Managerial incentives to increase firm volatility provided by debt, stock, and options. Joshua D. Anderson

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Managerial incentives to increase firm volatility provided by debt, stock, and options. Joshua D. Anderson jdanders@mit."

Transcription

1 Managerial incentives to increase firm volatility provided by debt, stock, and options Joshua D. Anderson (617) John E. Core* (617) Abstract We use option pricing theory to derive and to calculate an overall measure of risk-taking incentives using managers debt, stock, and option sensitivities to firm volatility. We compare this measure to option vega and relative measures used by the prior literature. Vega does not capture risk incentives from managers ownership of stock and debt, and does not reflect the fact that employee options are warrants. The relative measures do not correctly incorporate the sensitivity of option value to firm volatility. We find that the new measure is more highly associated with risk choices than vega and the relative measures. First draft: October 19, 2011 This draft: March 25, 2013 * Corresponding author. We gratefully acknowledge comments from Ana Albuquerque (discussant), Wayne Guay, Mitchell Petersen, Eric So, Daniel Taylor, Anand Venkateswaran, and seminar participants at Columbia University, MIT Sloan, Northeastern University and the financial support of the MIT Sloan School of Management. We thank Ingolf Dittmann for his estimates of CEO non-firm wealth.

2 1. Introduction A large literature uses the sensitivity of stock options to an increase in stock volatility ( vega ) to study whether options provide managers incentives to increase risk (e.g., Guay, 1999; Core and Guay, 2002; Coles et al., 2006; Hayes et al., 2012). Studies on early samples show a strong positive association between vega and risk-taking (Guay, 1999; Coles et al., 2006), whereas studies on later samples show mixed results (e.g., Hayes et al., 2012). We re-examine vega and show that it has two shortcomings: (1) it does not capture potential risk incentives from managers ownership of stock and of debt (unsecured pensions and deferred compensation), and (2) it does not reflect the fact that employee options are warrants. Limited liability implies that firm equity is an option on firm value with a strike price equal to the face value of debt. Consequently, an increase in firm volatility increases equity value by reducing debt value (Black and Scholes 1973; Merton, 1973, 1974). When a firm has options, this increase in equity value is shared between the stock and options. This implies an option sensitivity to volatility that is larger than vega. Because options are warrants, an increase in volatility that increases the value of an option comes in part from a reduction in the value of stock. If the firm has no debt, all of the increase in option value from an increase in volatility comes from a decrease in stock value. This implies a stock sensitivity to volatility that goes from being negative to positive as leverage increases. These interrelations at the firm level imply that a manager s attitude toward an increase in firm volatility will be affected by the relative magnitudes of the firm s debt, stock, and option sensitivities to firm volatility and by the relative magnitudes of the managers holdings of debt, stock, and options. To estimate the sensitivities of the firm s debt, stock, and options to firm volatility, we value total firm equity (stock and stock options) as an option on the value of firm assets (e.g., 1

3 Eberhart, 2005; Campbell et al., 2008; Bharath and Shumway, 2008). This option pricing model gives an estimate of the decrease in debt value for a given increase in firm volatility. Since total firm value has no sensitivity to volatility, a decrease in debt value implies an equal increase in equity value. This increase in equity value is shared between the stock and stock options. We estimate the CEO s sensitivities by applying the CEO s ownership of debt, stock, and options to the firm s sensitivities. Our primary sample contains 6,020 Execucomp CEO-years from 2006 to The typical firm in this sample has low leverage. It is intuitive therefore that the typical firm has a very low debt sensitivity to firm volatility, and therefore low equity sensitivity to firm volatility. As the firms leverage increases, however, the debt sensitivity to firm volatility becomes much more negative, while the option sensitivity remains fairly constant. The stock sensitivity to firm volatility is negative for low values of leverage (where the dilution effect of warrants dominates), but becomes strongly positive for high levels of leverage (where the option value of equity dominates). We calculate a total sensitivity measure that sums the sensitivities of the CEO s debt, stock, and options to firm volatility. The average CEO in our sample owns roughly 2% of the debt, 2% of the stock, and 16% of the options. Accordingly, in terms of incentives to increase volatility, the typical CEO has small negative incentives from debt, small or negative incentives from stock, and large positive incentives from options. Further, 92% of our CEOs have total incentives from debt, stock, and options to increase risk, and these incentives can be substantial. A one standard deviation increase in firm volatility increases the average CEO s wealth by $3 million, or 7% of total wealth. As leverage increases, the average CEO s debt sensitivity to firm volatility decreases, but the average CEO s equity sensitivity (the sum of stock and option 2

4 sensitivities) to volatility increases more because the stock sensitivity changes from being negative to strongly positive. The total sensitivity increases as leverage increases, but the vega roughly remains constant with leverage. The vega and total sensitivity have a Pearson correlation of Because vega ignores debt and stock sensitivities, it can be a noisy and biased measure of risk-taking incentives. If the total sensitivity better reflects CEO incentives, we expect it to exhibit a higher association with CEO s risk-taking choices. To test this conjecture, we examine the association between the measures and three proxies for future firm risk: stock volatility, research and development expense, and leverage. We follow similar specifications in Coles et al. (2006) and Hayes et al. (2012). In general our results suggest that the total sensitivity is more highly associated with risk-taking. Measuring incentives with total sensitivity, we find the expected positive associations, though they are not always significant. Unexpectedly, we find that vega has a negative and significant coefficient in some regressions for our sample as compared to positive and significant coefficients for the sample in Coles et al. We examine modified specifications in which we scale the the CEO s risk-taking incentives with a proxy for the CEO s total wealth. We also scale CEO s incentive to increase stock price ( delta ) and with a proxy for the CEO s total wealth. Theory suggests that higher risk-taking incentives relative to wealth lead to higher risk-taking, and that higher delta relative to wealth leads to lower risk-taking. Prior research (e.g., Coles et al., 2006) controls for wealth effects by using tenure and compensation as proxies for CEO wealth. We find that the scaled measures explain firm risk better than the unscaled measures, and that the scaled total sensitivity explains firm risk better than the scaled vega. 3

5 The total sensitivity measure requires data on CEOs inside debt, which data became available only in To avoid this limitation, we also examine the equity sensitivity, which is equal to the total sensitivity minus the debt sensitivity. Empirically, the sample CEOs have little incentives from their inside debt, so their equity sensitivity is almost perfectly correlated with their total sensitivity. We compute the equity sensitivity from and compare it with vega. In this sample, we also find that equity sensitivity explains risk-taking better than vega, and that the scaled equity sensitivity is superior to the unscaled measures. A concern about our results is reverse causality (that is, when risk is expected to be high, firm use high risk-taking incentives). To explore the robustness of our results, we follow Hayes et al. (2012) and use the introduction of option expensing (SFAS 123R) as an exogenous change to incentives. Consistent with Hayes et al., we find no significant association between the change in vega and changes in firm risk for our sample. However, the change in scaled equity sensitivity is significantly positively associated with both the change in stock volatility and the change in leverage. To the extent that scaled equity sensitivity is a superior measure than vega, our results suggest that it may be premature to conclude that CEOs risk-taking incentives are not causally related to their risk-taking choices. Our analysis of the interrelation between the sensitivity of debt, stock, and options also implies that the relative risk-taking measures used in the recent literature (e.g., Cassell et al., 2012; Sundaram and Yermack, 2007; Wei and Yermack, 2011) are noisy and can be biased. Although the calculations are slightly different, these measures do not correctly incorporate the sensitivity of option value to firm volatility. We calculate a measure that attempts to correctly weight the manager s debt, stock, and option sensitivities. The prior measures suggest that CEOs on average tend to have a fairly large identification with debt holders: the average CEO has debt 4

6 incentives to reduce volatility that are three times his equity incentives to increase volatility. By contrast, the corrected measure, which explicitly takes into account volatility incentives from options, is an order of magnitude smaller, suggesting that CEOs have little identification with debt holders: the average CEO has incentives to reduce volatility that are equal to 0.3 times his equity incentives to increase volatility. 1 Despite these problems, these ratios provide reasonable explanatory power for risk choices. However, our scaled total sensitivity measure is generally more highly associated with risk-taking choices than the relative ratios. We contribute to the literature in several ways. We provide a measure of risk-taking incentives that includes the sensitivity of managers debt and stock holdings. In addition, our measure better calculates the sensitivity of the manager s stock options to firm volatility. We compare this measure to option vega and relative measures used by the prior literature. Vega does not capture risk incentives from managers ownership of stock and debt, and does not reflect the fact that employee options are warrants. The relative measures do not correctly incorporate the sensitivity of option value to firm volatility. We find that the new measure is more highly associated with risk choices than vega and the relative measures. Finally, our measure offers a potential resolution to the unexpected result in Hayes et al. (2012) that changes in risk-taking incentives do not seem to be related to changes in risk-taking. The remainder of the paper proceeds as follows. In the next section, we first define the sensitivity of firm debt, stock, and options to firm volatility, and then define the corresponding measures of manager s sensitivities to volatility. In the third section, we describe how we select a 1 While the relative measures can address the question of whether a given CEO has more incentives to reduce risk than to increase risk, they do not necessarily order risk-taking incentives across CEOs. For example, suppose that two CEOs each have relative incentives of 0.9, and are otherwise identical but one CEO has risk-reducing incentives of -$900 and has risk-increasing incentives of $1,000, while the other CEO has risk-reducing incentives of -$90,000 and has risk-increasing incentives of $100,000. The relative measure (0.9) scales away the sensitivities and suggests that both CEOs make the same risk choices, even though the second CEO benefits more from increasing risk. 5

