON, KING COUNTY NOTICE OF PROPOSED CLASS ACTION SETTLEMENT SUPERIOR COURT OF THE STATE OF WASHINGTON, KING COUNTY NOTICE OF PROPOSED CLASS ACTION SETTLEMENT If you paid money to Microsoft for an MSN account established in your name at a Best Buy store, never logged

More information

Breach remedies of contract, settlement and. litigation

Breach remedies of contract, settlement and. litigation Breach remedies of contract, settlement and litigation Kotaro Uchino April, 2007 Abstract The effects of breach remedies of contract are compared under a situation with incomplete information and litigation

More information

Applying the Kelly criterion to lawsuits

Applying the Kelly criterion to lawsuits Law, Probability and Risk (2010) 9, 139 147 Advance Access publication on April 27, 2010 doi:10.1093/lpr/mgq002 Applying the Kelly criterion to lawsuits TRISTAN BARNETT Faculty of Business and Law, Victoria

More information

Asbestos. Show Me The Money MEALEY S LITIGATION REPORT. A commentary article reprinted from the December 3, 2007 issue of Mealey s Litigation Report:

Asbestos. Show Me The Money MEALEY S LITIGATION REPORT. A commentary article reprinted from the December 3, 2007 issue of Mealey s Litigation Report: MEALEY S LITIGATION REPORT Asbestos Show Me The Money By Charles E. Bates, Ph.D. and Charles H. Mullin, Ph.D. Bates White Washington, D.C. A commentary article reprinted from the December 3, 2007 issue

More information

DISTRICT OF COLUMBIA COURT OF APPEALS. No. 01-CV-810. Appeal from the Superior Court of the District of Columbia (CA-7519-00)

DISTRICT OF COLUMBIA COURT OF APPEALS. No. 01-CV-810. Appeal from the Superior Court of the District of Columbia (CA-7519-00) Notice: This opinion is subject to formal revision before publication in the Atlantic and Maryland Reporters. Users are requested to notify the Clerk of the Court of any formal errors so that corrections

More information

PERUVIAN ECONOMIC ASSOCIATION. Financially-Constrained Lawyers

PERUVIAN ECONOMIC ASSOCIATION. Financially-Constrained Lawyers PERUVIAN ECONOMIC ASSOCIATION Financially-Constrained Lawyers Claudia M. Landeo Maxim Nikitin Working Paper No. 52, October 2015 The views expressed in this working paper are those of the author(s) and

More information

The Effect of Third-Party Funding of Plaintiffs on Settlement. By Andrew F. Daughety and Jennifer F. Reinganum*

The Effect of Third-Party Funding of Plaintiffs on Settlement. By Andrew F. Daughety and Jennifer F. Reinganum* 1 The Effect of Third-Party Funding of Plaintiffs on Settlement By Andrew F. Daughety and Jennifer F. Reinganum* A significant policy concern about the emerging plaintiff legal funding industry is that

More information

SETTLEMENT NEGOTIATIONS WITH TWO-SIDED ASYMMETRIC INFORMATION: MODEL DUALITY, INFORMATION DISTRIBUTION AND EFFICIENCY*

SETTLEMENT NEGOTIATIONS WITH TWO-SIDED ASYMMETRIC INFORMATION: MODEL DUALITY, INFORMATION DISTRIBUTION AND EFFICIENCY* SETTLEMENT NEGOTIATIONS WITH TWO-SIDED ASYMMETRIC INFORMATION: MODEL DUALITY, INFORMATION DISTRIBUTION AND EFFICIENCY* Andrew F. Daughety and Jennifer F. Reinganum** Abstract We analyze a settlement and

More information

Ethical issues raised in bulk settlement agreements in mass torts

Ethical issues raised in bulk settlement agreements in mass torts Ethical issues raised in bulk settlement agreements in mass torts Judge Charles McCoy Assistant Presiding Judge Superior Court for the County of Los Angeles 111 N. Hill Street, Room 204 Los Angeles, CA

