Capital versus Performance Covenants in Debt Contracts

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Capital versus Performance Covenants in Debt Contracts"

Transcription

1 Capital versus Performance Covenants in Debt Contracts Hans B. Christensen and Valeri V. Nikolaev The University of Chicago Booth School of Business 5807 South Woodlawn Avenue Chicago, IL Abstract: We study the contracting role of financial covenants classified into two types. We argue that capital covenants control agency problems by maintaining sufficient equity capital and hence aligning debtholder-shareholder incentives, whereas performance covenants serve as tripwires that facilitate early transfers of control and renegotiations when performance deteriorates. We find that capital and performance covenants are negatively correlated but are not used interchangeably. Performance covenants are strong predictors of future contract renegotiations, while this is not the case for capital covenants. Further, restrictions on certain managerial actions are less common in conjunction with capital covenants, in line with their incentives alignment effect. We also study how the contracting value of accounting information affects covenant package design. We predict and find that performance covenants are contracted on when accounting information is descriptive of credit quality, while the opposite holds for capital covenants. This relation implies that properties of accounting information have a sizable effect on the design of financial contracts. Keywords: accounting-based covenants, private debt, capital structure JEL Classification: M40 First version: January 2010 This version: October 2010 We thank Ray Ball, Phil Berger, Richard Frankel, Laurence van Lent, Douglas Skinner, and workshop participants at the University of Chicago, London Business School, Tilburg University, Washington University, and the Fourth Interdisciplinary Accounting Conference in Copenhagen for helpful comments. Financial support from the University of Chicago Booth School of Business is gratefully acknowledged.

2 1. Introduction Covenants, which are designed to reduce the agency costs associated with conflicts of interest between creditors and shareholders, are a key component of debt contracts. The classic view on covenants expressed in Jensen and Meckling (1976) and Smith and Warner (1979) suggests that covenants control the agency costs of debt by giving shareholders incentives to follow a firm value-maximizing policy via restrictions on managerial behavior. More recent theoretical literature views covenants as tripwires that give lenders an option to renegotiate loan terms by threatening default following a decline in economic performance (Berlin and Mester 1992; Rajan and Winton 1995; Gorton and Kahn 2000; Garleanu and Zwiebel 2009). The theoretical papers on covenants typically employ a generic definition of the information signal in terms of which covenants are formulated, and hence largely disregard the fact that, in practice, covenants are formulated in terms of a variety of accounting ratios (Leftwich 1983; Dichev and Skinner 2002). This raises a number of interesting questions about the contracting role of accounting-based covenants. First, are there important distinctions in the monitoring role of different accounting ratios? Second, do covenants that rely on different accounting ratios reduce contracting frictions through different mechanisms? Third, what are the relations among different accounting-based covenants and financial policy choices or non-accounting contract features? And finally, how does the contractibility of accounting information influence covenant package design? In this paper we attempt to shed light on these questions by studying the intensity of accounting-based covenants (so-called financial or maintenance covenants) used in private 1

3 lending agreements. 1 To characterize the covenants package, we propose a simple classification of these covenants into two broad categories. The first category comprises capital covenants, which rely on information about sources and uses of capital and therefore balance sheet information only. Capital covenants typically control the level of equity or debt in the capital structure directly. The second category consists of performance covenants, which are formulated in terms of current-period efficiency indicators. 2 These covenants rely on income statement (cash flow statement) information alone or combine it with a balance sheet amount (e.g., debt-tocash flow). We argue that the two types of covenants limit debt-related agency problems in different ways. Capital covenants essentially ensure that shareholders have enough money inside the company. Such restrictions are an effective way to control the agency costs of debt (Smith and Warner 1979), as they ensure that shareholder wealth is (sufficiently) sensitive to managerial actions to incentivize shareholders to monitor management. Thus, capital covenants align shareholders' incentives with those of lenders ex ante, in which case there is less need for debtholder interference with managerial actions ex post. In line with this argument, capital covenants are not breached as long as management raises additional equity or cuts back on dividends, which provides incentives to finance investments with equity rather than debt. A cost of using these covenants, however, is that to be effective they have to place stringent constraints 1 Maintenance covenants require borrowers to maintain certain levels of financial ratios at every compliance date. These covenants are different from so-called negative covenants that restrict managerial actions depending on the level of accounting ratios. Such covenants are extensively considered by Smith and Warner (1979). 2 A concurrent working paper by Demerjian (2010) studies how accounting regulation has influenced the use of covenants. The paper refers to capital covenants as "balance sheet covenants" and to performance covenants as "income statement covenants". While such classification also seems appropriate, we do not use these labels for two reasons. First, the classification of some covenants (e.g., debt-to-cash flow or debt-to-ebitda) into balance sheet, income statement, or cash flow statement groups is arbitrary. Second, the labels "capital" and "performance" are more descriptive of the economic nature of these covenants and the underlying mechanism through which they address agency problems (as discussed further in the paper). 2

4 on the amount of debt in the capital structure. In contrast, we hypothesize that performance covenants are used as tripwires that detect early signals of distress and hence provide lenders an early option to renegotiate the contract or restrict managerial actions after deterioration in credit quality, i.e., ex post (Berlin and Mester 1992; Dichev and Skinner 2002; Garleanu and Zwiebel 2009). Performance covenants generally detect deteriorations in credit quality sooner than capital covenants because they are based on current performance (efficiency) ratios rather than on the stock of past profits and net capital contributions. While this is another effective way to control contracting frictions, compared to capital covenants' ex ante alignment of interests, it requires lenders to monitor the borrower more closely. To examine the differences in the role of the two covenant types, we develop two sets of empirical predictions that we test using data from Dealscan. Our first set of predictions seeks to improve our understanding of the contracting role of the two types of covenants. First, based on our characterization of the two covenant types, we predict that the two types of covenants are not used interchangeably as substitutes. In line with this prediction, we find that performance covenants' and capital covenants' intensities have different determinants and exhibit associations of opposite signs with many firm and contract characteristics. For example, consistent with the idea that capital covenants limit the use of debt, we find that they exhibit a strong negative association with the level of long-term debt, whereas consistent with tripwire covenants improving banks' incentives to monitor the loan (Rajan and Winton 1995), performance covenants are positively correlated with long-term debt. Second, since performance covenants are used as tripwires, we predict that they are positively related to the frequency of contract renegotiations, as a result of which covenants are 3

5 waived or reset conditional on firms' future performance. In contrast, capital covenants are expected to reduce the need to renegotiate because of debtholder-shareholder incentive alignment effects. We find that, in line with our prediction, performance (capital) covenants exhibit a significantly positive (negative) correlation with renegotiations and the number of covenant amendments. These results extend to a multivariate setting where we find that performance covenants, but not capital covenants, are significant predictors of subsequent renegotiations. Third, we predict that negative covenants such as restrictions on dividends, capital expenditures, and "cash sweeps" are used in conjunction with performance but not capital covenants. This is because when incentives are aligned through capital covenants, demand for negative covenants should be lower. In contrast, performance covenants may occasionally fail to transfer control in a timely fashion and hence negative covenants are needed to prevent shareholders from expropriating wealth from lenders. Our results provide strong empirical support for this prediction. Our second set of predictions seeks to shed light on how the contracting value of accounting information influences covenant package design. We argue that tripwire covenants are only effective at reducing contracting frictions if they transfer control to lenders when credit quality deteriorates (otherwise their use is costly). Thus, our fourth prediction is that performance covenants are used when accounting information is descriptive of credit risk. In contrast, capital covenants are likely to be a more effective mechanism to limit debt-related agency problems when accounting information is a poor indicator of credit quality, for two reasons. First, capital covenants align the incentives of shareholders and lenders ex ante and therefore do not rely on frequent control transfers and renegotiations. Second, aggregation of 4

6 profits over time, as it occurs in the balance sheet, reduces accounting noise. Using four proxies to measure accounting information's inherent contracting value (similar to Ball et al. 2008), we find that the use of performance (capital) covenants is increasing (decreasing) in the debt contracting value of accounting information, and that the fraction of performance covenants is also positively associated with our contracting value proxies. These results continue to hold when we use timely loss recognition and earnings persistence as alternative contracting value proxies and when we control for the investment opportunity set (Skinner 1993) and other covenant determinants. Taken together, the evidence suggests that performance covenants are chosen over capital covenants when accounting information is a good indicator of credit quality, in line with our predictions. Our fifth and final prediction is an extension of the arguments in Ball et al. (2008). Ball et al. find that credit rating-based pricing grids substitute for accounting-based pricing grids when accounting is uninformative about credit risk. Since the purpose of credit ratings and performance measures is to detect changes in credit quality, in contrast to capital-based measures, we argue that the effect documented in Ball et al. is largely due to substitution between credit ratings and the indicators used by performance covenants but not capital covenants. Our evidence supports this argument. Our study contributes to three threads of the literature. First, we contribute to the literature on creditor control rights and debt contract design (e.g., Dichev and Skinner 2002; Nash et al. 2003; Nini et al. 2007; Chava and Roberts 2008). Smith and Warner (1979) highlight the need to study interrelations between covenants. We propose a simple distinction between two types of financial covenants that is conceptually appealing and turns out to be empirically powerful. In particular, our results support the argument that performance and capital covenants 5