7 sample of CEOs from 2006 to 2010, and compare various measures of incentives. In the fourth section, we examine the determinants of the incentive measures. In the fifth section, we compare regressions using the measures to explain various firm outcomes and provide robustness tests. In the sixth section, we conclude. 2. Definition of incentive measures In this section we first show how firm debt, equity, and option values change with changes in firm volatility, and then we relate these changes to measures of managerial incentives. 2.1 Sensitivity of firm capital structure to firm volatility In general, firms are financed with debt, equity, and employee options: (1) Debt is the market value of the debt, Stock is the market value of stock, and Options is the market value of options. It is convenient to express stock and option values in per share amounts, and we assume the firm has n shares of stock outstanding with stock price P. The firm has qn stock options outstanding with option price O. For simplicity in our notation, we assume for the moment that all options have the same exercise price and time to maturity and that each option is worth O. To begin, suppose that there are no stock options outstanding, so that (1) becomes: (2) Black and Scholes (1973) and Merton (1973) show that equity can be valued as a call with a strike price equal to the face value of debt. Changes in firm volatility do not change the value of the firm, so: 0 (3) 6

8 Therefore, any loss in debt value due to volatility increases is offset by an equal gain in equity value: (4) More volatile returns increase the value of equity holders call option, which reduces the value of debt. The interests of debt and equity conflict. Equity prefers higher firm volatility, which raises the value of its call; debt prefers lower firm volatility, which increases the value of its short call. Now consider a firm with no debt financed with stock and employee stock options. Employee stock options are warrants because exercising the options results in the firm issuing new shares of stock and receiving the strike price. From above: (5) Analogous to (4), an increase in firm volatility has the following effect on the stock price and the option price: (6) Equation (6) shows that the price of a share of stock in a firm with only stock and employee stock options decreases when firm volatility increases (Galai and Schneller, 1978). The share price decreases because the increased volatility makes it more likely that the option will be in the money and that the current value of a share outstanding will be diluted. This result for options on stock is similar to the result when stock is an option on the value of the levered firm. Increases in volatility do not change the value of the firm: Therefore, any gains to the options are offset by losses to the stock. Now we combine the results for debt and options. An increase in firm volatility affects debt, stock, and option value according to the following relation: 7

9 (7) In firms with both debt and options, shareholders have purchased a call on the assets, and they have sold a call on the equity to employees. They are in a position with respect to the equity similar to the position of the debt holders with respect to the assets. When the firm is levered, increasing firm volatility causes shareholders to gain from the call on the asset but to lose on the call on the equity. Since the change in stockholders value is a combination of these two opposing effects, whether stockholders prefer more volatility depends on the number of options outstanding and firm leverage, as we illustrate next Estimation of firm sensitivities To estimate the sensitivities described above, we calculate the value of debt and options using standard pricing models. We then increase firm volatility by 1%, hold firm value fixed, and recalculate the values of debt, stock, and options. We estimate the sensitivities to a one percent change in firm volatility as the difference between these values. Appendix A describes the details. We first price employee options as warrants using the Black-Scholes model, as modified to account for dividend payouts by Merton (1973), and modified to reflect warrant pricing by Schulz and Trautmann (1994). Calculating option value this way gives a value for total firm equity. Second, we model firm equity as an option on the levered firm following Merton (1974) using the Black-Scholes formula. This model allows us to calculate total firm value and firm volatility following the approach of Eberhart (2005). With these values in hand, we calculate the value of the debt as a put on the firm s assets with strike price equal to the face value of debt. To calculate the sensitivities, we increase firm volatility by 1%, which implies a 1% increase in stock volatility. We use this new firm volatility to determine a new debt value. The sensitivity of the debt to a change in firm volatility is the difference between this value and the 8

10 value at the lower firm volatility. From (7), equity increases by the magnitude of the decrease in the debt value. Finally, we use the higher equity value and higher stock volatility to compute a new value for stock and stock options following Schulz and Trautmann (1994). The difference between these stock and option values and those calculated in the first step is the sensitivity to firm volatility for the stock and options Example of firm sensitivities In Panel A of Table 1, we show an example firm with $2.5 billion market value assets and firm volatility of 35%. We use values that are approximately the mean values of our sample described below. Options are 7% of shares outstanding, and have a price-to-strike ratio of The options and the debt have a maturity of four years. Leverage is the face value of debt divided by the sum of the book value of debt and market value of equity. To calculate the values and sensitivities, we assume a risk-free rate of 2.25%, that the interest rate on debt is equal to the risk-free rate, and that the firm pays no dividends. The first set of rows shows the change in the value of firm debt, stock, and options for a 1% change in the standard deviation of the assets at various levels of leverage. An increase in volatility reduces debt value, and this reduction is greater for greater leverage. This reduction in debt value is shared between the stock and options. Options always benefit from increases in volatility. When leverage is low, the sensitivity of debt to firm volatility is very low. Since there is little debt to transfer value from, option holders gain at the expense of stockholders when volatility increases. As leverage increases, the sensitivity of debt to firm volatility increases. As this happens, the stock sensitivity becomes positive as the stock offsets losses to options with gains against the debt. 9

11 The second set of rows show the sensitivity of the debt, stock, and options as a percentage of the market value of each security. As leverage increases, the market value of the debt increases because more debt is outstanding. However, the increase in the sensitivity of the debt increases faster than the value of the debt, as shown in Column (2). The percentage stock sensitivity in Column (3) and the percentage option sensitivity in Column (4) both increase as leverage increases. 2.2 Managers incentives from the sensitivity of firm capital structure to firm volatility Total incentives to increase firm volatility We now use the above results to derive measures of managerial incentives. A manager s (risk-neutral) incentives to increase volatility from a given security are equal to the security s sensitivity to firm volatility multiplied by the fraction owned by the manager. If the manager owns α of the outstanding stock, β of the outstanding debt, and options, the manager s total incentives to increase firm volatility are: where (8) is the manager s average per option sensitivity to firm volatility, computed to reflect that employee options are warrants. (At this point, we begin to use the notation W to indicate that the option is valued as a warrant, in contrast to the notation O to indicate that the option is valued using Black-Scholes.) Vega incentives to stock volatility Prior literature uses the option vega, the sensitivity of managers option holdings to a change in stock volatility, as a proxy for incentives to increase volatility (Guay, 1999; Core and Guay, 2002; Coles et al., 2006; Hayes et al., 2012). The vega is the change in the Black-Scholes option value for a change in stock volatility: 10

12 (9) Comparing the vega with the total sensitivity in (8), one can see that the vega is a subset of total risk-taking incentives, and in particular does not include incentives from debt and stock and does not account for the fact that employee stock options are warrants. Inspection of the difference between (8) and (9) reveals that for the vega to be similar to total risk-taking incentives, the firm must have low or no leverage (so that the volatility increase causes little re-distribution from debt value to equity value) and the firm must have low amounts of options (so that the volatility increase causes little re-distribution from stock value to option value) Relative incentives to increase volatility Jensen and Meckling (1976) suggest a scaled measure of incentives: the ratio of riskreducing incentives to risk-increasing incentives. The ratio of risk-reducing to risk-taking incentives in (8) is equal to the ratio of debt incentives (multiplied by -1) to stock and option incentives: (10a) From Panel A of Table 1 above, the sensitivity of price to volatility can be negative when the firm has options but little leverage. In this case the ratio of risk-reducing to risk-taking incentives is: (10b) We term this ratio the relative sensitivity ratio. As in Jensen and Meckling, the ratio is informative about whether the manager has net incentives to increase or decrease firm risk. It can be useful to know whether risk-reducing incentives are greater than risk-increasing incentives (that is, whether Eq. (8) is negative or positive, or equivalently whether the ratio in Eq. (10) is 11

13 greater or less than one). If the ratio in Eq. (10) is less than one, then the manager has more risktaking incentives than risk-reducing incentives and vice versa if the ratio is greater than one. When the manager s portfolio of debt, stock, and options mirrors the firm s capital structure, the ratio in (10) is one. Jensen and Meckling (1976) posit that a manager with such a portfolio would have no incentives whatsoever to reallocate wealth between capital providers (p. 352) by increasing the risk of the underlying assets. If the firm has no employee options, the relative sensitivity ratio (10) becomes: (11) The first equality follows from (4):, and the sensitivity of total debt value to volatility divides off. The second equality follows from the definition of β and α as the manager s fractional holdings of debt and stock. An advantage of this ratio is that, if in fact the firm has no employee options, one does not have to estimate the sensitivity of debt to volatility to compute the ratio. Much prior literature (e.g., Anantharaman et al., 2011; Cassell et al., 2012; Sundaram and Yermack, 2007; Tung and Wang, 2011; Wang et al., 2010, 2011) uses this measure, and terms it the relative leverage ratio, as it compares the manager s leverage to the firm s leverage. Since most firms have options in their capital structure, to operationalize the relative leverage ratio, researchers make an ad hoc adjustment by adding the Black-Scholes value of the options to the value of the firm s stock and CEO s stock: (12) 12

14 Alternatively, Wei and Yermack (2011) make a different ad hoc adjustment for options by converting the options into equivalent units of stock by multiplying the options by their Black- Scholes delta : (13) These adjustments for options are not correct because the correct relative sensitivity measure shown in (10) uses the option sensitivity to firm volatility, which is quite different than the option value or the option delta. Only when the firm has no employee options are the relative leverage and incentive ratios equal to the relative sensitivity ratio. However, it is important to note that scaling away the levels information contained in (8) can lead to incorrect inference, even when calculated correctly. For example, imagine two CEOs who both have $1 million total wealth and both have a relative sensitivity ratio of 0.9. Although they are otherwise identical, CEO A has risk-reducing incentives of -$900 and has riskincreasing incentives of $1,000, while CEO B has risk-reducing incentives of -$90,000 and has risk-increasing incentives of $100,000. The relative measure (0.9) scales away the sensitivities and suggests that both CEOs make the same risk choices. However, CEO B is much more likely to take risks: his wealth increases by $10,000 (1% of wealth) for each 1% increase in firm volatility, while CEO A s increases by only $100 (0.01% of wealth) Empirical estimation of CEO sensitivities We calculate CEO sensitivities as weighted functions of the firm sensitivities. The CEO s debt and stock sensitivities are the CEO s percentage ownership of debt and stock multiplied by the firm sensitivities. We calculate the average strike price and maturity of the manager s options following Core and Guay (2002). We calculate the value of the CEO s options following Schulz 13