More information

The Effect of Third-Party Funding of Plaintiffs on Settlement. Andrew F. Daughety and Jennifer R. Reinganum ABSTRACT

The Effect of Third-Party Funding of Plaintiffs on Settlement. Andrew F. Daughety and Jennifer R. Reinganum ABSTRACT The Effect of Third-Party Funding of Plaintiffs on Settlement Andrew F. Daughety and Jennifer R. Reinganum ABSTRACT In this paper we use a signaling model to analyze the effect of (endogenouslydetermined)

More information

THE VALUE OF LIABILITY IN MEDICAL

THE VALUE OF LIABILITY IN MEDICAL THE VALUE OF LIABILITY IN MEDICAL MALPRACTICE by Michelle J. White Prologue: In the debate over reforming the U.S. health care system, there are relatively few areas of agreement among the various parties

More information

Each copy of any part of a JSTOR transmission must contain the same copyright notice that appears on the screen or printed page of such transmission.

Each copy of any part of a JSTOR transmission must contain the same copyright notice that appears on the screen or printed page of such transmission. Asymmetric Information and the Selection of Disputes for Litigation Author(s): Keith N. Hylton Source: The Journal of Legal Studies, Vol. 22, No. 1 (Jan., 1993), pp. 187-210 Published by: The University

More information

Do not open this exam until told to do so.

Do not open this exam until told to do so. Do not open this exam until told to do so. Department of Economics College of Social and Applied Human Sciences K. Annen, Winter 004 Final (Version ): Intermediate Microeconomics (ECON30) Solutions Final

More information

Beyond the Polyester Veil : A Personal Injury Negotiations Case Study

Beyond the Polyester Veil : A Personal Injury Negotiations Case Study Beyond the Polyester Veil : A Personal Injury Negotiations Case Study I m going to tell you something else almost as useful.i m going to tell you the big secret of handling your personal injury case. For

More information

Game Theory and Algorithms Lecture 10: Extensive Games: Critiques and Extensions

Game Theory and Algorithms Lecture 10: Extensive Games: Critiques and Extensions Game Theory and Algorithms Lecture 0: Extensive Games: Critiques and Extensions March 3, 0 Summary: We discuss a game called the centipede game, a simple extensive game where the prediction made by backwards

More information

United States General Accounting Office Testimony

United States General Accounting Office Testimony United States General Accounting Office Testimony For Release on Delivery Expected at 2:00 p.m. EST Wednesday June 22, 1988 Comparison of Amtrak Employee Injury Settlement Costs Under the Federal Employers'

More information

An Empirical Approach To Reverse Payment Settlements

An Empirical Approach To Reverse Payment Settlements Portfolio Media. Inc. 860 Broadway, 6th Floor New York, NY 10003 www.law360.com Phone: +1 646 783 7100 Fax: +1 646 783 7161 customerservice@law360.com An Empirical Approach To Reverse Payment Settlements

More information

Settlement and Trial: Selected Analyses of the Bargaining Environment

Settlement and Trial: Selected Analyses of the Bargaining Environment Settlement and Trial: Selected Analyses of the Bargaining Environment by Andrew F. Daughety and Jennifer F. Reinganum Department of Economics and Law School Vanderbilt University June 2014 Prepared for

More information

Nash Equilibria and. Related Observations in One-Stage Poker

Nash Equilibria and. Related Observations in One-Stage Poker Nash Equilibria and Related Observations in One-Stage Poker Zach Puller MMSS Thesis Advisor: Todd Sarver Northwestern University June 4, 2013 Contents 1 Abstract 2 2 Acknowledgements 3 3 Literature Review

More information

Hijacked by Ulterior Motives:

Hijacked by Ulterior Motives: Hijacked by Ulterior Motives: The Manipulation of the Mandatory Mediation Process in Ontario By: Bruce Ally B.A., M.A., PhD., OCPM., & Leah Barclay B.A. Adv. The use of mediation as a method of conflict

More information

Liability Insurance as Protection Against Legal Error. Vickie Bajtelsmit Colorado State University. and