7 are not substitutes, that is, they reduce contracting frictions through different mechanisms. We thus find that the covenant mix varies meaningfully with different firm characteristics as well as contract characteristics such as leverage and negative covenants. Second, we contribute to the literature on the renegotiation of financial contracts (Roberts and Sufi 2009). Our evidence indicates that contracts with performance covenants are more frequently renegotiated than contracts without performance covenants. This is not the case for capital covenants, however, in line with capital covenants reducing the need for future renegotiations ex ante. Third, we contribute to the literature on how accounting information affects the design of debt contracts (Frankel and Litov 2007; Ball et al. 2008; Bharath et al. 2008; Nikolaev 2010; Costello and Wittenberg-Moerman 2010; Demerjian 2007 and 2010). Specifically, we show that performance covenants are preferred to capital covenants when accounting information provides a good description of credit quality. The remainder of our paper is organized as follows: Section 2 develops our hypotheses; Section 3 discusses our measure of the contracting value of accounting information; Section 4 outlines the sample selection and provides descriptive statistics; Section 5 presents the results; and Section 6 concludes. 2. Background and hypotheses Accounting-based covenants limit contracting inefficiencies. There are many channels through which covenants operate. Covenants can reduce agency problems by restricting managerial actions that potentially hurt debtholders as a company approaches financial distress (Jensen and Meckling 1976; Smith and Warner 1979). Alternatively, covenants can serve as a screening device that helps lenders obtain information about the borrower (Garleanu and Zwiebel 2009). Covenants can further alleviate hold up problems associated with short-term debt 6

8 (Sharpe 1990; Rajan 1992), improve lenders' incentives to monitor the loan (Rajan and Winton 1995), and provide a valuable option to renegotiate a contract following an adverse event (Berlin and Mester 1992). However, there is a disconnect between theory and practice as the theory is silent with respect to the roles of the different accounting ratios on which covenants are formulated. In this paper we classify covenants into two types to provide early evidence on the contracting role of the two types of accounting indicators used in practice. Before developing our hypotheses in turn below, we begin with a discussion of the classification that we propose Capital versus performance covenants To shed light on the role of accounting-based covenants, we classify covenants into two types: capital covenants and performance covenants. Capital covenants are formulated in terms of accounting information about sources and uses of capital, that is, balance sheet information only. Examples include restrictions on leverage, debt-to-equity, loan-to-value, debt-to-tangible net worth, and current ratios. In contrast, performance covenants consists of those covenants formulated in terms of current-period performance or efficiency ratios. Such covenants include interest coverage, fixed charge coverage, debt-to-earnings, and debt-to-cash flow ratios, as well as earnings (EBITDA) itself (see Appendix A for a complete classification of covenants). A notable distinction between the two types of covenants relates to the fact that capital covenants typically place explicit restrictions on a firm's minimum equity or maximum debt level, for instance, by requiring that the firm maintain certain leverage or net worth thresholds. Shareholders can ensure that such thresholds are respected by contributing additional equity capital or cutting back on dividend payments. Thus, capital covenants are not breached as long as shareholders are willing to participate in the firm's investments with their own capital. In contrast, performance covenants place no direct restrictions on the amount of a firm's debt; 7

9 instead they require that a minimum performance (profitability) level be maintained. Under performance covenants a company can keep increasing the level of debt in its capital structure as long as its new investments are sufficiently profitable. 3 However, a breach of performance covenants can rarely be avoided simply by contributing equity or cutting dividends. Another distinction between the two covenant types relates to the timeliness of control transfers. Capital covenants are based on a firm's cumulative profitability plus shareholders' net capital contributions, that is, they measure equity holders' capital in the firm including the stock of past undistributed profits. Performance covenants, in contrast, are functions of current-period performance only and thus are informative about changes in the stock of equity capital (profits) net of dividends. To become binding, capital covenants may require a series of losses, while it simply takes a lower level of current-period performance (which need not be a loss) for performance covenants to bind. Thus, performance covenants are usually timelier and more forward-looking indicators of negative trends in credit quality. Further, capital covenants rely on cumulated and aggregated accounting information from the balance sheet. Although this is likely to reduce noise over longer time periods, this comes at the expense of timeliness as current-period performance receives relatively small weight over longer periods. We note that it is rather difficult to draw a sharp line between performance and capital covenants because a firm's level of capital and performance are correlated. For example, if a company underperforms over an extended period its capital will be depleted and control reallocation will take place with capital covenants unless shareholders contribute new equity capital. However, this correlation is expected to prevail only over rather long measurement 3 Capitalizing future profits is generally not allowed under GAAP and thus financing a profitable new project with debt alone will be difficult in the presence of capital structure covenants. 8

10 horizons. Contracting parties should therefore find the distinction between the two types of covenants relevant Role of capital and performance covenants in limiting contracting frictions The distinctions we outlined above imply that the two types of covenants limit contracting frictions in different ways. Capital covenants require that shareholders maintain enough net assets in the firm (i.e., have enough "money" inside the firm). This ensures that shareholders' wealth is sensitive to opportunistic actions that decrease firm value (i.e., an equity option on the firm's assets is in the money), which in turn reduces shareholders' incentives to expropriate debtholder value and encourages them to monitor management (i.e., aligns the interests of shareholders and lenders). In contrast, instead of directly influencing the level of shareholders' equity and hence aligning incentives, performance covenants lead to more active monitoring by lenders by identifying deteriorations in a firm's performance and facilitating renegotiation. Performance covenants therefore reduce agency problems by reallocating control when debtholder-shareholder conflicts of interest become more severe. Smith and Warner (1979) argue that one of the most effective ways to control debtholdershareholder agency conflicts is to limit the amount of debt in the capital structure to a relatively low level. These authors distinguish four types of agency conflicts between shareholders (and managers' actions on their behalf) and debtholders, namely, (1) conflicts over dividends, (2) claim dilution, (3) asset substitution (Jensen and Meckling 1976), and (4) underinvestment (Myers 1977). To see how capital covenants can reduce agency conflicts, consider each of these problems in turn. First, by imposing a minimum equity constraint, capital covenants directly limit excessive dividend payouts and claim dilution. Next, because asset substitution arises due to shareholders' limited downside risk, which provides shareholders (and ultimately managers) 9

11 with risk-taking incentives, capital covenants' minimum equity constraint increases shareholders' downside sensitivity and hence helps mitigate asset substitution. Finally, because the underinvestment problem arises when the return on new investments effectively accrues to debtholders rather than shareholders, that is, when equity capital is thin and shareholders hold an out-of-the-money option on the firm's assets, capital covenants' equity requirements help preventing the underinvestment problem as well. Performance covenants can also address the four agency problems above by acting as tripwires that preempt managerial actions by reallocating control to debtholders at risk of expropriation. Control transfers allow debtholders to discipline managerial actions such as dividend payouts, capital expenditures, asset sales, and changes in the debt level (Roberts and Sufi 2009). We argue that capital structure covenants are less able to serve as tripwires as they do not focus on current performance, are less timely, and are easier to avoid. Thus, whereas capital covenants provide ex ante incentives against opportunistic actions, performance covenants limit agency conflicts by transferring control after operating performance deterioration. Based on the above discussion we expect that the two types of covenants are used by companies with different characteristics, such as for example, different investment opportunity sets (Skinner 1993). This implies that the two types of covenants are not direct substitutes. More formally: H1: Capital and performance covenants are used by borrowers with different investment opportunity sets, i.e., they are not substitutes. We state our first hypothesis in general form and discuss specific associations with firm characteristics in the results section. Our alternative hypothesis is that the two types of covenants are substitutes and hence exhibit similar relations with firm characteristics. 10

12 2.3. The use of negative covenants In addition to financial covenants, credit agreements often contain negative covenants, such as dividend restrictions, capital expenditure restrictions, and cash sweeps (which require remittance of a portion of cash proceeds from asset sales, new debt or equity issuance, etc. to the lender and hence effectively restrict these actions). Negative covenants are an alternative mechanism to control excessive dividend payouts, asset substitution, and claim dilution. We expect demand for negative covenants to be lower when managerial incentives are aligned with those of debtholders via capital covenants. In contrast, negative covenants are vital when performance covenants fail to transfer control in a timely manner and hence the risk of expropriation increases. This leads to the following hypothesis: H2: Dividend restrictions, capital expenditure restrictions, and cash sweeps are used in conjunction with performance covenants but not with capital covenants Frequency of renegotiation Lender monitoring via tripwire covenants is closely related to contract renegotiations. When economic performance deteriorates, tripwire covenants give lenders an option to renegotiate the terms of the loan. Garleanu and Zwiebel (2009), for example, show that under asymmetric information it is optimal to give stronger decision rights to lenders via covenants, which increase the frequency of subsequent renegotiation. We posit that because performance covenants serve as tripwires, the intensity of performance covenants is significantly related to the frequency of contract amendments that lead to covenant modifications. In contrast, because capital covenants are less suitable for active lender monitoring, we do not expect a positive association between capital covenants and contract amendments. Indeed, in the absence of conditioning on performance covenants, capital covenants are likely to reduce the frequency of renegotiation as they align managerial incentives ex ante. Our third hypothesis is thus as 11

13 follows: H3: Performance covenants are positively related to the frequency of contract amendments, whereas capital covenants do not show a positive relation with contract amendment frequency Accounting-based covenants and the contracting value of accounting information A key role of accounting information in the debt markets is to provide contractible information. Properties of accounting information are likely to be important in determining debt contract design and more specifically the use of accounting-based covenants (Skinner 1993; Frankel and Litov 2007; Bharath et al. 2008; Nikolaev 2010). We argue that performance covenants require accounting information to be a good indicator of credit quality. First, if accounting is not descriptive of credit risk, performance covenants will not effectively control agency problems as they will not transfer control in a timely manner (Type I error). Second, performance covenants will be costly if they transfer control and require renegotiation at times when doing so is unjustified (Beneish and Press 1993) (Type II error). Finally, if accounting information does not easily map into credit scores, monitoring of covenants written in terms of such information (which entails verifying quarterly compliance certificates, understanding covenant violations, and possibly renegotiation) will be relatively costly. In contrast, capital covenants do not require that accounting information explain credit quality. First, capital covenants reduce agency conflicts not by reallocation of control but rather by aligning shareholders' and debtholders' interests and giving shareholders incentives to control managerial actions. Second, accounting noise present in performance measures (e.g., earnings) reverse and wash out over time, and therefore have only a minor effect on capital covenants that rely on cumulative numbers from the balance sheet. However, the use of capital covenants entails a significant cost as they directly limit the use of debt as a mechanism to align incentives. 12