15 and Trautmann (1994). Appendix A.5 provides details and notes the necessary Execucomp, Compustat and CRSP variable names. Calculating the sensitivities requires a normalization for the partial derivatives. Prior literature (e.g., Guay, 1999) calculates vega using a 0.01 increase in stock volatility. The disadvantage of using a 0.01 increase in stock volatility for our calculations is that it implies an increase in firm volatility that grows smaller than 0.01 as firm leverage increases. Throughout this paper we report results using a 1% increase in firm volatility, which is equivalent to a 1% increase in stock volatility. So that the measures are directly comparable, we therefore use 1% increase in stock volatility to compute vega. The 1% vega is very highly correlated (0.93) with the 0.01 increase vega used in the prior literature, and our results with the 1% vega are very similar to results with the 0.01 increase vega Example of CEO sensitivities In Panel B of Table 1, we illustrate how incentives to take risk vary with firm leverage for an example CEO (of the example firm introduced above). The example CEO owns 2% of the firm s debt, 2% of the firm s stock, and 16% of the firm s options. These percentages are similar to the averages for our main sample described below. We assume that the value of the CEO s wealth outside the firm is 50% of the value of the CEO s debt, stock, and options. Wealth for the example CEO declines slightly with leverage. The CEO owns a slightly smaller percentage of debt than of equity, and as leverage increases his debt value increases less than his equity value decreases. The first set of rows shows the sensitivities of the CEO s debt, stock, and options to a 1% change in firm volatility for various levels of leverage. As with the firm sensitivities, the example CEO s debt sensitivity decreases monotonically with leverage, while the sensitivities of 14

16 stock and options increase monotonically with leverage. Column (5) shows the total equity sensitivity, which is the sum of the stock and option sensitivities, increases sharply as the stock sensitivity goes from being negative to positive. Column (6) shows the total sensitivity, which is the sum of the debt, stock and option sensitivities. These total risk-taking incentives increase monotonically with leverage as the decrease in the debt sensitivity is outweighed by the increase in the equity sensitivity. Column (7) shows the vega for the example CEO. In contrast to the equity sensitivity and the total sensitivity which both increase in leverage, the vega first increases and then decreases with leverage in this example. Part of the reason is that the vega does not capture the debt and stock sensitivity. Holding this aside, the vega does not measure well the sensitivity of the option to firm volatility. It captures the fact that the option price is sensitive to stock volatility, but it misses the fact that equity value benefits from decreases in debt value. As leverage increases, the sensitivity of equity value to firm volatility increases dramatically (as shown by the increasingly negative debt sensitivity), but this effect is omitted from the vega calculations. Consequently, the vega is likely to be a good approximation of the CEO s incentives to increase risk when leverage is very low, but the approximation is much noisier as leverage increases. While the level measures of the CEO s incentives are useful, they essentially assume the same amount of CEO wealth across comparisons. If, as is frequently assumed in the literature (e.g., Hall and Murphy, 2002; Lewellen, 2006; Conyon et al., 2011), CEOs have decreasing absolute risk aversion, CEOs with different levels of wealth will value incentives with the same payoffs differently. Similarly, the same level of incentives will motivate a less wealthy CEO much more than a wealthier CEO. 15

17 A direct way to generate a measure of the strength of incentives across CEOs is to scale the level of incentives by the CEO s wealth. The second set of rows show scaled incentive measures. Columns (2) through (7) show the sensitivities in the corresponding columns above as percentages of total wealth. These scaled measures show similar, but muted, relations with leverage as do the level measures. The percentages shown by the scaled measures appear small, but recall that the underlying sensitivities are for a 1% change in volatility. If the example CEO of the lowest leverage firm could increase firm volatility by (our sample standard deviation), the CEO s total wealth would increase by 2.3%. The final Columns (8) to (10) illustrate the various relative incentive measures. The relative sensitivity measure in Column (8) is calculated following Eq. (10) as the negative of the sum of debt and stock sensitivities divided by the option sensitivity when the stock sensitivity is negative (as for the three lower leverage values) and as the negative of debt sensitivity divided by the sum of the stock and option sensitivity otherwise. The risk-reducing incentives decrease from -6 to -55 as leverage increases, while the risk-increasing incentives increase more slowly from 46 to 112. Accordingly, as leverage increases, the relative sensitivity measure increases from 0.13 (= 6/46) to 0.49 (= 46/112), indicating that the CEO is more identified with debt holders (has fewer relative risk-taking incentives). This inference that risk-taking incentives decline is the opposite of the increase in risk-taking incentives shown in Column (6) for the total sensitivity and total sensitivity as a percentage of total wealth. This example illustrates the point above that scaling away the levels information contained in Eq. (8) can lead to incorrect inference even when the relative ratio is calculated correctly. In columns (9) and (10) of the final rows, we illustrate how the relative leverage and relative incentive ratios for our example CEO. The relative leverage ratio is computed by 16

18 dividing the CEO s percentage debt ownership (2%) by the CEO s ownership of total stock and option value (roughly 2.4%). Because these value ratios do not change much with leverage, the relative incentive ratio stays about 0.8, suggesting that the CEO is highly identified with debt holders. The relative incentive ratio, which has is similarly computed by dividing the CEO s percentage debt ownership (2%) by the CEO s ownership of total stock and option delta (roughly 2.8%), also shows high identification with debt holders and little change with leverage. Again, this is inconsistent with the substantial increase in risk-taking incentives illustrated in Column (6) for the total sensitivity and total sensitivity as a percentage of total wealth. Again, as noted above, these ratios only measure relative incentives correctly when the firm has little or no options, and even a correctly calculated relative-risking ratio can lead to incorrect inference. The incentive ratios are not informative about the magnitude of the sensitivity of the manager s wealth to an increase in firm volatility. 3. Sample and Variable Construction 3.1 Sample Selection We use two samples of Execucomp CEO data. Our main sample contains Execucomp CEOs from 2006 to 2010, and our secondary sample, described in more detail in Section 5.4 below contains Execucomp CEOs from 1992 to The total incentive measures described above require information on CEO inside debt (pensions and deferred compensation) and on firm options outstanding. Execucomp provides information on inside debt only beginning in 2006 (when the SEC began to require detailed disclosures). Our main sample therefore begins in The sample ends in 2010 because our tests require one-year ahead data that is only available through Following Coles et al. 17

19 (2006) and Hayes et al. (2012), we remove financial firms (firms with SIC codes between 6000 and 6999) and utility firms (firms with SIC codes between 4900 and 4999). We identify an executive as CEO if we can calculate CEO tenure from Execucomp data and if the CEO is in office at the end of the year. If the firm has more than one CEO during the year, we choose the individual with the higher total pay. We merge the Execucomp data with data from Compustat and CRSP, and the resulting sample contains 6,020 CEO-year observations that have complete data. 3.2 Descriptive statistics firm size, volatility, and leverage Table 2, Panel A shows descriptive statistics for volatility, the market value of firm debt, stock, and options, and leverage for the firms in our sample. We describe in Appendix A.3 how we estimate firm market values following Eberhart (2005). To mitigate the effect of outliers, we winsorize all variables each year at the 1 st and 99 th percentiles. Since our sample consists of S&P 1500 firms, the firms are large, with mean (median) market value of assets of $9.0 ($2.0) billion dollars. The mean (median) value of common stock is $7.1 ($1.5) billion, and the mean (median) value of debt is $1.5 ($0.3) billion. Employee stock options are a much smaller part of the capital structure with a mean (median) value of options is $118 ($29) million. A majority of firms in our sample have low leverage. The median value is 14%, although the mean in our sample is 19%. These low amounts of leverage suggest low agency costs of asset substitution for most sample firms (Jensen and Meckling, 1976). Table 2, Panel B presents sample descriptive statistics sorted by leverage in the same format as Table 1, Panel A. We rank the sample by leverage and divide it into five groups of 1,204 firm-years. Similar to Table 1, Panel A, the first set of rows shows the sensitivity of the value of firm debt, stock, and options for a 1% increase in firm volatility at various levels of 18

20 leverage. We describe in Section above and detail in Appendix A.4 how we calculate these sensitivities. The second set of rows show the sensitivity of the debt, stock, and options as a percentage of the market value of each security. Since firm size varies greatly, the percentage values are most interpretable, and we concentrate our discussion on the values in the second set of rows. Column (2) shows that as leverage increases the mean sensitivity of firm debt to firm volatility decreases. Intuitively, if the debt holders will be repaid with a very high probability, the value of their claims changes little with increases in firm volatility. The mean stock and option sensitivities in Columns (3) and (4) both increase with leverage. It is noteworthy that the stock sensitivity is negative for low levels of leverage (as increases in volatility benefit options at the expense of stock), but becomes positive for higher levels of leverage (as increases in volatility benefit both stock and options at the expense of debt). 3.3 Descriptive statistics CEO incentive measures Table 3, Panel A shows full sample descriptive statistics for the incentive measures. As discussed above in Section 2.2.4, we calculate CEO sensitivities as weighted functions of the firm sensitivities. The CEO s debt and stock sensitivities are the CEO s percentage ownership of debt and stock multiplied by the firm sensitivities. We calculate the average strike price and maturity of the manager s options following Core and Guay (2002). We calculate the value of the CEO s options following Schulz and Trautmann (1994). Appendix A.4 and A.5 provide details and notes the necessary Execucomp, Compustat and CRSP variable names. We begin by looking at the incentives provided by the CEOs debt, stock, and options. The average CEO in our sample has some incentives from debt to decrease risk, but the amount of these incentives is low. This is consistent with low leverage in the typical sample firm. In fact, 19