Liability Insurance as Protection Against Legal Error. Vickie Bajtelsmit Colorado State University. and lipale.v2a 07-17-08 Liability Insurance as Protection Against Legal Error Vickie Bajtelsmit Colorado State University and Paul D. Thistle * University of Nevada Las Vegas Thistle s research was supported

More information

IMF (Australia) Ltd. Combined Financial Services Guide and Product Disclosure Statement

IMF (Australia) Ltd. Combined Financial Services Guide and Product Disclosure Statement IMF (Australia) Ltd Combined Financial Services Guide and Product Disclosure Statement Dated the 18th day of January 2010 FINANCIAL SERVICES GUIDE & PRODUCT DISCLOSURE STATEMENT PAGE 2 1. Introduction

More information

Costs Law Update Lamont v Burton

Costs Law Update Lamont v Burton - The Defendant Costs Specialists Costs Law Update Lamont v Burton The Court of Appeal s decision last week in Lamont v Burton [2007] EWCA Civ 429 is likely to have serious costs implications for defendants

More information

Chapter 17 Compromise; Settlement 2001 EDITION

Chapter 17 Compromise; Settlement 2001 EDITION Chapter 17 Compromise; Settlement 2001 EDITION 17.065 Definitions for ORS 17.065 to 17.085 17.075 When settlement prohibited between employer and employee 17.085 When settlement allowed 17.100 Assignment

More information

PRACTICAL ADVICE ON THE MOST EFFECTIVE WAY TO SETTLE YOUR CASE WITH THE GOVERNMENT

PRACTICAL ADVICE ON THE MOST EFFECTIVE WAY TO SETTLE YOUR CASE WITH THE GOVERNMENT PRACTICAL ADVICE ON THE MOST EFFECTIVE WAY TO SETTLE YOUR CASE WITH THE GOVERNMENT This article is collaboration between the panel moderator Brian J. Alexander and panel participants, Richard Saltsman,

More information

An Empirical Analysis of Insider Rates vs. Outsider Rates in Bank Lending

An Empirical Analysis of Insider Rates vs. Outsider Rates in Bank Lending An Empirical Analysis of Insider Rates vs. Outsider Rates in Bank Lending Lamont Black* Indiana University Federal Reserve Board of Governors November 2006 ABSTRACT: This paper analyzes empirically the

More information

Strategic Decisions on Lawyers' Compensation in Civil Disputes

Strategic Decisions on Lawyers' Compensation in Civil Disputes Strategic Decisions on Lawyers' Compensation in Civil Disputes a b, Kyung Hwan Baik, In-Gyu Kim a Department of Economics, Sungkyunkwan University, Seoul 110-745, Korea b Department of Economics, Hallym

More information

THE AMERICAN LAW INSTITUTE Continuing Legal Education

THE AMERICAN LAW INSTITUTE Continuing Legal Education 9 THE AMERICAN LAW INSTITUTE Continuing Legal Education Third Party Litigation Funding: Pros, Cons, and How It Works November 1, 2012 Telephone Seminar/Audio Webcast Alternative Litigation Funding Conference

More information

APIL/PIBA CFA version 9, for personal injuries and clinical negligence claims, from 1.4.13,

APIL/PIBA CFA version 9, for personal injuries and clinical negligence claims, from 1.4.13, SHORT FORM CFA for use BETWEEN SOLICITORS AND COUNSEL on or after 1 April 2013 in personal injuries and clinical negligence claims (This agreement is not suitable for claims for diffuse mesothelioma.)

More information

IN THE SUPREME COURT OF FLORIDA CASE NO. SC05-1150 COMMENTS OF DAN CYTRYN, ESQUIRE OF LAW OFFICES CYTRYN & SANTANA, P.A.

IN THE SUPREME COURT OF FLORIDA CASE NO. SC05-1150 COMMENTS OF DAN CYTRYN, ESQUIRE OF LAW OFFICES CYTRYN & SANTANA, P.A. IN THE SUPREME COURT OF FLORIDA CASE NO. SC05-1150 IN RE: PETITION TO AMEND RULE 4-1.5(F)(4)(B) OF THE RULES OF PROFESSIONAL CONDUCT / COMMENTS OF DAN CYTRYN, ESQUIRE OF LAW OFFICES CYTRYN & SANTANA, P.A.