14 These arguments imply that there exists a tradeoff between capital and performance covenants that is affected by the contracting value of accounting information: when accounting information's ability to explain credit quality increases, performance (capital) covenants become a more (less) appealing contracting mechanism. 4 More formally: H4: The reliance on performance (capital) covenants is positively (negatively) associated with the ability of accounting information to explain credit risk Pricing grids and accounting information Loans frequently rely on pricing grids that make interest payments contingent on accounting indicators or credit ratings (Asquith et al. 2005). Pricing grids based on accounting information can be classified into (1) capital-based pricing grids, which rely on accounting indicators used by capital covenants, and (2) profitability-based grids, which rely on accounting indicators used by performance covenants. 5 Ball et al. (2008) predict and find that rating-based pricing grids substitute for accounting-based grids when the contracting value of accounting information is low. Extending their argument, we argue that rating-based grids substitute only for profitability-based grids and not capital-based grids. To see this, note that ratings are likely used for the same purpose as performance measures: to detect changes in credit quality. Capitalbased pricing grids, on the other hand, are less affected by the contracting value of accounting information since they provide incentives to maintain a sufficient equity cushion rather than detect changes in credit quality. Substitution of profitability-based grids for rating-based grids is 4 Note that this is different from predicting that performance (capital) covenants are used when performance (capital) measures are more informative about credit quality. It is likely that informative performance measures will lead to informative capital ratios and vice versa. Thus, we expect and find that these are highly positively correlated. As a result, it is difficult to separate informativeness effects empirically. 5 Capital indicators include senior leverage and the ratio of debt to tangible net worth; profitability (performance) indicators include the debt service coverage ratio, fixed charge coverage, interest coverage, senior debt to cash flow (EBITDA), and total debt to cash flow (EBITDA); rating measures include commercial paper rating, subordinated debt rating, and senior debt rating. 13

15 expected in cases where accounting information is a poor indicator of credit risk. As a result, we predict that the use of profitability-based pricing grids, but not capital-based pricing grids, is increasing in the contracting value of accounting information. This leads to our fifth hypothesis: H5: Pricing grids are formulated in terms of performance indicators rather than capital indicators when accounting information is more descriptive of credit risk. 3. Measuring the contracting value of accounting information Accounting information explains credit risk to the extent that it maps into credit scores. To quantify the ability of accounting information to measure default risk we construct four proxies for contracting value. Following Ball et al. (2008), our contracting value proxies are based on industry-level regressions of long-term debt ratings (transformed into numerical scores) on accounting variables. As credit ratings summarize credit risk, R 2 s from these regressions capture the relative ability of accounting information to explain default risk. A low explanatory power would imply the presence of a large information component for the industry that is not easily captured by accounting information (but that is taken into account when determining credit risk). In this case the amount of contractible accounting information available to capture credit risk is limited. In contrast, a high R 2 would imply that accounting benchmarks are sufficient statistics for determining credit scores within a particular industry. We estimate the regressions at the industry level over the period , similar to Ball et al. (2008). Our approach differs from that in Ball et al. (2008) who measure the contracting value by looking at whether changes in accounting earnings explain credit rating downgrades. We do not follow their procedure as our objective is different. The first reason for using levels rather than changes in earnings is that we are interested in using variables actually used in contracts. Contracts are written in terms of performance or capital indicator levels and thus it is interesting 14

16 to focus on these variables. Moreover, performance indicators already effectively inform us about the changes in shareholder's capital (wealth) and thus differencing capital indicators brings us to performance measures. Specifically, differencing net worth yields current period earnings net of dividends. If the purpose of the analysis is to compare net worth vs. earnings as two contracting alternatives, differencing is misleading. Second, we are not interested in whether changes in accounting variables predict credit rating downgrades per se. 6 Instead, we are interested in determining whether accounting information maps into a credit score, or whether a large amount of other information (captured in residuals) explains credit ratings. Because levels of earnings and capital are likely to be important in determining credit risk, calculating changes would difference out this essential information component. 7 Further, the lack of a credit rating downgrade need not necessarily imply that accounting information is uninformative about credit quality; rather, it may simply suggest relatively stable performance. 8 As a result, it is difficult to evaluate whether accounting information explains (as a sufficient statistic) credit risk by focusing on credit rating downgrades. 9 6 Note that credit rating downgrades following changes in profitability are endogenously related to the use of covenants, as contracts that rely on tight tripwire covenants have a higher probability of a downgrade following a change, which complicates inferences. In contrast, examining the extent to which earnings map into credit risk scores is a non-causal approach that is less subject to this concern. Note that the mapping of earnings into credit scores is unlikely to depend on whether covenants are used or not. 7 While a specification in changes allows one to get closer to a causal relation between accounting variables and credit rating, we are not interested in causal relations per se, but rather the strength of association. 8 Econometrics of panel data suggests that taking differences is likely to exacerbate econometric problems caused by measurement error when there is a lack of within-subject (company) variation in the variables of interest (i.e., subjects are correlated over time) (Hsiao 2003, Section 10.5). 9 As a technical complication, our data do not allow us to construct a quality measure of credit rating downgrades. For example, suppose we observe a credit rating on February 1, 2000, and on April 1, 2002 we observe a lower rating. This could mean that the company was downgraded right before April 1, 2002, or alternatively it could mean that there was an interruption in coverage. 15

17 Note that private loan covenants are usually not written in terms of credit ratings, and hence they are suitable as benchmarks for measuring the contracting value of accounting information (as this avoid selection issues). While it is beyond the scope of this paper to establish why covenants are not written in terms of credit ratings, several explanations are possible. First, the introduction of conflicts of interest between rating agencies (compensated by the borrower) and debtholders can discourage contracting on ratings. Second, circularity would arise because ratings are determined in part by firms' access to bank financing (Standard&Poor's 2010) and therefore lenders' decisions. For example, S&P could downgrade a company's debt in response to lenders' intention to recall the loan, in which case contracting on ratings makes default a self-fulfilling prophesy, similar to covenants written on credit spreads. It is worth pointing out that whereas the circularity above reduces the usefulness of ratings in contracts, to our knowledge it should not bias the contracting value proxies used in this study. As a robustness check, in Section 5.6 we use credit default spreads instead of credit ratings. We now turn to the construction of our contracting value proxies. 10 Our first proxy for the debt contracting value of accounting information, CV1, is the R 2 from the following industrylevel regression: Rating E E E E E (1) it 0 1 it 2 it 1 3 it 2 4 it 3 5 it 4 it where Rating it is constructed by assigning 1 to companies with the highest credit rating following quarter t, 2 to companies with the second-highest credit rating, and so on, and then taking the natural logarithm. Eit s is earnings before extraordinary items in quarter t s divided by average total assets over the quarter. 10 We use quarterly data as private credit agreements' compliance with accounting-based covenants is often determined on a quarterly basis. 16

18 Our second contracting value proxy, CV2, is the R 2 from the industry-level regression: Rating Coverage Coverage Coverage it 0 1 it 2 it 1 3 it 2 Coverage Coverage 4 it 3 5 it 4 it (2) where Rating is defined as above and divided by total interest expense). Coverageit s is quarter t s interest coverage (EBITDA Notice that both CV1 and CV2 are formulated in terms of performance indicators that lenders are interested in. One may also measure the extent to which accounting information maps into credit quality based only on balance sheet variables, i.e., capital indicators. Doing so allows us to contrast capital ratios with performance indicators. Our proxy based only on capital indicators, CV3, is the R 2 from the following regression: Rating NetWorth Leverage Tangibility (3) it 0 1 it 2 it 3 it it where Rating is as defined above, by total assets, NetWorthit is the quarter t ratio of book value of equity divided Leverage it is long-term debt divided by total assets in period t, and Tangibility it is capital intensity defined as book value of net property, plant, and equipment divided by total assets. 11 Finally, our all-in contracting value proxy, CV4, is based on the R 2 from the following industry-level regression (here we do not include lags to keep the model parsimonious): Rating E Coverage NetWorth Leverage Tangibility (4) it 0 1 it 2 it 3 it 4 it 5 it it where all variables are as defined previously. Appendix B provides pooled sample estimates for Models (1) through (4) Alternative proxies for contracting value 11 While Tangibility is rarely used in credit agreements, it clearly represents a measure of assets-in-place, which is important in lending decisions (Skinner 1993). 17