21 a CEO with large debt incentives (at the first quartile of the distribution) gains only $2,490 in additional wealth for a 1% decrease in firm volatility. Over half the CEOs have no debt incentives. The magnitude of the incentives from stock to increase firm risk is also small on average. However, there is substantial variation in the stock incentives, with a standard deviation of approximately $47 thousand as compared to $19 thousand for debt incentives. The average sensitivity of the CEO s options to firm volatility is an order of magnitude larger. The mean value of the total (debt, stock, and option) sensitivity is $65 thousand, which indicates that a 1% increase in firm volatility provides the average CEO in our sample with $65 thousand in additional wealth. As with the firm variables described above, we winsorize all incentive variables each year at the 1 st and 99 th percentiles. 2 The vega, calculated for a 1% increase in stock volatility rather than the 0.01 increase used in prior literature, is smaller than the total sensitivity, and has strictly positive values as compared to the total sensitivity which has about 8% negative values. To provide another comparison that abstracts away from size differences, we scale the sensitivities by CEO total wealth. We estimate CEO total wealth as the sum of the value of the CEO s debt, stock, and option portfolio and non-firm outside wealth as measured by Dittmann and Maug (2007). 3 The distributions of the scaled incentive measures are similar to those of the level measures. The average scaled total sensitivity is 0.14% of wealth. The value is low because 2 Consequently, the averages in the table do not add, i.e., the average total sensitivity is not equal the sum of the average debt sensitivity and average equity sensitivity. 3 To develop the proxy, Dittmann and Maug assume that the CEO enters the Execucomp database with no wealth, and then accumulates outside wealth from cash compensation., selling shares, and exercising options. Dittmann and Maug assume that the CEO does not consume any of his outside wealth. The only reduction in outside wealth comes from using cash to exercise his stock options and paying U.S. federal taxes. Dittmann and Maug claim that their proxy is the best available given that managers preferences for saving and consumption are unobservable. We follow Dittmann and Maug (2007) and set negative estimates of outside wealth to missing. Dittmann and Maug provide the measure on their website. For those CEOs missing the measure, we impute the fraction of equity wealth to total wealth using a generalized linear model. We use the same explanatory variables in this model as in the model for incentive determinants described in 4.1 below. 20

22 the sensitivities are calculated with respect to a 1% increase in firm volatility. If the average CEO increases firm volatility by one standard deviation (19.9%), that CEO s wealth increases by 7%. While some CEOs have net incentives to decrease risk, these incentives are a small fraction of the CEOs total wealth. For the CEO with large risk-reducing incentives (at the first percentile of the distribution), a one standard deviation decrease in firm volatility increases the CEO s wealth by 2%. The mean (median) relative leverage ratio is 3.03 (0.18), and the mean (median) relative incentive ratio is 2.29 (0.15). These values are similar to those in Cassell et al. (2012), who also use an Execucomp sample. These ratios are skewed, and are approximately one at the third quartile, suggesting that 25% of our sample CEOs have incentives to decrease risk. This fraction is much larger than the 8% of CEOs with net incentives to reduce risk based on the total sensitivity measure, and highlights the bias in the relative leverage and incentive measures. By contrast, the mean (median) relative sensitivity ratio is 0.32 (0.03), suggesting low incentives to decrease risk. To shed light on the differences between our incentive measures and those used in the prior literature, we present sample descriptive statistics sorted by leverage in Table 3, Panel B. As in Table 2, Panel B, we rank the sample by leverage and divide it into five groups of 1,204 firm-years. Similar to Table 1, Panel B, the first set of rows shows the sensitivity of the value of CEO s debt, stock, and options for a 1% increase in firm volatility at various levels of leverage. The second set of rows show the mean sensitivity of the CEO s debt, stock, and options as a percentage of the CEO s wealth. Since CEO wealth varies greatly, the percentage values are most interpretable, and we concentrate our discussion on the values in these rows. Column (2) shows that as leverage increases the mean of the CEOs debt sensitivity to firm volatility 21

23 decreases. Intuitively, the sensitivity of the firm s debt decreases in leverage, so the sensitivity of the CEO s inside debt also decreases, holding percentage ownership constant. The mean stock and option sensitivities in Columns (3) and (4) both increase with leverage. While the CEO s stock sensitivity is negative for low levels of leverage, the mean incentives from stock are very small as a fraction of wealth. When leverage is high, stock sensitivity is much larger. CEOs option sensitivity has also increases with leverage. Given the large increase is equity sensitivity shown in Column (5), the CEOs total sensitivity to firm volatility in Column (6) increases across leverage bins. By contrast, the vega in Column (7) has no relation with leverage. The vega excludes one of the two channels that affect option sensitivity to firm volatility: the stocksensitivity channel. When leverage is high, the stock price responds strongly to increases in firm volatility, changing the value of the stock options. Since the vega excludes this channel, it is biased downwards when leverage is high. The relative ratios (Columns (8) through (10)) all decrease in leverage, consistent with the increase in the total sensitivity in Column (6). The mean relative sensitivity ratio in Column (8) is below one for all of the leverage bins. This is consistent with the intuition that firms must provide risk-averse CEOs with incentives to increase risk. The relative leverage and incentive ratios are much higher than one for the two lowest leverage firm bins. According to these measures, low leverage firms choose to provide their CEO s with the most identification with debt holders. However, these are the firms that have few agency problems from debt because of their low leverage, so there is little need to provide strong identification with debt holders. This puzzling observation is a result of these ratios incorrectly weighting the sensitivity of the CEOs options to firm volatility. 22

24 Panel C of Table 3 shows correlations between the level sensitivity measures for the full sample. The total sensitivity and vega are highly correlated with each other. The Pearson (Spearman) correlation coefficient is 0.69 (0.83). The fact that the total sensitivity measure can take on negative values because it includes debt and stock sensitivities differentiates this measure from the vega measure. In addition, nearly five percent of the firms in our sample do not provide the CEO with stock options. These firms still provide their CEOs with differing levels of incentives using stock and inside debt even though all of these CEOs have a vega of zero. The total sensitivity is almost perfectly correlated with the equity sensitivity. Since debt sensitivity to firm volatility is low for most firms and CEOs percentage equity holdings are larger than their percentage debt holdings, including debt sensitivity does not provide much incremental information about CEOs incentives. The scaled measures of risk-taking incentives (total sensitivity, vega, and equity sensitivity) show similar correlations as the level measures, though scaled vega is more highly correlated with the scaled sensitivity measures than in levels. The scaled incentive measures exhibit much lower correlations with the relative measures. The relative leverage and incentive ratios, which incorrectly weight the sensitivity of CEOs options to firm volatility, show the lowest correlations with the other incentive measures, which explicitly calculate the sensitivity of stock options to volatility. The relative leverage and relative incentive ratios are almost perfectly correlated with each other. Because the correlation is so high, we do not include the relative incentive ratio in our subsequent analyses below. 4. Determinants of incentives 4.1 Research Design 23

25 Prior research focuses on: (1) what determines incentives (i.e., what types of firms use incentives more); and (2) how incentives affect firm risk choices. Coles et al. (2006) and Hayes et al. (2012) examine both of these questions, and we generally follow their research designs. Our regressions for the determinants of incentives take the following form: (14) Our control variables include the CEO s cash compensation, the CEO s age and tenure, which are intended to control for the CEO s outside wealth and risk aversion (Guay, 1999). We control for firm size using the natural logarithm of total sales, ln(sales), and for growth opportunities using Market-to-Book, R&D Expense, and CAPEX. We also control for Book Leverage, the debtto-assets ratio. We include additional variables related to the firm s and CEO s desire to defer compensation. Salary > $1 million indicates whether the CEO s salary is greater than $1 million. Section 162(m) of the Internal Revenue Service code limits the tax deductibility of nonperformance based compensation in excess of $1 million, and many firms require executives to defer compensation above this limit. Ceteris paribus, these firms will show lower cash compensation, higher equity incentives, and higher debt incentives. It will be less advantageous for executives to defer compensation when their current tax rates are lower. We proxy for low executive tax rates with an indicator for whether there is no state income tax on personal income in the state where the firm is headquartered and an indicator for whether the firm s headquarters are outside of the U.S. We also include an indicator for Liquidity Constraint if the firm generates negative cash flow from operations. By offering employees more non-cash compensation, cash-constrained firms can conserve cash. Finally, we include the stock return in years t (Return) and t-1 (Lag 24