More information

Conditional Fee Agreement: What You Need to Know

Conditional Fee Agreement: What You Need to Know Conditional Fee Agreement: What You Need to Know This document forms an important part of your agreement with us. Please read it carefully. Definitions of words used in this document and the accompanying

More information

GUIDE TO FUNDING YOUR MEDICAL NEGLIGENCE CLAIM

GUIDE TO FUNDING YOUR MEDICAL NEGLIGENCE CLAIM GUIDE TO FUNDING YOUR MEDICAL NEGLIGENCE CLAIM Because of the expert knowledge and depth of investigation required in order to bring a successful claim, negligence litigation can be expensive. Understandably,

More information

Advice Note. An overview of civil proceedings in England. Introduction

Advice Note. An overview of civil proceedings in England. Introduction Advice Note An overview of civil proceedings in England Introduction There is no civil code in England; English civil law comprises of essentially legislation by Parliament and decisions by the courts.

More information

2. Information Economics

2. Information Economics 2. Information Economics In General Equilibrium Theory all agents had full information regarding any variable of interest (prices, commodities, state of nature, cost function, preferences, etc.) In many

More information

NFL, RETIRED PLAYERS RESOLVE CONCUSSION LITIGATION; COURT-APPOINTED MEDIATOR HAILS HISTORIC AGREEMENT. Thousands of Retirees and Families to Benefit

NFL, RETIRED PLAYERS RESOLVE CONCUSSION LITIGATION; COURT-APPOINTED MEDIATOR HAILS HISTORIC AGREEMENT. Thousands of Retirees and Families to Benefit ALTERNATIVE DISPUTE RESOLUTION CENTER 840 Newport Center Drive Suite 450 Newport Beach, CA 92660-6324 Telephone: (949) 760-5288 Fax: (949) 760-5289 NFL, RETIRED PLAYERS RESOLVE CONCUSSION LITIGATION; COURT-APPOINTED

More information

Strengthening International Courts and the Early Settlement of Disputes

Strengthening International Courts and the Early Settlement of Disputes Strengthening International Courts and the Early Settlement of Disputes Michael Gilligan, Leslie Johns, and B. Peter Rosendorff November 18, 2008 Technical Appendix Definitions σ(ŝ) {π [0, 1] s(π) = ŝ}

More information

Market mechanisms in dispute resolution: the position of legal expenses insurance

Market mechanisms in dispute resolution: the position of legal expenses insurance Prof. Dr. Heico Kerkmeester Market mechanisms in dispute resolution: the position of legal expenses insurance In this paper, I take a law and economics -approach to legal expenses insurance. This approach

More information

Retainer Agreement and Information Personal Injury Contingent Fee

Retainer Agreement and Information Personal Injury Contingent Fee Retainer Agreement and Information Personal Injury Contingent Fee This document is a supplement to practicepro's managing the finances of your practice booklet. It reviews the steps you can take to better

More information

CRIMINAL DEFENSE AGREEMENTS

CRIMINAL DEFENSE AGREEMENTS 5/6/13 CRIMINAL DEFENSE & CIVIL LITIGATION AGREEMENTS LLOYD M. CUETO LAW OFFICE OF LLOYD M. CUETO P.C. 7110 WEST MAIN STREET BELLEVILLE, ILLINOIS 62223 (618) 277-1554 CRIMINAL DEFENSE AGREEMENTS HOW TO

More information

Plain Language Summary of the proposed Settlement Agreement between Listuguj and Canada

Plain Language Summary of the proposed Settlement Agreement between Listuguj and Canada Plain Language Summary of the proposed Settlement Agreement between Listuguj and Canada October 28, 2014 Plain Language Summary of the proposed Settlement Agreement Between Listuguj and Canada This is

More information