19 While there is no consensus in the accounting literature on how to measure accounting quality (Dechow et al. 2009), we use two simple properties of accounting information that likely affect contracting parties' decision on covenants: timely loss recognition and earnings predictability. Apart from being interesting in their own right, timely loss recognition and earnings persistence also help us validate our contracting value proxies described above. 12 Timely loss recognition, or conditional conservatism, plays an important role in debt markets (Watts 2003). In particular, timely loss recognition improves the effectiveness of accounting-based covenants by facilitating transfers of control to debtholders when a company approaches financial distress (Ball and Shivakumar 2005). Thus, timely loss recognition is important for tripwire-type covenants. We measure timely loss recognition, TLR, as the coefficient 3 from the following industry-level regression based on Basu (1997): Et / P t 1 0 1D( R t 0) 2R t 3D( R t 0) R t (5) t where Et / Pt 1 is defined as the ratio of annual earnings before extraordinary items scaled by beginning-of-period market value of common stock, R t is the stock return from CRSP compounded over the 12-month period starting three months after the beginning of the fiscal year (to exclude prior earnings announcement effects), and D(.) is an indicator function. Earnings predictability is also often argued to be an important consideration for lenders and thus is likely to influence the covenants decision. We measure predictability, PRED, as the R 2 from the following industry-level regression (e.g., Dichev and Tang 2009): E E (6) it 0 1 it 1 it 12 Ball et al. (2008) also use timeliness, the R 2 from regressing stock returns on accounting earnings and their changes. They find, however, that timeliness exhibits a negative correlation with timely loss recognition. This is not unexpected given the construction of these two proxies. As a result, and given that the contracting benefit of a higher return-earnings association is unclear, we do not include this measure in our analysis. 18

20 where Et is annual earnings divided by average total assets. Regressions (5) and (6) are estimated by industry over the period Sample and summary statistics 4.1. Sample selection We use Dealscan to measure reliance on accounting-based covenants and other loan characteristics. Accounting variables and firm characteristics are collected from Compustat. We merge loans from Dealscan to the fiscal years in which they are issued on Compustat using the Dealscan-Compustat link (August 2010 vintage) constructed and maintained by Michael Roberts and WRDS (see Chava and Roberts 2008). 13 If a loan package has several credit facilities, we aggregate information at the deal (i.e., loan) level. Contracts without covenant information are excluded from the analysis. 14 We capture a contract's reliance on covenants by using covenant intensity, which is the number of covenants in the contract. C-Covenants denotes a count of capital covenants, and P-Covenants denotes a count of performance covenants. The classification of accounting-based covenants into performance covenants (P-Covenants) and capital covenants (C-Covenants) is described in Appendix A. To construct our contracting value proxies we link the S&P Credit Ratings Database to the Compustat quarterly database and use S&P's entity-level long-term credit ratings. Each endof-quarter credit rating is linked to accounting information from the current and preceding quarters. If S&P did not update a firm's credit rating during a particular quarter, we use the most 13 We thank the authors for generously sharing the link information. 14 Approximately 50% of credit agreements in Dealscan are coded as having no covenants. It is highly unlikely that these credit agreements do not employ covenants given that almost all private credit agreements rely on covenants (e.g., Christensen and Nikolaev 2009). The absence of covenant data indicates simply that Dealscan was unable to obtain information on covenants. Thus, we exclude contracts with no covenant information rather than set this number to zero. 19

21 recent long-term credit rating. S&P Credit Ratings data dates back to the 1920s, but coverage is sparse before As we further require cash flow statement data, we limit the sample to the period Over this period S&P rated over 5,500 companies and on average released credit rating (or economic outlook) information 1,900 times per year (this number ranges from about 500 in 1988 to 3,300 in 2008). In general it takes more than a year for S&P to update information about a given company's long-term credit. Contracting value is measured based on SIC industry classification: 3-digit SIC codes are used in cases where more than 25 companies and 250 quarterly observations are available; 3- digit SIC codes that do not meet this requirement are combined and considered at their 2-digit level (all industries are mutually exclusive). This procedure achieves a more balanced distribution of companies across resulting industry groups. We further exclude industry groups with less than 25 companies or 250 quarterly observations to improve the reliability of estimates and avoid overfitting that occurs in small samples. This procedure results in 50 industry groups. We employ the same industry classification procedure when measuring timely loss recognition and earnings predictability. 15 These properties are estimated using the intersection of CRSP and annual Compustat data. We omit 1% of the observations for CRSP and Compustat variables at each tail and restrict the sample to non-negative EBITDA (which is necessary to compute interest coverage). 16 All variables are defined in Appendix C. The final sample size varies from approximately 6,000 to over 10,000 debt contracts depending on data availability for the specific regression Summary statistics 15 The resulting set of industries is larger as we do not require S&P data to be present. 16 The results are not sensitive to this choice. 20

22 Table 1 presents summary statistics. With a mean (median) market value of assets at $4,553 ($975) million, the average firm in our sample is larger than the average firm on Compustat. Average book-to-market is 0.63, which is similar to the Compustat average. Leverage, as measured by long-term debt divided by book value of assets, is 27%, which is substantially higher than the 17% that corresponds to the population of Compustat firms. The mean contracting value proxies range from 15% in the case of CV1 to 44% in the case of CV4, which implies that a substantial portion of the variation in credit ratings is explained by variation in accounting variables. Half of the sample companies have at least one C-Covenant and two P- Covenants. Table 2, Panel A reports correlations among the contracting value proxies. All CV proxies exhibit high positive correlations with each other. This result is interesting as it shows empirically that profitability indicators' ability to explain credit risk is closely correlated with the ability of balance sheet capital ratios to do so. It is therefore unlikely that the choice of covenants is explained by trading off how well balance sheet vs. income statement variables map into credit risk. In addition, the CV proxies exhibit significant positive correlations with the timely loss recognition (TLR) and predictability (PRED) proxies. For example, the correlation between TLR (PRED) and CV4 is 31% (50%). This result helps validate our contracting value proxies. Table 2, Panel B provides pairwise correlations among covenants based on a more refined classification of the financial covenants into five main groups (detailed in the table header). The five main groups are given by indicator variables for covenants on debt-toprofitability, interest coverage, liquidity (current ratio), leverage, and net worth. Note that interest coverage and debt-to-profitability covenants belong to P-Covenants while liquidity, 21

23 leverage, and net worth covenants belong to C-Covenants. As expected, performance and capital covenants exhibit positive correlations with other members of their group. However, they exhibit significant negative correlations with members of the other group, which is consistent with covenants across these groups being substitutes. Overall, P-Covenants and C-Covenants exhibit a significantly negative correlation of Panel C of Table 2 shows the correlations between financial covenants' intensity and the presence of negative covenants (dividend and capital expenditure restrictions, as well as cash sweeps). We observe significantly positive (negative) correlations between negative covenants and performance (capital) covenants, consistent with H2. Table 3 provides Pearson correlations among firm- and contract-level variables. P- Covenants and C-Covenants exhibit correlations of opposite signs with leverage (0.26 and -0.16, respectively). This evidence is consistent with the idea that capital covenants mitigate agency conflicts by limiting access to debt financing. The covenants mix, P/C CovMix = C- Covenants/(C-Covenants+P-Covenants), also exhibits significant correlations with a number of firm characteristics, including size, leverage, and book-to-market. 5. Results 5.1. Are performance and capital covenants substitutes (H1)? To examine whether performance and capital covenants are substitutes, we regress them on the investment opportunity set (Skinner 1993) and other covenant determinants (Nash et al. 2003; Billett et al. 2007; Chava and Roberts 2008; Chava et al. 2010). Table 4 presents the regression estimates. Models (1) and (2) explain the determinants of performance covenants (P-Covenants) and capital covenants (C-Covenants), respectively. Model (3) explains the covenant mix, P/C-CovMix. We find that only the coefficients on Size, 22

24 ROA, and Altman's Z-score share the same sign across performance and capital covenants. All other firm characteristics in Models (1) and (2) exhibit opposite signs across the two types of covenants and in many cases are significantly different from zero. Perhaps the most striking finding in the table is that leverage exhibits a strong positive association with P-Covenants, while it exhibits a strong negative association with C-Covenants. This finding confirms the univariate results discussed in Section 4.2. In addition, whereas prior research documents a positive association between the number of accounting covenants and leverage (Press and Weintrop 1990; Duke and Hunt 1990; Skinner 1993; Bradley and Roberts 2004), this relationship does not hold for C-Covenants, further underscoring the difference between C- Covenants and P-Covenants. We do not derive empirical predictions as to how different types of covenants should be related to firm characteristics as the relationship is often an empirical question. However, we offer interpretations for several coefficients of interest. We find that larger (Size) and more mature companies (Age) rely on capital rather than performance covenants, which can be explained by lower information asymmetry in such companies. Consistent with this idea, Garleanu and Zwiebel (2009) show that tripwire-type covenants are used to address contracting frictions due to information asymmetry. We do not have a clear prediction on how growth opportunities are related to the covenant mix. On the one hand, capital covenants allow for greater managerial independence and flexibility, essential for high growth firms. On the other hand, lenders may be reluctant to grant flexibility to such firms due to greater agency problems. Existing empirical evidence on growth options and covenants is mixed. For instance, Bradley and Roberts (2004) find that high growth firms face more covenants, Demiroglu and James (2010) find that high growth firms get more but looser covenants, whereas Skinner (1993) finds 23

25 that high growth firms face fewer covenants. We find that companies with relatively high growth opportunities (as implied by lower book-to-market, B/M) tend to rely on performance rather than capital covenants. Our evidence complements and potentially helps reconcile the mixed findings of prior literature. In particular, the more intense use of performance covenants among high growth borrowers suggests more direct monitoring by lenders when investment opportunities are greater. We further find that companies with a larger portion of tangible assets (tangibility) rely more on C-Covenants than P-Covenants. Skinner (1993) argues that having assets-in-place helps overcome the asset substitution and underinvestment problems as such assets can be used as collateral and are easier to monitor via covenants. The need for tripwire covenants is thus likely lower. On the other hand, capital covenants are still likely to be useful as they help ensure that the value of the collateral (assets-in-place) exceeds a minimum threshold. In addition, R&D intensive companies (controlling for growth opportunities) and companies with low profits also gravitate towards the use of C-Covenants. This result can be explained intuitively by the lack of meaningful performance indicators in such companies (Demerjian 2007). For example, negative earnings, due say to large R&D expenditures, preclude the interpretation of performance ratios. Finally, consistent with the argument that volatile operations likely make the use of P-Covenants costly due to unwarranted covenant breaches, the standard deviation of returns (StdRet) is negatively associated with P-covenants but positively related to C-Covenants. The results on the determinants of the covenant mix in Model (3) closely mimic those in Models (1) and (2). This result makes P/C-CovMix a convenient summary measure of the type of covenant package used. Overall, the evidence implies that capital and performance covenants are indeed used by companies with different characteristics. This result, in combination with the 24