26 Return). We also include year effects and fixed effects for industries at the 2-digit SIC level in all of the regressions. Appendix B summarizes how we measure these variables. 4.2 Determinants of incentives Table 4 presents the results of our regressions that examine the determinants of our incentive measures. Column (1) shows that the determinants of vega in our sample are similar to prior research: vega is larger for larger firms, firms with greater growth opportunities, and longer tenured CEOs. The determinants of the total sensitivity to firm volatility in Column (2) are similar with the exception that the total sensitivity is positively related to leverage, while vega is negatively related. The analysis above of Table 1 and Table 3 show that the equity sensitivity increases with leverage while the debt sensitivity decreases, and that the CEO s debt sensitivity is small relative to the equity sensitivity. Accordingly, total sensitivity increases with leverage. This result is consistent with risky firms providing incentives for CEOs to take risk. Vega, by contrast, decreases with leverage. As discussed above, scaling by wealth more directly addresses the fact that the same dollar value of incentives will motivate two CEOs differently if they have different levels of wealth. Columns (3) and (4) show that the determinants of vega and total sensitivity scaled by total wealth are different in several respects from the level measures. Most differences are intuitive: scaling by wealth removes some of the size affect from the levels measures, so the scaled measures show no relation with the size proxies Cash Compensation and ln(sales). CEO Tenure is negatively related to both of the scaled measures. The intuition is that new CEOs face greater risk that they will be a bad fit in their new positions (Gibbons and Murphy, 1992), and so need more risk-taking incentives as insurance against this fit risk. These risk-taking incentives are less important for longer serving CEOs because they have proven their ability to manage the 25

27 firm. The positive relation between tenure and the level of risk-taking incentives can be reconciled by noting that wealth grows faster with tenure (untabulated). One puzzling difference is that the scaled measures are negatively related to Market-to-Book, and one expects a positive relation between growth opportunities and risk-taking incentives per unit of wealth. However, note that the other proxy for growth opportunities, R&D Expense, is positively related to the scaled measures. Finally, we note that the return over the last two years is negatively related to both the level and scaled vega and total sensitivity. This follows from the mechanics of stock options: A positive return increases the price, and as the price increases, the stock and equity options go further in-the-money, and their sensitivities to changes in risk decrease. 4 Although not a focus of our analysis, in Columns (5) and (6) provide an analysis of the determinants of Delta and scaled delta as a comparison with our measures of risk-taking incentives. Consistent with the literature, larger firms and firms with high growth opportunities provide more incentives. Longer-serving CEOs have more incentives in the level, consistent with the idea that more explicit incentives are provided as fit concerns decline. The finding that lower incentives scaled by total wealth decline with tenure and age is puzzling, as here too one expects explicit incentives as fit concerns decline. Finally, we examine the determinants of the relative sensitivity and the relative leverage ratios in columns (7) and (8). 5 Since the ratios have a mass at 0, we estimate Tobit models. As discussed previously, these ratios do not necessarily order CEOs risk preferences as well as the 4 Although it might be desirable for firms to re-set risk-taking incentives following price changes, it is difficult for firms and managers to rebalance risk-taking incentives (Gormley, Matsa, and Milbourn, 2013). 5 As noted above, the relative leverage and incentive ratios are almost perfectly correlated, so we do not include an analysis of the relative incentive ratio. (Results for it are virtually identical to those shown for the relative leverage ratio.) 26

The Effect of Employee Stock Options on the Evolution of Compensation in the 1990s

The Effect of Employee Stock Options on the Evolution of Compensation in the 1990s Hamid Mehran and Joseph Tracy The Effect of Employee Stock Options on the Evolution of Compensation in the 1990s As the labor market tightened in 1999, the growth rate of compensation per hour (CPH) unexpectedly

More information

Paul Brockman Xiumin Martin Emre Unlu

Paul Brockman Xiumin Martin Emre Unlu Paul Brockman Xiumin Martin Emre Unlu Objective and motivation Research question and hypothesis Research design Discussion of results Conclusion The purpose of this paper is to examine the CEO s portfolio

More information

Compensation and Incentives in German Corporations

Compensation and Incentives in German Corporations University of Konstanz Department of Economics Compensation and Incentives in German Corporations Moritz Heimes and Steffen Seemann Working Paper Series 2011-20 http://www.wiwi.uni-konstanz.de/workingpaperseries

More information

How to Value Employee Stock Options

How to Value Employee Stock Options John Hull and Alan White One of the arguments often used against expensing employee stock options is that calculating their fair value at the time they are granted is very difficult. This article presents

More information

How To Find Out If A Dividend Is Negatively Associated With A Manager'S Payout

How To Find Out If A Dividend Is Negatively Associated With A Manager'S Payout Dividend Payout and Executive Compensation in US Firms Nalinaksha Bhattacharyya 1 I.H.Asper School of Business University of Manitoba 181 Freedman Crescent Winnipeg, MB R3T 5V4 Tel: (204) 474-6774 Fax:

More information

Does Executive Portfolio Structure Affect Risk Management? CEO Risktaking Incentives and Corporate Derivatives Usage

Does Executive Portfolio Structure Affect Risk Management? CEO Risktaking Incentives and Corporate Derivatives Usage Does Executive Portfolio Structure Affect Risk Management? CEO Risktaking Incentives and Corporate Derivatives Usage Daniel A. Rogers a a School of Business Administration, Portland State University, Portland,

More information

Empirical Evidence on the Relation Between Stock Option Compensation and Risk Taking

Empirical Evidence on the Relation Between Stock Option Compensation and Risk Taking Empirical Evidence on the Relation Between Stock Option Compensation and Risk Taking Shivaram Rajgopal Assistant Professor Department of Accounting University of Washington Box 353200 Seattle, WA 98195

More information

DETERMINING THE VALUE OF EMPLOYEE STOCK OPTIONS. Report Produced for the Ontario Teachers Pension Plan John Hull and Alan White August 2002

DETERMINING THE VALUE OF EMPLOYEE STOCK OPTIONS. Report Produced for the Ontario Teachers Pension Plan John Hull and Alan White August 2002 DETERMINING THE VALUE OF EMPLOYEE STOCK OPTIONS 1. Background Report Produced for the Ontario Teachers Pension Plan John Hull and Alan White August 2002 It is now becoming increasingly accepted that companies

More information

The Determinants and the Value of Cash Holdings: Evidence. from French firms

The Determinants and the Value of Cash Holdings: Evidence. from French firms The Determinants and the Value of Cash Holdings: Evidence from French firms Khaoula SADDOUR Cahier de recherche n 2006-6 Abstract: This paper investigates the determinants of the cash holdings of French

More information

A Primer on Valuing Common Stock per IRS 409A and the Impact of Topic 820 (Formerly FAS 157)

A Primer on Valuing Common Stock per IRS 409A and the Impact of Topic 820 (Formerly FAS 157) A Primer on Valuing Common Stock per IRS 409A and the Impact of Topic 820 (Formerly FAS 157) By Stanley Jay Feldman, Ph.D. Chairman and Chief Valuation Officer Axiom Valuation Solutions May 2010 201 Edgewater

More information

GAMMA.0279 THETA 8.9173 VEGA 9.9144 RHO 3.5985

GAMMA.0279 THETA 8.9173 VEGA 9.9144 RHO 3.5985 14 Option Sensitivities and Option Hedging Answers to Questions and Problems 1. Consider Call A, with: X $70; r 0.06; T t 90 days; 0.4; and S $60. Compute the price, DELTA, GAMMA, THETA, VEGA, and RHO

More information

Options: Valuation and (No) Arbitrage

Options: Valuation and (No) Arbitrage Prof. Alex Shapiro Lecture Notes 15 Options: Valuation and (No) Arbitrage I. Readings and Suggested Practice Problems II. Introduction: Objectives and Notation III. No Arbitrage Pricing Bound IV. The Binomial

More information

Stock option plans for non-executive employees $

Stock option plans for non-executive employees $ Journal of Financial Economics 61 (2001) 253 287 Stock option plans for non-executive employees $ John E. Core, Wayne R. Guay* The Wharton School, 2400 Steinberg-Dietrich Hall, University of Pennsylvania,

More information

{What s it worth?} in privately owned companies. Valuation of equity compensation. Restricted Stock, Stock Options, Phantom Shares, and

{What s it worth?} in privately owned companies. Valuation of equity compensation. Restricted Stock, Stock Options, Phantom Shares, and plantemoran.com {What s it worth?} Valuation of equity compensation in privately owned companies Restricted Stock, Stock Options, Phantom Shares, and Other Forms of Equity Compensation The valuation of

More information

How To Calculate Financial Leverage Ratio

How To Calculate Financial Leverage Ratio What Do Short-Term Liquidity Ratios Measure? What Is Working Capital? HOCK international - 2004 1 HOCK international - 2004 2 How Is the Current Ratio Calculated? How Is the Quick Ratio Calculated? HOCK

More information

READING 11: TAXES AND PRIVATE WEALTH MANAGEMENT IN A GLOBAL CONTEXT

READING 11: TAXES AND PRIVATE WEALTH MANAGEMENT IN A GLOBAL CONTEXT READING 11: TAXES AND PRIVATE WEALTH MANAGEMENT IN A GLOBAL CONTEXT Introduction Taxes have a significant impact on net performance and affect an adviser s understanding of risk for the taxable investor.

More information

The Economic Dilution of Employee Stock Options: Diluted EPS for Valuation and Financial Reporting

The Economic Dilution of Employee Stock Options: Diluted EPS for Valuation and Financial Reporting The Economic Dilution of Employee Stock ptions: Diluted EPS for Valuation and Financial Reporting John Core, The Wharton School University of Pennsylvania 2400 Steinberg-Dietrich Hall Philadelphia, PA

More information

Extending Factor Models of Equity Risk to Credit Risk and Default Correlation. Dan dibartolomeo Northfield Information Services September 2010

Extending Factor Models of Equity Risk to Credit Risk and Default Correlation. Dan dibartolomeo Northfield Information Services September 2010 Extending Factor Models of Equity Risk to Credit Risk and Default Correlation Dan dibartolomeo Northfield Information Services September 2010 Goals for this Presentation Illustrate how equity factor risk

More information

Autoria: Eduardo Kazuo Kayo, Douglas Dias Bastos

Autoria: Eduardo Kazuo Kayo, Douglas Dias Bastos Frequent Acquirers and Financing Policy: The Effect of the 2000 Bubble Burst Autoria: Eduardo Kazuo Kayo, Douglas Dias Bastos Abstract We analyze the effect of the 2000 bubble burst on the financing policy.