Debt Covenant Design and Creditor Control Rights: Evidence from Covenant Restrictiveness and Loan Outcomes

Debt Covenant Design and Creditor Control Rights: Evidence from Covenant Restrictiveness and Loan Outcomes Debt Covenant Design and Creditor Control Rights: Evidence from Covenant Restrictiveness and Loan Outcomes Jing Wang * August 2013 Abstract Using three measures of covenant restrictiveness, I examine the

More information

Refinancing Risk, Managerial Risk Shifting, and Debt Covenants: An Empirical Analysis

Refinancing Risk, Managerial Risk Shifting, and Debt Covenants: An Empirical Analysis Refinancing Risk, Managerial Risk Shifting, and Debt Covenants: An Empirical Analysis Bo Li Queen s University First Draft: January 2012 November 2, 2012 Abstract This paper identifies a special channel

More information

Borrower Conservatism and Debt Contracting

Borrower Conservatism and Debt Contracting Borrower Conservatism and Debt Contracting Jayanthi Sunder a Shyam V. Sunder b Jingjing Zhang c Kellogg School of Management Northwestern University November 2008 a Northwestern University, 6245 Jacobs

More information

Measuring Financial Covenant Strictness in Private Debt Contracts

Measuring Financial Covenant Strictness in Private Debt Contracts Measuring Financial Covenant Strictness in Private Debt Contracts Peter R. Demerjian Foster School of Business, University of Washington Edward L. Owens Simon School of Business, University of Rochester

More information

The Determinants and the Value of Cash Holdings: Evidence. from French firms

The Determinants and the Value of Cash Holdings: Evidence. from French firms The Determinants and the Value of Cash Holdings: Evidence from French firms Khaoula SADDOUR Cahier de recherche n 2006-6 Abstract: This paper investigates the determinants of the cash holdings of French

More information

Accounting Information in Financial Contracting: An Incomplete. Contract Theory Perspective

Accounting Information in Financial Contracting: An Incomplete. Contract Theory Perspective Accounting Information in Financial Contracting: An Incomplete Contract Theory Perspective Hans B. Christensen The University of Chicago Booth School of Business 5807 South Woodlawn Avenue, Chicago, IL,

More information

Capital Market Access and Corporate Loan Structure. Kenneth Khang. Idaho State University. Tao-Hsien Dolly King

Capital Market Access and Corporate Loan Structure. Kenneth Khang. Idaho State University. Tao-Hsien Dolly King Capital Market Access and Corporate Loan Structure Kenneth Khang Idaho State University Tao-Hsien Dolly King University of North Carolina - Charlotte Current version: September 2010 We thank Steven Byers

More information

Qualified Audit Opinions and Debt Contracting

Qualified Audit Opinions and Debt Contracting Qualified Audit Opinions and Debt Contracting Presented by Dr Derrald Stice Assistant Professor Hong Kong University of Science and Technology #2013/14-03 The views and opinions expressed in this working

More information

An Empirical Analysis of Insider Rates vs. Outsider Rates in Bank Lending

An Empirical Analysis of Insider Rates vs. Outsider Rates in Bank Lending An Empirical Analysis of Insider Rates vs. Outsider Rates in Bank Lending Lamont Black* Indiana University Federal Reserve Board of Governors November 2006 ABSTRACT: This paper analyzes empirically the

More information

Financial Ratios and Credit Risk: The Selection of Financial Ratio Covenants in Debt Contracts

Financial Ratios and Credit Risk: The Selection of Financial Ratio Covenants in Debt Contracts Financial Ratios and Credit Risk: The Selection of Financial Ratio Covenants in Debt Contracts Peter R. W. Demerjian* Stephen M. Ross School of Business University of Michigan January 11, 2007 Abstract

More information

Covenant Violations, Loan Contracting, and Default Risk of Bank Borrowers

Covenant Violations, Loan Contracting, and Default Risk of Bank Borrowers Covenant Violations, Loan Contracting, and Default Risk of Bank Borrowers Felix Freudenberg Björn Imbierowicz Anthony Saunders* Sascha Steffen March 2012 Abstract This paper investigates the consequences

More information

Corporate loan securitization and the standardization of financial covenants * Zahn Bozanic The Ohio State University mailto:mbozanic.1@osu.

Corporate loan securitization and the standardization of financial covenants * Zahn Bozanic The Ohio State University mailto:mbozanic.1@osu. Corporate loan securitization and the standardization of financial covenants * Zahn Bozanic The Ohio State University mailto:mbozanic.1@osu.edu Maria Loumioti USC Leventhal School of Accounting loumioti@marshall.usc.edu

More information

Working Paper No. 09-12. Who uses fair value accounting for non-financial assets after IFRS adoption?

Working Paper No. 09-12. Who uses fair value accounting for non-financial assets after IFRS adoption? Working Paper No. 09-12 Who uses fair value accounting for non-financial assets after IFRS adoption? Hans B. Christensen University of Chicago Booth School of Business Valeri Nikolaev University of Chicago

More information

The Information Content of Threshold Values in Earnings-Based Covenants*

The Information Content of Threshold Values in Earnings-Based Covenants* The Information Content of Threshold Values in Earnings-Based Covenants* Ningzhong Li London Business School Regent s Park, London, NW1 4SA, United Kingdom nli@london.edu Florin P. Vasvari London Business

More information

Accounting Conservatism and Private Debt Contracting

Accounting Conservatism and Private Debt Contracting Accounting Conservatism and Private Debt Contracting Jingjing Zhang Kellogg School of Management Northwestern University February 2008 I am grateful to my summer paper advisors, Jayanthi Sunder and Shyam

More information

Creditor Control Rights, Capital Structure and Legal Enforcement

Creditor Control Rights, Capital Structure and Legal Enforcement Creditor Control Rights, Capital Structure and Legal Enforcement Mai Daher* I investigate how the effectiveness of the judicial system impacts corporate financing policy through the channel of covenant

More information

Evidence on the Contracting Explanation of Conservatism

Evidence on the Contracting Explanation of Conservatism Evidence on the Contracting Explanation of Conservatism Ryan Blunck PhD Student University of Iowa Sonja Rego Lloyd J. and Thelma W. Palmer Research Fellow University of Iowa November 5, 2007 Abstract

More information

The Impact of Changes in Balance Sheet Covenant Protection on the Design of Private Loan Contracts

The Impact of Changes in Balance Sheet Covenant Protection on the Design of Private Loan Contracts The Impact of Changes in Balance Sheet Covenant Protection on the Design of Private Loan Contracts Peter Demerjian* Goizeuta Business School Emory University 1300 Clifton St NE Atlanta GA 30322 October

More information

Cash Holdings and Bank Loan Terms

Cash Holdings and Bank Loan Terms Preliminary and incomplete. Comments encouraged. Cash Holdings and Bank Loan Terms Mark Huson and Lukas Roth * January 2013 Abstract Recent evidence suggests that high cash holdings presage financial difficulties,

More information

Determinants of Capital Structure in Developing Countries

Determinants of Capital Structure in Developing Countries Determinants of Capital Structure in Developing Countries Tugba Bas*, Gulnur Muradoglu** and Kate Phylaktis*** 1 Second draft: October 28, 2009 Abstract This study examines the determinants of capital

More information

AN EMPIRICAL EXPLORATION OF FINANCIAL COVENANTS IN LARGE BANK LOANS 1

AN EMPIRICAL EXPLORATION OF FINANCIAL COVENANTS IN LARGE BANK LOANS 1 Banks and Bank Systems / Volume 1, Issue 2, 2006 103 AN EMPIRICAL EXPLORATION OF FINANCIAL COVENANTS IN LARGE BANK LOANS 1 John K. Paglia, Donald J. Mullineaux Abstract Financial covenants in large bank

More information

ONLINE APPENDIX TO Bridging the gap: the design of bank loan contracts and distance

ONLINE APPENDIX TO Bridging the gap: the design of bank loan contracts and distance ONLINE APPENDIX TO Bridging the gap: the design of bank loan contracts and distance Stephan Hollander and Arnt Verriest There are three sections in this Online Appendix. Section 1 reports on the determinants

More information

PERFORMANCE PRICING COVENANTS AND CORPORATE LOAN SPREADS. This Version: April 2013 ABSTRACT

PERFORMANCE PRICING COVENANTS AND CORPORATE LOAN SPREADS. This Version: April 2013 ABSTRACT PERFORMANCE PRICING COVENANTS AND CORPORATE LOAN SPREADS Kamphol Panyagometh a, Gordon S. Roberts b,*, Aron A. Gottesman c, Mehdi Beyhaghi d This Version: April 2013 ABSTRACT We explore the relation between

More information

Understanding a Firm s Different Financing Options. A Closer Look at Equity vs. Debt

Understanding a Firm s Different Financing Options. A Closer Look at Equity vs. Debt Understanding a Firm s Different Financing Options A Closer Look at Equity vs. Debt Financing Options: A Closer Look at Equity vs. Debt Business owners who seek financing face a fundamental choice: should

More information

Comment On: Reducing Foreclosures by Christopher Foote, Kristopher Gerardi, Lorenz Goette and Paul Willen

Comment On: Reducing Foreclosures by Christopher Foote, Kristopher Gerardi, Lorenz Goette and Paul Willen Comment On: Reducing Foreclosures by Christopher Foote, Kristopher Gerardi, Lorenz Goette and Paul Willen Atif Mian 1 University of Chicago Booth School of Business and NBER The current global recession

More information

The Debt-Contracting Value of Accounting Information and Loan Syndicate Structure *

The Debt-Contracting Value of Accounting Information and Loan Syndicate Structure * The Debt-Contracting Value of Accounting Information and Loan Syndicate Structure * Ryan Ball Kenan-Flagler Business School University of North Carolina-Chapel Hill ballr@unc.edu Robert Bushman Kenan-Flagler

More information

Aggregate Risk and the Choice Between Cash and Lines of Credit

Aggregate Risk and the Choice Between Cash and Lines of Credit Aggregate Risk and the Choice Between Cash and Lines of Credit Viral Acharya NYU Stern School of Business, CEPR, NBER Heitor Almeida University of Illinois at Urbana Champaign, NBER Murillo Campello Cornell

More information

Determinants of short-term debt financing

Determinants of short-term debt financing ABSTRACT Determinants of short-term debt financing Richard H. Fosberg William Paterson University In this study, it is shown that both theories put forward to explain the amount of shortterm debt financing

More information

Accounting Conservatism and the Consequences of Covenant Violations

Accounting Conservatism and the Consequences of Covenant Violations Accounting Conservatism and the Consequences of Covenant Violations by Yutao Li A thesis presented to the University of Waterloo in fulfilment of the thesis requirement for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy

More information

Debtor-in-Possession Financing. Sris Chatterjee * Upinder S. Dhillon ** Gabriel G. Ramírez *** Forthcoming Journal of Banking and Finance, 2005

Debtor-in-Possession Financing. Sris Chatterjee * Upinder S. Dhillon ** Gabriel G. Ramírez *** Forthcoming Journal of Banking and Finance, 2005 Debtor-in-Possession Financing Sris Chatterjee * Upinder S. Dhillon ** Gabriel G. Ramírez *** Forthcoming Journal of Banking and Finance, 2005 * Corresponding Author Graduate Business School, Fordham University,

More information

Cost of Capital, Valuation and Strategic Financial Decision Making

Cost of Capital, Valuation and Strategic Financial Decision Making Cost of Capital, Valuation and Strategic Financial Decision Making By Dr. Valerio Poti, - Examiner in Professional 2 Stage Strategic Corporate Finance The financial crisis that hit financial markets in

More information

Managerial incentives to increase firm volatility provided by debt, stock, and options. Joshua D. Anderson jdanders@mit.

Managerial incentives to increase firm volatility provided by debt, stock, and options. Joshua D. Anderson jdanders@mit. Managerial incentives to increase firm volatility provided by debt, stock, and options Joshua D. Anderson jdanders@mit.edu (617) 253-7974 John E. Core* jcore@mit.edu (617) 715-4819 Abstract We use option

More information

Firm characteristics. The current issue and full text archive of this journal is available at www.emeraldinsight.com/0307-4358.htm

Firm characteristics. The current issue and full text archive of this journal is available at www.emeraldinsight.com/0307-4358.htm The current issue and full text archive of this journal is available at www.emeraldinsight.com/0307-4358.htm How firm characteristics affect capital structure: an empirical study Nikolaos Eriotis National

More information

Credit Analysis 10-1

Credit Analysis 10-1 Credit Analysis 10-1 10-2 Liquidity and Working Capital Basics Liquidity - Ability to convert assets into cash or to obtain cash to meet short-term obligations. Short-term - Conventionally viewed as a

More information

FRBSF ECONOMIC LETTER

FRBSF ECONOMIC LETTER FRBSF ECONOMIC LETTER 2009-27 August 31, 2009 Credit Market Conditions and the Use of Bank Lines of Credit BY CHRISTOPHER M. JAMES Many credit line agreements contain restrictive covenants and other contingencies

More information

The Composition and Priority of Corporate Debt: Evidence from Fallen Angels*

The Composition and Priority of Corporate Debt: Evidence from Fallen Angels* The Composition and Priority of Corporate Debt: Evidence from Fallen Angels* Joshua D. Rauh University of Chicago Graduate School of Business and NBER Amir Sufi University of Chicago Graduate School of

More information

The Role of Bond Covenants and Short-Term Debt: Evidence from Brazil

The Role of Bond Covenants and Short-Term Debt: Evidence from Brazil Available online at http:// BAR, Rio de Janeiro, v. 10, n. 3, art. 5, pp. 323-346, July/Sept. 2013 The Role of Bond Covenants and Short-Term Debt: Evidence from Brazil Vinícius Augusto Brunassi Silva E-mail

More information

Understanding Leverage in Closed-End Funds

Understanding Leverage in Closed-End Funds Closed-End Funds Understanding Leverage in Closed-End Funds The concept of leverage seems simple: borrowing money at a low cost and using it to seek higher returns on an investment. Leverage as it applies

More information

Similarity in Bond Covenants*

Similarity in Bond Covenants* Similarity in Bond Covenants* Gus De Franco Rotman School of Management, University of Toronto 105 St. George Street, Toronto, M5S 3E6, Canada gus.defranco@rotman.utoronto.ca Florin P. Vasvari London Business

More information

How Does Financing Impact Investment? The Role of Debt Covenants

How Does Financing Impact Investment? The Role of Debt Covenants THE JOURNAL OF FINANCE VOL. LXIII, NO. 5 OCTOBER 2008 How Does Financing Impact Investment? The Role of Debt Covenants SUDHEER CHAVA and MICHAEL R. ROBERTS ABSTRACT We identify a specific channel (debt

More information

Variable Construction

Variable Construction Online Data Appendix for Where Did All the Dollars Go?? The Effect of Cash Flows on Capital and Asset Structure Sudipto Dasgupta, Thomas H. Noe, and Zhen Wang Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis,,

More information

Journal Of Financial And Strategic Decisions Volume 8 Number 1 Spring 1995

Journal Of Financial And Strategic Decisions Volume 8 Number 1 Spring 1995 Journal Of Financial And Strategic Decisions Volume 8 Number 1 Spring 1995 THE DETERMINANTS OF ACTUARIAL ASSUMPTIONS UNDER PENSION ACCOUNTING DISCLOSURES V.Gopalakrishnan * and Timothy F. Sugrue * Abstract

More information

Accounting Conservatism and Debt Contracts: Efficient Liquidation and Covenant Renegotiation

Accounting Conservatism and Debt Contracts: Efficient Liquidation and Covenant Renegotiation Accounting Conservatism and Debt Contracts: Efficient Liquidation and Covenant Renegotiation Jing Li Tepper School of Business Abstract This paper develops a theoretical model to understand the role of

More information

Autoria: Eduardo Kazuo Kayo, Douglas Dias Bastos

Autoria: Eduardo Kazuo Kayo, Douglas Dias Bastos Frequent Acquirers and Financing Policy: The Effect of the 2000 Bubble Burst Autoria: Eduardo Kazuo Kayo, Douglas Dias Bastos Abstract We analyze the effect of the 2000 bubble burst on the financing policy.

More information

EFRAG Short Discussion Series THE USE OF INFORMATION BY CAPITAL PROVIDERS IMPLICATIONS FOR STANDARD SETTING

EFRAG Short Discussion Series THE USE OF INFORMATION BY CAPITAL PROVIDERS IMPLICATIONS FOR STANDARD SETTING EFRAG Short Discussion Series THE USE OF INFORMATION BY CAPITAL PROVIDERS IMPLICATIONS FOR STANDARD SETTING JAN 2014 This document has been published by EFRAG to assist constituents in developing their

More information

Chapter 7: Capital Structure: An Overview of the Financing Decision

Chapter 7: Capital Structure: An Overview of the Financing Decision Chapter 7: Capital Structure: An Overview of the Financing Decision 1. Income bonds are similar to preferred stock in several ways. Payment of interest on income bonds depends on the availability of sufficient

More information

A Piece of the Pie: Alternative Approaches to Allocating Value

A Piece of the Pie: Alternative Approaches to Allocating Value A Piece of the Pie: Alternative Approaches to Allocating Value Cory Thompson, CFA, CIRA cthompson@srr.com Ryan Gandre, CFA rgandre@srr.com Introduction Enterprise value ( EV ) represents the sum of debt

More information

How credit analysts view and use the financial statements

How credit analysts view and use the financial statements How credit analysts view and use the financial statements Introduction Traditionally it is viewed that equity investment is high risk and bond investment low risk. Bondholders look at companies for creditworthiness,

More information

The role of covenants in public and private debt

The role of covenants in public and private debt The role of covenants in public and private debt Flavio Bazzana, Eleonora Broccardo Faculty of Economics Via Inama, 5 University of Trento Italy Ph. +39 0461 883107 Fax +39 0461 882124 flavio.bazzana@economia.unitn.it

More information

Financial Statement Analysis of Leverage and How It Informs About Profitability and Price-to-Book Ratios

Financial Statement Analysis of Leverage and How It Informs About Profitability and Price-to-Book Ratios Financial Statement Analysis of Leverage and How It Informs About Profitability and Price-to-Book Ratios Doron Nissim Graduate School of Business Columbia University 3022 Broadway, Uris Hall 604 New York,

More information

The Use of Bank Lines of Credit in Corporate Liquidity Management: A Review of Empirical Evidence. Abstract

The Use of Bank Lines of Credit in Corporate Liquidity Management: A Review of Empirical Evidence. Abstract The Use of Bank Lines of Credit in Corporate Liquidity Management: A Review of Empirical Evidence Cem Demiroglu, College of Administrative Sciences and Economics, Koc University Christopher James, Warrington

More information

Jarrad Harford, Sandy Klasa and William Maxwell

Jarrad Harford, Sandy Klasa and William Maxwell Refinancing Risk and Cash Holdings The Journal of Finance Refinancing Risk and Cash Holdings Refinancing Risk and Cash Holdings Jarrad Harford, Sandy Klasa and William Maxwell The Journal of Finance The

More information

Bank Lines of Credit in Corporate Finance: An Empirical Analysis

Bank Lines of Credit in Corporate Finance: An Empirical Analysis RFS Advance Access published January 31, 2007 Bank Lines of Credit in Corporate Finance: An Empirical Analysis AMIR SUFI* University of Chicago Graduate School of Business 5807 South Woodlawn Avenue Chicago,

More information

Corporate governance and restrictions in debt contracts 1

Corporate governance and restrictions in debt contracts 1 Corporate governance and restrictions in debt contracts 1 Xi Li a, İrem Tuna b, Florin P. Vasvari c a Fox School of Business, Temple University, 449 Alter Hall, 1801 Liacouras Walk Philadelphia, PA 19122,

More information

Stock market booms and real economic activity: Is this time different?