More information

CHAPTER 20. Hybrid Financing: Preferred Stock, Warrants, and Convertibles

CHAPTER 20. Hybrid Financing: Preferred Stock, Warrants, and Convertibles CHAPTER 20 Hybrid Financing: Preferred Stock, Warrants, and Convertibles 1 Topics in Chapter Types of hybrid securities Preferred stock Warrants Convertibles Features and risk Cost of capital to issuers

More information

DIVIDEND PAYOUT AND EXECUTIVE COMPENSATION: THEORY AND EVIDENCE. Nalinaksha Bhattacharyya 1 University of Manitoba. Amin Mawani York University

DIVIDEND PAYOUT AND EXECUTIVE COMPENSATION: THEORY AND EVIDENCE. Nalinaksha Bhattacharyya 1 University of Manitoba. Amin Mawani York University DIVIDEND PAYOUT AND EXECUTIVE COMPENSATION: THEORY AND EVIDENCE Nalinaksha Bhattacharyya 1 University of Manitoba Amin Mawani York University Cameron Morrill University of Manitoba May 2003 ABSTRACT Bhattacharyya

More information

Internet Appendix to Target Behavior and Financing: How Conclusive is the Evidence? * Table IA.I Summary Statistics (Actual Data)

Internet Appendix to Target Behavior and Financing: How Conclusive is the Evidence? * Table IA.I Summary Statistics (Actual Data) Internet Appendix to Target Behavior and Financing: How Conclusive is the Evidence? * Table IA.I Summary Statistics (Actual Data) Actual data are collected from Industrial Compustat and CRSP for the years

More information

Chapter 5 Option Strategies

Chapter 5 Option Strategies Chapter 5 Option Strategies Chapter 4 was concerned with the basic terminology and properties of options. This chapter discusses categorizing and analyzing investment positions constructed by meshing puts

More information

Option pricing. Vinod Kothari

Option pricing. Vinod Kothari Option pricing Vinod Kothari Notation we use this Chapter will be as follows: S o : Price of the share at time 0 S T : Price of the share at time T T : time to maturity of the option r : risk free rate

More information

Employee Options, Restricted Stock and Value. Aswath Damodaran 1

Employee Options, Restricted Stock and Value. Aswath Damodaran 1 Employee Options, Restricted Stock and Value 1 Basic Proposition on Options Any options issued by a firm, whether to management or employees or to investors (convertibles and warrants) create claims on

More information

Incentive Features in CEO Compensation in the Banking Industry

Incentive Features in CEO Compensation in the Banking Industry Kose John and Yiming Qian Incentive Features in CEO Compensation in the Banking Industry T 1. Introduction he topic of corporate governance in general, and topmanagement compensation in particular, has

More information

Call Price as a Function of the Stock Price

Call Price as a Function of the Stock Price Call Price as a Function of the Stock Price Intuitively, the call price should be an increasing function of the stock price. This relationship allows one to develop a theory of option pricing, derived

More information

Hedging Illiquid FX Options: An Empirical Analysis of Alternative Hedging Strategies

Hedging Illiquid FX Options: An Empirical Analysis of Alternative Hedging Strategies Hedging Illiquid FX Options: An Empirical Analysis of Alternative Hedging Strategies Drazen Pesjak Supervised by A.A. Tsvetkov 1, D. Posthuma 2 and S.A. Borovkova 3 MSc. Thesis Finance HONOURS TRACK Quantitative

More information

Understanding Financial Management: A Practical Guide Guideline Answers to the Concept Check Questions

Understanding Financial Management: A Practical Guide Guideline Answers to the Concept Check Questions Understanding Financial Management: A Practical Guide Guideline Answers to the Concept Check Questions Chapter 8 Capital Budgeting Concept Check 8.1 1. What is the difference between independent and mutually

More information

1 Pricing options using the Black Scholes formula

1 Pricing options using the Black Scholes formula Lecture 9 Pricing options using the Black Scholes formula Exercise. Consider month options with exercise prices of K = 45. The variance of the underlying security is σ 2 = 0.20. The risk free interest

More information

Chapter 11 Options. Main Issues. Introduction to Options. Use of Options. Properties of Option Prices. Valuation Models of Options.

Chapter 11 Options. Main Issues. Introduction to Options. Use of Options. Properties of Option Prices. Valuation Models of Options. Chapter 11 Options Road Map Part A Introduction to finance. Part B Valuation of assets, given discount rates. Part C Determination of risk-adjusted discount rate. Part D Introduction to derivatives. Forwards

More information

Employee stock option grants grew dramatically in the

Employee stock option grants grew dramatically in the Hedging Employee Stock Options, Taxes, and Debt Hedging Employee Stock Options, Corporate Taxes, and Debt Abstract - This study explores two effects of employee stock options on tax incentives to issue

More information

Valuing Stock Options For Divorce and Estate Planning

Valuing Stock Options For Divorce and Estate Planning REPRINTED FROM THE APRIL 2001 ISSUE Valuing Stock Options For Divorce and Estate Planning by: Michael A. Paschall, ASA, CFA, JD Husband to family law attorney: My ex-wife has stock options in a public

More information

A Primer on Valuing Common Stock per IRS 409A and the Impact of FAS 157

A Primer on Valuing Common Stock per IRS 409A and the Impact of FAS 157 A Primer on Valuing Common Stock per IRS 409A and the Impact of FAS 157 By Stanley Jay Feldman, Ph.D. Chairman and Chief Valuation Officer Axiom Valuation Solutions 201 Edgewater Drive, Suite 255 Wakefield,

More information

CHAPTER 22 Options and Corporate Finance

CHAPTER 22 Options and Corporate Finance CHAPTER 22 Options and Corporate Finance Multiple Choice Questions: I. DEFINITIONS OPTIONS a 1. A financial contract that gives its owner the right, but not the obligation, to buy or sell a specified asset

More information

In the wake of the recent financial crisis, U.S.

In the wake of the recent financial crisis, U.S. 2010 Core and Guay 1 E X C H A N G E Is CEO Pay Too High and Are Too Low? A Wealth-Based Contracting Framework by John E. Core and Wayne R. Guay Executive Overview In the wake of the recent financial crisis,

More information

Evidence on the Contracting Explanation of Conservatism

Evidence on the Contracting Explanation of Conservatism Evidence on the Contracting Explanation of Conservatism Ryan Blunck PhD Student University of Iowa Sonja Rego Lloyd J. and Thelma W. Palmer Research Fellow University of Iowa November 5, 2007 Abstract

More information

RESP Investment Strategies

RESP Investment Strategies RESP Investment Strategies Registered Education Savings Plans (RESP): Must Try Harder Graham Westmacott CFA Portfolio Manager PWL CAPITAL INC. Waterloo, Ontario August 2014 This report was written by Graham

More information

Finance and Economics Discussion Series Divisions of Research & Statistics and Monetary Affairs Federal Reserve Board, Washington, D.C.

Finance and Economics Discussion Series Divisions of Research & Statistics and Monetary Affairs Federal Reserve Board, Washington, D.C. Finance and Economics Discussion Series Divisions of Research & Statistics and Monetary Affairs Federal Reserve Board, Washington, D.C. Dividend Taxes and Stock Volatility Erin E. Syron Ferris 2015-036

More information

Inside Debt and Corporate Investment

Inside Debt and Corporate Investment Inside Debt and Corporate Investment Joonil Lee Kyung Hee University Kevin J. Murphy University of Southern California Peter SH. Oh University of Southern California Marshall Vance University of Southern

More information

Options Pricing. This is sometimes referred to as the intrinsic value of the option.

Options Pricing. This is sometimes referred to as the intrinsic value of the option. Options Pricing We will use the example of a call option in discussing the pricing issue. Later, we will turn our attention to the Put-Call Parity Relationship. I. Preliminary Material Recall the payoff

More information

Distribution of Household Wealth in the U.S.: 2000 to 2011

Distribution of Household Wealth in the U.S.: 2000 to 2011 Distribution of Household Wealth in the U.S.: By Marina Vornovitsky, Alfred Gottschalck, and Adam Smith Household net worth, or wealth, is an important indicar of economic well-being in the United States.

More information

Derivative Users Traders of derivatives can be categorized as hedgers, speculators, or arbitrageurs.