Stock market booms and real economic activity: Is this time different? International Review of Economics and Finance 9 (2000) 387 415 Stock market booms and real economic activity: Is this time different? Mathias Binswanger* Institute for Economics and the Environment, University

More information

READING 11: TAXES AND PRIVATE WEALTH MANAGEMENT IN A GLOBAL CONTEXT

READING 11: TAXES AND PRIVATE WEALTH MANAGEMENT IN A GLOBAL CONTEXT READING 11: TAXES AND PRIVATE WEALTH MANAGEMENT IN A GLOBAL CONTEXT Introduction Taxes have a significant impact on net performance and affect an adviser s understanding of risk for the taxable investor.

More information

Asian Economic and Financial Review THE CAPITAL INVESTMENT INCREASES AND STOCK RETURNS

Asian Economic and Financial Review THE CAPITAL INVESTMENT INCREASES AND STOCK RETURNS Asian Economic and Financial Review journal homepage: http://www.aessweb.com/journals/5002 THE CAPITAL INVESTMENT INCREASES AND STOCK RETURNS Jung Fang Liu 1 --- Nicholas Rueilin Lee 2 * --- Yih-Bey Lin

More information

Use this section to learn more about business loans and specific financial products that might be right for your company.

Use this section to learn more about business loans and specific financial products that might be right for your company. Types of Financing Use this section to learn more about business loans and specific financial products that might be right for your company. Revolving Line Of Credit Revolving lines of credit are the most

More information

Mezzanine Finance. by Corry Silbernagel Davis Vaitkunas Bond Capital. With a supplement by Ian Giddy

Mezzanine Finance. by Corry Silbernagel Davis Vaitkunas Bond Capital. With a supplement by Ian Giddy Mezzanine Finance by Corry Silbernagel Davis Vaitkunas Bond Capital With a supplement by Ian Giddy Mezzanine Debt--Another Level To Consider Mezzanine debt is used by companies that are cash flow positive

More information

How Much Liquidity Insurance Can Lines of Credit Provide? The Impact of Bank Reputation and Lending Relationship *

How Much Liquidity Insurance Can Lines of Credit Provide? The Impact of Bank Reputation and Lending Relationship * How Much Liquidity Insurance Can Lines of Credit Provide? The Impact of Bank Reputation and Lending Relationship * Zhaohui Chen McIntire School of Commerce University of Virginia Yan Hu University of Minnesota

More information

The Perceived Earnings Quality Consequences of Announcements to Voluntarily Adopt the Fair Value Method of Accounting for Stock-Based Compensation

The Perceived Earnings Quality Consequences of Announcements to Voluntarily Adopt the Fair Value Method of Accounting for Stock-Based Compensation The Perceived Earnings Quality Consequences of Announcements to Voluntarily Adopt the Fair Value Method of Accounting for Stock-Based Compensation John D. Phillips* University of Connecticut Karen Teitel

More information

Black-Scholes-Merton approach merits and shortcomings

Black-Scholes-Merton approach merits and shortcomings Black-Scholes-Merton approach merits and shortcomings Emilia Matei 1005056 EC372 Term Paper. Topic 3 1. Introduction The Black-Scholes and Merton method of modelling derivatives prices was first introduced

More information

Determinants of Recovery Rates on Defaulted Bonds and Loans for North American Corporate Issuers: 1983-2003

Determinants of Recovery Rates on Defaulted Bonds and Loans for North American Corporate Issuers: 1983-2003 Special Comment December 2004 Contact Phone New York Praveen Varma 1.212.553.1653 Richard Cantor Determinants of Recovery Rates on Defaulted Bonds and Loans for North American Corporate Issuers: 1983-2003

More information

On Loan Sales, Loan Contracting, and Lending Relationships

On Loan Sales, Loan Contracting, and Lending Relationships On Loan Sales, Loan Contracting, and Lending Relationships Steven Drucker and Manju Puri * July 2006 ABSTRACT Banks are increasingly using secondary loan sales to manage credit risk and diversify their

More information

Debt Dispersion, Creditor Conflicts, and Covenants in Corporate Loans

Debt Dispersion, Creditor Conflicts, and Covenants in Corporate Loans Debt Dispersion, Creditor Conflicts, and Covenants in Corporate Loans Yun Lou and Clemens A. Otto March 2015 Abstract How do conflicts between different creditors affect debt contract terms? We study this

More information

Financial-Institutions Management

Financial-Institutions Management Solutions 3 Chapter 11: Credit Risk Loan Pricing and Terms 9. County Bank offers one-year loans with a stated rate of 9 percent but requires a compensating balance of 10 percent. What is the true cost

More information

t = 1 2 3 1. Calculate the implied interest rates and graph the term structure of interest rates. t = 1 2 3 X t = 100 100 100 t = 1 2 3

t = 1 2 3 1. Calculate the implied interest rates and graph the term structure of interest rates. t = 1 2 3 X t = 100 100 100 t = 1 2 3 MØA 155 PROBLEM SET: Summarizing Exercise 1. Present Value [3] You are given the following prices P t today for receiving risk free payments t periods from now. t = 1 2 3 P t = 0.95 0.9 0.85 1. Calculate

More information

Paul Brockman Xiumin Martin Emre Unlu

Paul Brockman Xiumin Martin Emre Unlu Paul Brockman Xiumin Martin Emre Unlu Objective and motivation Research question and hypothesis Research design Discussion of results Conclusion The purpose of this paper is to examine the CEO s portfolio

More information

An Alternative Way to Diversify an Income Strategy

An Alternative Way to Diversify an Income Strategy Senior Secured Loans An Alternative Way to Diversify an Income Strategy Alternative Thinking Series There is no shortage of uncertainty and risk facing today s investor. From high unemployment and depressed

More information

Response to Critiques of Mortgage Discrimination and FHA Loan Performance

Response to Critiques of Mortgage Discrimination and FHA Loan Performance A Response to Comments Response to Critiques of Mortgage Discrimination and FHA Loan Performance James A. Berkovec Glenn B. Canner Stuart A. Gabriel Timothy H. Hannan Abstract This response discusses the

More information

Financial Terms & Calculations

Financial Terms & Calculations Financial Terms & Calculations So much about business and its management requires knowledge and information as to financial measurements. Unfortunately these key terms and ratios are often misunderstood

More information

Capital Structure. Itay Goldstein. Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania

Capital Structure. Itay Goldstein. Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania Capital Structure Itay Goldstein Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania 1 Debt and Equity There are two main types of financing: debt and equity. Consider a two-period world with dates 0 and 1. At

More information

Institutional Trading, Brokerage Commissions, and Information Production around Stock Splits

Institutional Trading, Brokerage Commissions, and Information Production around Stock Splits Institutional Trading, Brokerage Commissions, and Information Production around Stock Splits Thomas J. Chemmanur Boston College Gang Hu Babson College Jiekun Huang Boston College First Version: September

More information

Understanding Bank Loan Covenants:

Understanding Bank Loan Covenants: Understanding Bank Loan Covenants: What You Need to Know Before You Sign This white paper, produced in collaboration with the Small Business Finance Institute, is the first in a series of educational articles

More information

Fundamentals Level Skills Module, Paper F9

Fundamentals Level Skills Module, Paper F9 Answers Fundamentals Level Skills Module, Paper F9 Financial Management December 2008 Answers 1 (a) Rights issue price = 2 5 x 0 8 = $2 00 per share Theoretical ex rights price = ((2 50 x 4) + (1 x 2 00)/5=$2

More information

THE EFFECT ON RIVALS WHEN FIRMS EMERGE FROM BANKRUPTCY

THE EFFECT ON RIVALS WHEN FIRMS EMERGE FROM BANKRUPTCY THE EFFECT ON RIVALS WHEN FIRMS EMERGE FROM BANKRUPTCY Gary L. Caton *, Jeffrey Donaldson**, Jeremy Goh*** Abstract Studies on the announcement effects of bankruptcy filings have found that when a firm

More information

In this chapter, we build on the basic knowledge of how businesses

In this chapter, we build on the basic knowledge of how businesses 03-Seidman.qxd 5/15/04 11:52 AM Page 41 3 An Introduction to Business Financial Statements In this chapter, we build on the basic knowledge of how businesses are financed by looking at how firms organize

More information

Working Paper No. 09-12. Does fair value accounting for non-financial assets pass the market test?

Working Paper No. 09-12. Does fair value accounting for non-financial assets pass the market test? Working Paper No. 09-12 Does fair value accounting for non-financial assets pass the market test? Hans B. Christensen University of Chicago Booth School of Business Valeri Nikolaev University of Chicago

More information

Factors Determining Bank Debt vs Bond Debt of Canadian Corporations

Factors Determining Bank Debt vs Bond Debt of Canadian Corporations Factors Determining Bank Debt vs Bond Debt of Canadian Corporations May 2012 Preliminary; do not quote George J. Georgopoulos Department of Economics York University, Toronto, Canada Abstract This paper

More information

Application of the Z -Score Model with Consideration of Total Assets Volatility in Predicting Corporate Financial Failures from 2000-2010

Application of the Z -Score Model with Consideration of Total Assets Volatility in Predicting Corporate Financial Failures from 2000-2010 Application of the Z -Score Model with Consideration of Total Assets Volatility in Predicting Corporate Financial Failures from 2000-2010 June Li University of Wisconsin, River Falls Reza Rahgozar University

More information

IASB/FASB Meeting Week beginning 11 April 2011. Top down approaches to discount rates

IASB/FASB Meeting Week beginning 11 April 2011. Top down approaches to discount rates IASB/FASB Meeting Week beginning 11 April 2011 IASB Agenda reference 5A FASB Agenda Staff Paper reference 63A Contacts Matthias Zeitler mzeitler@iasb.org +44 (0)20 7246 6453 Shayne Kuhaneck skuhaneck@fasb.org

More information

Does Fair Value Accounting for Non-Financial Assets Pass the Market Test?

Does Fair Value Accounting for Non-Financial Assets Pass the Market Test? Does Fair Value Accounting for Non-Financial Assets Pass the Market Test? Hans B. Christensen and Valeri V. Nikolaev The University of Chicago Booth School of Business 5807 South Woodlawn Avenue Chicago,

More information

DIVIDEND POLICY, TRADING CHARACTERISTICS AND SHARE PRICES: EMPIRICAL EVIDENCE FROM EGYPTIAN FIRMS

DIVIDEND POLICY, TRADING CHARACTERISTICS AND SHARE PRICES: EMPIRICAL EVIDENCE FROM EGYPTIAN FIRMS International Journal of Theoretical and Applied Finance Vol. 7, No. 2 (2004) 121 133 c World Scientific Publishing Company DIVIDEND POLICY, TRADING CHARACTERISTICS AND SHARE PRICES: EMPIRICAL EVIDENCE

More information

Small Bank Comparative Advantages in Alleviating Financial Constraints and Providing Liquidity Insurance over Time

Small Bank Comparative Advantages in Alleviating Financial Constraints and Providing Liquidity Insurance over Time Small Bank Comparative Advantages in Alleviating Financial Constraints and Providing Liquidity Insurance over Time Allen N. Berger University of South Carolina Wharton Financial Institutions Center European

More information

Stock Trading and Capital Structure in Tunisian Stock Exchange

Stock Trading and Capital Structure in Tunisian Stock Exchange Journal of Business Studies Quarterly ISSN 2152-1034 Stock Trading and Capital Structure in Tunisian Stock Exchange Karim Ben Khediri, CEROS, University Paris Ouest Nanterre La Défense & University of

More information

Debt Capacity and Tests of Capital Structure Theories

Debt Capacity and Tests of Capital Structure Theories Debt Capacity and Tests of Capital Structure Theories Michael L. Lemmon David Eccles School of Business University of Utah email: finmll@business.utah.edu Jaime F. Zender Leeds School of Business University

More information

The Effect of Capital Structure on the Financial Performance of Small and Medium Enterprises in Thika Sub-County, Kenya

The Effect of Capital Structure on the Financial Performance of Small and Medium Enterprises in Thika Sub-County, Kenya International Journal of Humanities and Social Science Vol. 5, No. 1; January 2015 The Effect of Capital Structure on the Financial Performance of Small and Medium Enterprises in Thika Sub-County, Kenya

More information

Rising Rates and the Case for Leveraged Loans PERSPECTIVE FROM FRANKLIN FLOATING RATE DEBT GROUP

Rising Rates and the Case for Leveraged Loans PERSPECTIVE FROM FRANKLIN FLOATING RATE DEBT GROUP January 11, 2013 Topic Paper September 2015 Rising Rates and the Case for Leveraged Loans PERSPECTIVE FROM FRANKLIN FLOATING RATE DEBT GROUP Mark Boyadjian and Reema Agarwal of Franklin Templeton Fixed

More information

ACCOUNTING STANDARDS BOARD FINANCIAL CAPITAL MANAGEMENT DISCLOSURES

ACCOUNTING STANDARDS BOARD FINANCIAL CAPITAL MANAGEMENT DISCLOSURES ACCOUNTING STANDARDS BOARD FINANCIAL CAPITAL MANAGEMENT DISCLOSURES DECEMBER 2010 Contents Highlights One - Introduction 1 Two - Market feedback 2 Three - Business review disclosures 3 Four - IFRS disclosures

More information

Hedge Fund Activism and Bank Loan Contracting

Hedge Fund Activism and Bank Loan Contracting Hedge Fund Activism and Bank Loan Contracting Yinghua Li Krannert School of Management Purdue University West Lafayette, IN 47907-205 Tel: (765) 496-3510, Email: yli@purdue.edu Jin Xu Krannert School of

More information

How To Calculate Financial Leverage Ratio

How To Calculate Financial Leverage Ratio What Do Short-Term Liquidity Ratios Measure? What Is Working Capital? HOCK international - 2004 1 HOCK international - 2004 2 How Is the Current Ratio Calculated? How Is the Quick Ratio Calculated? HOCK

More information

How Do Small Businesses Finance their Growth Opportunities? The Case of Recovery from the Lost Decade in Japan

How Do Small Businesses Finance their Growth Opportunities? The Case of Recovery from the Lost Decade in Japan How Do Small Businesses Finance their Growth Opportunities? The Case of Recovery from the Lost Decade in Japan Daisuke Tsuruta National Graduate Institute for Policy Studies and CRD Association January

More information

Small Business Borrowing and the Owner Manager Agency Costs: Evidence on Finnish Data. Jyrki Niskanen Mervi Niskanen 10.11.2005

Small Business Borrowing and the Owner Manager Agency Costs: Evidence on Finnish Data. Jyrki Niskanen Mervi Niskanen 10.11.2005 Small Business Borrowing and the Owner Manager Agency Costs: Evidence on Finnish Data Jyrki Niskanen Mervi Niskanen 10.11.2005 Abstract. This study investigates the impact that managerial ownership has

More information

CHAPTER 16. Financial Distress, Managerial Incentives, and Information. Chapter Synopsis

CHAPTER 16. Financial Distress, Managerial Incentives, and Information. Chapter Synopsis CHAPTER 16 Financial Distress, Managerial Incentives, and Information Chapter Synopsis In the previous two chapters it was shown that, in an otherwise perfect capital market in which firms pay taxes, the

More information

The Effect of Bank Shocks on Corporate Financing and Investment: Evidence from 2007-2009 Financial Crisis

The Effect of Bank Shocks on Corporate Financing and Investment: Evidence from 2007-2009 Financial Crisis The Effect of Bank Shocks on Corporate Financing and Investment: Evidence from 2007-2009 Financial Crisis This version: April 5, 2013 Abstract We examine how shocks to banks financial conditions impact

More information

LAW & PROJECT FINANCE

LAW & PROJECT FINANCE 2 7 T H A U G 2 0 1 0 LAW & PROJECT FINANCE K R I S H N A M U R T H Y S U B R A M A N I A N INDIAN SCHOOL OF BUSINESS Joint with F R E D E R I C K T U N G Chair Professor of Law, Boston University, USA

More information

THE EURO AREA BANK LENDING SURVEY 1ST QUARTER OF 2014

THE EURO AREA BANK LENDING SURVEY 1ST QUARTER OF 2014 THE EURO AREA BANK LENDING SURVEY 1ST QUARTER OF 214 APRIL 214 European Central Bank, 214 Address Kaiserstrasse 29, 6311 Frankfurt am Main, Germany Postal address Postfach 16 3 19, 666 Frankfurt am Main,

More information

Exclusion of Stock-based Compensation Expense from Analyst Earnings Forecasts: Incentive- and Information-based Explanations. Mary E.

Exclusion of Stock-based Compensation Expense from Analyst Earnings Forecasts: Incentive- and Information-based Explanations. Mary E. Exclusion of Stock-based Compensation Expense from Analyst Earnings Forecasts: Incentive- and Information-based Explanations Mary E. Barth* Ian D. Gow Daniel J. Taylor Graduate School of Business Stanford

More information

Discretionary Accruals and Earnings Management: An Analysis of Pseudo Earnings Targets

Discretionary Accruals and Earnings Management: An Analysis of Pseudo Earnings Targets THE ACCOUNTING REVIEW Vol. 81, No. 3 2006 pp. 617 652 Discretionary Accruals and Earnings Management: An Analysis of Pseudo Earnings Targets Benjamin C. Ayers University of Georgia John (Xuefeng) Jiang

More information

International Financial Reporting Standard 7. Financial Instruments: Disclosures

International Financial Reporting Standard 7. Financial Instruments: Disclosures International Financial Reporting Standard 7 Financial Instruments: Disclosures INTERNATIONAL FINANCIAL REPORTING STANDARD AUGUST 2005 International Financial Reporting Standard 7 Financial Instruments:

More information