Derivative Users Traders of derivatives can be categorized as hedgers, speculators, or arbitrageurs. OPTIONS THEORY Introduction The Financial Manager must be knowledgeable about derivatives in order to manage the price risk inherent in financial transactions. Price risk refers to the possibility of loss

More information

Financial Statement Analysis of Leverage and How It Informs About Profitability and Price-to-Book Ratios

Financial Statement Analysis of Leverage and How It Informs About Profitability and Price-to-Book Ratios Financial Statement Analysis of Leverage and How It Informs About Profitability and Price-to-Book Ratios Doron Nissim Graduate School of Business Columbia University 3022 Broadway, Uris Hall 604 New York,

More information

The Relation between Accruals and Uncertainty. Salman Arif arifs@indiana.edu. Nathan Marshall nathmars@indiana.edu

The Relation between Accruals and Uncertainty. Salman Arif arifs@indiana.edu. Nathan Marshall nathmars@indiana.edu The Relation between Accruals and Uncertainty Salman Arif arifs@indiana.edu Nathan Marshall nathmars@indiana.edu Teri Lombardi Yohn tyohn@indiana.edu 1309 E 10 th Street Kelley School of Business Indiana

More information

MEDDELANDEN FRÅN SVENSKA HANDELSHÖGSKOLAN SWEDISH SCHOOL OF ECONOMICS AND BUSINESS ADMINISTRATION WORKING PAPERS. Daniel Pasternack & Matts Rosenberg

MEDDELANDEN FRÅN SVENSKA HANDELSHÖGSKOLAN SWEDISH SCHOOL OF ECONOMICS AND BUSINESS ADMINISTRATION WORKING PAPERS. Daniel Pasternack & Matts Rosenberg MEDDELANDEN FRÅN SVENSKA HANDELSHÖGSKOLAN SWEDISH SCHOOL OF ECONOMICS AND BUSINESS ADMINISTRATION WORKING PAPERS 476 Daniel Pasternack & Matts Rosenberg THE IMPACT OF STOCK OPTION INCENTIVES ON INVESTMENT

More information

A Comparison of CEO Pay in Public and Private US Firms *

A Comparison of CEO Pay in Public and Private US Firms * A Comparison of CEO Pay in Public and Private US Firms * Huasheng Gao Nanyang Business School Nanyang Technological University S3-B1A-06, 50 Nanyang Avenue, Singapore 639798 65.6790.4653 hsgao@ntu.edu.sg

More information

How Dilution Affects Option Value

How Dilution Affects Option Value How Dilution Affects Option Value If you buy a call option on an options exchange and then exercise it, you have no effect on the number of outstanding shares. The investor who sold the call simply hands

More information

Understanding Leverage in Closed-End Funds

Understanding Leverage in Closed-End Funds Closed-End Funds Understanding Leverage in Closed-End Funds The concept of leverage seems simple: borrowing money at a low cost and using it to seek higher returns on an investment. Leverage as it applies

More information

Stock Option Compensation Incentives and R&D Investment Returns

Stock Option Compensation Incentives and R&D Investment Returns Stock Option Compensation Incentives and R&D Investment Returns Bruce K. Billings Florida State University James R. Moon, Jr. Georgia State University Richard M. Morton Florida State University Dana M.

More information

Are Consultants to Blame for High CEO Pay?

Are Consultants to Blame for High CEO Pay? Preliminary Draft Please Do Not Circulate Are Consultants to Blame for High CEO Pay? Kevin J. Murphy Marshall School of Business University of Southern California Los Angeles, CA 90089-0804 E-mail: kjmurphy@usc.edu

More information

Valuation Effects of Debt and Equity Offerings. by Real Estate Investment Trusts (REITs)

Valuation Effects of Debt and Equity Offerings. by Real Estate Investment Trusts (REITs) Valuation Effects of Debt and Equity Offerings by Real Estate Investment Trusts (REITs) Jennifer Francis (Duke University) Thomas Lys (Northwestern University) Linda Vincent (Northwestern University) This

More information

How To Make Money From A Bank Loan

How To Make Money From A Bank Loan NEWS RELEASE FOR FURTHER INFORMATION: WEBSITE: www.bnccorp.com TIMOTHY J. FRANZ, CEO TELEPHONE: (612) 305-2213 DANIEL COLLINS, CFO TELEPHONE: (612) 305-2210 BNCCORP, INC. REPORTS THIRD QUARTER NET INCOME

More information

READING 14: LIFETIME FINANCIAL ADVICE: HUMAN CAPITAL, ASSET ALLOCATION, AND INSURANCE

READING 14: LIFETIME FINANCIAL ADVICE: HUMAN CAPITAL, ASSET ALLOCATION, AND INSURANCE READING 14: LIFETIME FINANCIAL ADVICE: HUMAN CAPITAL, ASSET ALLOCATION, AND INSURANCE Introduction (optional) The education and skills that we build over this first stage of our lives not only determine

More information

TPPE17 Corporate Finance 1(5) SOLUTIONS RE-EXAMS 2014 II + III

TPPE17 Corporate Finance 1(5) SOLUTIONS RE-EXAMS 2014 II + III TPPE17 Corporate Finance 1(5) SOLUTIONS RE-EXAMS 2014 II III Instructions 1. Only one problem should be treated on each sheet of paper and only one side of the sheet should be used. 2. The solutions folder

More information

Lecture Notes: Basic Concepts in Option Pricing - The Black and Scholes Model

Lecture Notes: Basic Concepts in Option Pricing - The Black and Scholes Model Brunel University Msc., EC5504, Financial Engineering Prof Menelaos Karanasos Lecture Notes: Basic Concepts in Option Pricing - The Black and Scholes Model Recall that the price of an option is equal to

More information

General Forex Glossary

General Forex Glossary General Forex Glossary A ADR American Depository Receipt Arbitrage The simultaneous buying and selling of a security at two different prices in two different markets, with the aim of creating profits without

More information

DUKE UNIVERSITY Fuqua School of Business. FINANCE 351 - CORPORATE FINANCE Problem Set #7 Prof. Simon Gervais Fall 2011 Term 2.

DUKE UNIVERSITY Fuqua School of Business. FINANCE 351 - CORPORATE FINANCE Problem Set #7 Prof. Simon Gervais Fall 2011 Term 2. DUKE UNIVERSITY Fuqua School of Business FINANCE 351 - CORPORATE FINANCE Problem Set #7 Prof. Simon Gervais Fall 2011 Term 2 Questions 1. Suppose the corporate tax rate is 40%, and investors pay a tax

More information

A Piece of the Pie: Alternative Approaches to Allocating Value

A Piece of the Pie: Alternative Approaches to Allocating Value A Piece of the Pie: Alternative Approaches to Allocating Value Cory Thompson, CFA, CIRA cthompson@srr.com Ryan Gandre, CFA rgandre@srr.com Introduction Enterprise value ( EV ) represents the sum of debt

More information

The Term Structure of Interest Rates, Spot Rates, and Yield to Maturity

The Term Structure of Interest Rates, Spot Rates, and Yield to Maturity Chapter 5 How to Value Bonds and Stocks 5A-1 Appendix 5A The Term Structure of Interest Rates, Spot Rates, and Yield to Maturity In the main body of this chapter, we have assumed that the interest rate

More information

The Discount Rate: A Note on IAS 36

The Discount Rate: A Note on IAS 36 The Discount Rate: A Note on IAS 36 Sven Husmann Martin Schmidt Thorsten Seidel European University Viadrina Frankfurt (Oder) Department of Business Administration and Economics Discussion Paper No. 246

More information

1 Introduction to Option Pricing

1 Introduction to Option Pricing ESTM 60202: Financial Mathematics Alex Himonas 03 Lecture Notes 1 October 7, 2009 1 Introduction to Option Pricing We begin by defining the needed finance terms. Stock is a certificate of ownership of

More information

What Determines Early Exercise of Employee Stock Options?

What Determines Early Exercise of Employee Stock Options? What Determines Early Exercise of Employee Stock Options? Summary Report of Honours Research Project Tristan Boyd Supervised by Professor Philip Brown and Dr Alex Szimayer University of Western Australia

More information

CEO Incentives and Payout Policy: Empirical Evidence. from Europe

CEO Incentives and Payout Policy: Empirical Evidence. from Europe CEO Incentives and Payout Policy: Empirical Evidence from Europe Amedeo De Cesari Aston Business School Neslihan Ozkan University of Bristol January 15th, 2013 Abstract: We investigate how corporate payout

More information

Do stock options overcome managerial risk aversion? Evidence from option exercises

Do stock options overcome managerial risk aversion? Evidence from option exercises Do stock options overcome managerial risk aversion? Evidence from option exercises Randall A. Heron Kelley School of Business Indiana University Indianapolis, IN 46202 Tel: 317-274-4984 Email: rheron@iupui.edu

More information

DO EXECUTIVE STOCK OPTIONS ENCOURAGE RISK-TAKING?

DO EXECUTIVE STOCK OPTIONS ENCOURAGE RISK-TAKING? First draft: October 1999 This draft: March 2000 Preliminary Comments welcome. Please do not circulate DO EXECUTIVE STOCK OPTIONS ENCOURAGE RISK-TAKING? Randolph B. Cohen, Brian J. Hall and Luis M. Viceira

More information

CHAPTER 21: OPTION VALUATION

CHAPTER 21: OPTION VALUATION CHAPTER 21: OPTION VALUATION 1. Put values also must increase as the volatility of the underlying stock increases. We see this from the parity relation as follows: P = C + PV(X) S 0 + PV(Dividends). Given

More information

Introduction to Options. Derivatives

Introduction to Options. Derivatives Introduction to Options Econ 422: Investment, Capital & Finance University of Washington Summer 2010 August 18, 2010 Derivatives A derivative is a security whose payoff or value depends on (is derived

More information

Valuing Stock Appreciation Rights (SARs) in ESOP Sponsor Companies

Valuing Stock Appreciation Rights (SARs) in ESOP Sponsor Companies ESOP Valuation Insights Valuing Stock Appreciation Rights (SARs) in ESOP Sponsor Companies Steve Whittington Stock appreciation rights (SARs) are used in conjunction with ESOP stock purchase transactions

More information

NOTES ON THE BANK OF ENGLAND OPTION-IMPLIED PROBABILITY DENSITY FUNCTIONS

NOTES ON THE BANK OF ENGLAND OPTION-IMPLIED PROBABILITY DENSITY FUNCTIONS 1 NOTES ON THE BANK OF ENGLAND OPTION-IMPLIED PROBABILITY DENSITY FUNCTIONS Options are contracts used to insure against or speculate/take a view on uncertainty about the future prices of a wide range

More information

CHAPTER 11 Solutions STOCKHOLDERS EQUITY

CHAPTER 11 Solutions STOCKHOLDERS EQUITY CHAPTER 11 Solutions STOCKHOLDERS EQUITY Chapter 11, SE 1. 1. c 4. 2. a 5. 3. b 6. d e a Chapter 11, SE 2. 1. Advantage 4. 2. Disadvantage 5. 3. Advantage 6. Advantage Disadvantage Advantage Chapter 11,

More information

The Cost of Capital and Optimal Financing Policy in a. Dynamic Setting

The Cost of Capital and Optimal Financing Policy in a. Dynamic Setting The Cost of Capital and Optimal Financing Policy in a Dynamic Setting February 18, 2014 Abstract This paper revisits the Modigliani-Miller propositions on the optimal financing policy and cost of capital

More information

t = 1 2 3 1. Calculate the implied interest rates and graph the term structure of interest rates. t = 1 2 3 X t = 100 100 100 t = 1 2 3

t = 1 2 3 1. Calculate the implied interest rates and graph the term structure of interest rates. t = 1 2 3 X t = 100 100 100 t = 1 2 3 MØA 155 PROBLEM SET: Summarizing Exercise 1. Present Value [3] You are given the following prices P t today for receiving risk free payments t periods from now. t = 1 2 3 P t = 0.95 0.9 0.85 1. Calculate

More information

The Empire Life Insurance Company

The Empire Life Insurance Company The Empire Life Insurance Company Condensed Interim Consolidated Financial Statements For the six months ended June 30, 2015 Unaudited Issue Date: August 7, 2015 DRAFT NOTICE OF NO AUDITOR REVIEW OF CONDENSED

More information

Corporate governance, chief executive officer compensation, and firm performance

Corporate governance, chief executive officer compensation, and firm performance Journal of Financial Economics 51 (1999) 371 406 Corporate governance, chief executive officer compensation, and firm performance John E. Core, Robert W. Holthausen*, David F. Larcker 2400 Steinberg-Dietrich

More information

Employee Stock Options, Financing Constraints, and Real Investment

Employee Stock Options, Financing Constraints, and Real Investment Employee Stock Options, Financing Constraints, and Real Investment Ilona Babenko Michael Lemmon Yuri Tserlukevich Hong Kong University of Science and Technology and University of Utah March 2009 Our goals

More information

Finance 2 for IBA (30J201) F. Feriozzi Re-sit exam June 18 th, 2012. Part One: Multiple-Choice Questions (45 points)

Finance 2 for IBA (30J201) F. Feriozzi Re-sit exam June 18 th, 2012. Part One: Multiple-Choice Questions (45 points) Finance 2 for IBA (30J201) F. Feriozzi Re-sit exam June 18 th, 2012 Part One: Multiple-Choice Questions (45 points) Question 1 Assume that capital markets are perfect. Which of the following statements

More information

Chapter 1 The Scope of Corporate Finance

Chapter 1 The Scope of Corporate Finance Chapter 1 The Scope of Corporate Finance MULTIPLE CHOICE 1. One of the tasks for financial managers when identifying projects that increase firm value is to identify those projects where a. marginal benefits

More information

A Note on Stock Options and Corporate Valuation

A Note on Stock Options and Corporate Valuation A Note on Stock Options and Corporate Valuation Bernhard Schwetzler * Many listed companies offer stock option plans (SOP) to their managers as part of a performance-based compensation package. For financial

More information

Cap Tables Explained

Cap Tables Explained Cap Tables Explained Introduction Capitalization tables ( cap tables ) are used to record and track ownership in a company. If you are a sole proprietor, then it is not necessary to use a cap table you

More information

Sensex Realized Volatility Index

Sensex Realized Volatility Index Sensex Realized Volatility Index Introduction: Volatility modelling has traditionally relied on complex econometric procedures in order to accommodate the inherent latent character of volatility. Realized

More information

Stock Prices and Institutional Holdings. Adri De Ridder Gotland University, SE-621 67 Visby, Sweden

Stock Prices and Institutional Holdings. Adri De Ridder Gotland University, SE-621 67 Visby, Sweden Stock Prices and Institutional Holdings Adri De Ridder Gotland University, SE-621 67 Visby, Sweden This version: May 2008 JEL Classification: G14, G32 Keywords: Stock Price Levels, Ownership structure,

More information

Valuation of Razorback Executive Stock Options: A Simulation Approach

Valuation of Razorback Executive Stock Options: A Simulation Approach Valuation of Razorback Executive Stock Options: A Simulation Approach Joe Cheung Charles J. Corrado Department of Accounting & Finance The University of Auckland Private Bag 92019 Auckland, New Zealand.

More information

The Effect of Housing on Portfolio Choice. July 2009

The Effect of Housing on Portfolio Choice. July 2009 The Effect of Housing on Portfolio Choice Raj Chetty Harvard Univ. Adam Szeidl UC-Berkeley July 2009 Introduction How does homeownership affect financial portfolios? Linkages between housing and financial

More information

Fundamentals Level Skills Module, Paper F9

Fundamentals Level Skills Module, Paper F9 Answers Fundamentals Level Skills Module, Paper F9 Financial Management June 2008 Answers 1 (a) Calculation of weighted average cost of capital (WACC) Cost of equity Cost of equity using capital asset

More information

An Empirical Analysis of the Tax Benefit from Employee Stock Options. Tippie College of Business, University of Iowa, Iowa City, IA 52242

An Empirical Analysis of the Tax Benefit from Employee Stock Options. Tippie College of Business, University of Iowa, Iowa City, IA 52242 An Empirical Analysis of the Tax Benefit from Employee Stock Options Michael Cipriano a, Daniel W. Collins a, Paul Hribar* b a Tippie College of Business, University of Iowa, Iowa City, IA 52242 b Johnson

More information

Volatility as an indicator of Supply and Demand for the Option. the price of a stock expressed as a decimal or percentage.

Volatility as an indicator of Supply and Demand for the Option. the price of a stock expressed as a decimal or percentage. Option Greeks - Evaluating Option Price Sensitivity to: Price Changes to the Stock Time to Expiration Alterations in Interest Rates Volatility as an indicator of Supply and Demand for the Option Different

More information

2. A very brief history of valuation questions

2. A very brief history of valuation questions EMPLOYEE STOCK OPTIONS GRAEME WEST, RISKWORX & FINANCIAL MODELLING AGENCY 1. What are employee stock options? Employee or executive stock options (ESOs for short) are call options granted by a company

More information

Financial Statement and Cash Flow Analysis

Financial Statement and Cash Flow Analysis Chapter 2 Financial Statement and Cash Flow Analysis Answers to Concept Review Questions 1. What role do the FASB and SEC play with regard to GAAP? The FASB is a nongovernmental, professional standards

More information

B.3. Robustness: alternative betas estimation

B.3. Robustness: alternative betas estimation Appendix B. Additional empirical results and robustness tests This Appendix contains additional empirical results and robustness tests. B.1. Sharpe ratios of beta-sorted portfolios Fig. B1 plots the Sharpe

More information

WHITE PAPER. Using SERPs to Create a Balanced Executive Compensation Plan. By Peter Lupo and Bruce Brownell

WHITE PAPER. Using SERPs to Create a Balanced Executive Compensation Plan. By Peter Lupo and Bruce Brownell WHITE PAPER Using SERPs to Create a Balanced Executive Compensation Plan By Peter Lupo and Bruce Brownell USING SERPS TO CREATE A BALANCED Executive Compensation Program Peter Lupo and Bruce Brownell RISKS

More information

Edinburgh Research Explorer

Edinburgh Research Explorer Edinburgh Research Explorer CEO Inside Debt Holdings and Risk-shifting: Evidence from Bank Payout Policies Citation for published version: Srivastav, A, Armitage, S & Hagendorff, J 2014, 'CEO Inside Debt

More information

Internet Appendix to. Why does the Option to Stock Volume Ratio Predict Stock Returns? Li Ge, Tse-Chun Lin, and Neil D. Pearson.

Internet Appendix to. Why does the Option to Stock Volume Ratio Predict Stock Returns? Li Ge, Tse-Chun Lin, and Neil D. Pearson. Internet Appendix to Why does the Option to Stock Volume Ratio Predict Stock Returns? Li Ge, Tse-Chun Lin, and Neil D. Pearson August 9, 2015 This Internet Appendix provides additional empirical results

More information

Employee Stock Options: Much More Valuable Than You Thought

Employee Stock Options: Much More Valuable Than You Thought Employee Stock Options: Much More Valuable Than You Thought by James E. Hodder and Jens Carsten Jackwerth February 28, 2005 James Hodder is from the University of Wisconsin-Madison, Finance Department,

More information

C(t) (1 + y) 4. t=1. For the 4 year bond considered above, assume that the price today is 900$. The yield to maturity will then be the y that solves

C(t) (1 + y) 4. t=1. For the 4 year bond considered above, assume that the price today is 900$. The yield to maturity will then be the y that solves Economics 7344, Spring 2013 Bent E. Sørensen INTEREST RATE THEORY We will cover fixed income securities. The major categories of long-term fixed income securities are federal government bonds, corporate

More information

Understanding Cash Flow Statements

Understanding Cash Flow Statements Understanding Cash Flow Statements 2014 Level I Financial Reporting and Analysis IFT Notes for the CFA exam Contents 1. Introduction... 3 2. Components and Format of the Cash Flow Statement... 3 3. The

More information

Financial Impacts from Farmland Value Declines by Various Farm Ownership Levels (AEC 2013-05)

Financial Impacts from Farmland Value Declines by Various Farm Ownership Levels (AEC 2013-05) Financial Impacts from Value Declines by Various Farm Ownership Levels (AEC 2013-05) By Cory Walters and John Barnhart 1 Long-term farm financial strength stemming from investment decisions is a primary

More information

Answers to Concepts in Review

Answers to Concepts in Review Answers to Concepts in Review 1. Puts and calls are negotiable options issued in bearer form that allow the holder to sell (put) or buy (call) a stipulated amount of a specific security/financial asset,

More information