INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY RIGHTS AS STRATEGIC ASSETS: THE CASE OF EUROPEAN PATENT OPPOSITION

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY RIGHTS AS STRATEGIC ASSETS: THE CASE OF EUROPEAN PATENT OPPOSITION"

Transcription

1 CESPRI Centro di Ricerca sui Processi di Innovazione e Internazionalizzazione Università Commerciale Luigi Bocconi Via R. Sarfatti, Milano Tel /7 fax Mario Calderini*, Giuseppe Scellato** INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY RIGHTS AS STRATEGIC ASSETS: THE CASE OF EUROPEAN PATENT OPPOSITION IN THE TELECOMMUNICATION INDUSTRY WP n. 158 July 2004 Stampato in proprio da: Università Commerciale Luigi Bocconi CESPRI Via Sarfatti, Milano Anno: 2004 * Politecnico di Torino, mario.calderini@polito.it tel ** Politecnico di Torino and Università degli Studi di Torino, giuseppe.scellato@polito.it tel

2 INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY RIGHTS AS STRATEGIC ASSETS: THE CASE OF EUROPEAN PATENT OPPOSITION IN THE TELECOMMUNICATION INDUSTRY Mario Calderini, Giuseppe Scellato Abstract The paper empirically investigates the phenomenon of patent litigation through the analysis of the all population of European patents opposition cases in the telecommunication industry. We recover the complete legal history of each dispute and the patent portfolios of the firms involved. We suggest that in an industry characterised by strong technological complementarities the distribution of patent rights may induce situations of mutual hold-up among innovators. The risk of retaliation through countersuits represents a credible threat that can eventually favour the instauration of collusive behaviours. Our results confirm this hypothesis, since the occurrence of patent oppositions among large incumbents is significantly lower than industry average. JEL CLASSIFICATION: K41, O34 KEYWORDS: PATENT LITIGATION - STRATEGIC PATENTING - TELECOMMUNICATIONS 2

3 1. Introduction Recent years have been characterised by a renewed attention to the intellectual property rights systems from both scholars and policy makers. In the two past decades very significant changes in U.S. patent law and policy have occurred, strengthening the rights of inventors and broadening the areas in which patents can be received. Moreover, the U.S. government has instituted a new unified Court of Appeals for the Federal Circuit to hear appeals on patent cases from all district courts. Such policy innovations concerning Acknowledgements. Preliminary versions of this paper were presented at the CESPRI seminar series in January 2004, at the Institute of Innovation seminar series at University of Manchester and at the International Schumpeter Society We gratefully acknowledge the usefull suggestions from all participants. This research has been financially supported by Fondazione Giovanni Agnelli. We wish to thank Director Marco Demarie for such support. Finally, we wish to acknowledge constant support by European Patent Office in data gathering. intellectual property rights have been partially adopted also in Europe. In particular, the issues involved in the design of the future community patent are a clear signal of the economic relevance of an efficient property rights system 1. Despite this policy activity, the recent scientific debate on intellectual property rights has been quite controversial. The economic analysis of the patent system has been traditionally based on the stream of literature on cost and benefits of temporary monopoly power (Nordhaus, 1972) in which the policy maker problem was to effectively adjust the terms of patent protection, namely length and breadth, in order to optimally balance static welfare losses and dynamic welfare gains. According to this stream of literature the theoretical analysis was essentially carried out through patent race models in which the firms involved are maximising the expected revenues from future monopolistic power 2. However, the latter approach has been somehow questioned by a series of recent paper which have highlighted the emergence - both in the U.S. and European economies - of a actual patent paradox. Hall and Ziedonis (2001) and Cohen et al. (2000) present very large surveys of private R&D divisions, which strongly support the hypothesis that modern companies judge patents a poor tool to protect innovation. In fact, when asked to rank different methodologies suitable for protecting innovative products and processes, R&D managers usually indicate patents after other channels like industrial secrecy, lead time or the use of complementary assets 3. 1 The main innovations relate to the treatment of legal suits. Presently for European patents it is possible to file a centralised opposition only with nine months after the granting date. After this deadline the legal proceedings for patent infringement move to the civil courts of each country in which protection has been asked. The community patent will introduce a unified and centralised court of appeal. 2 It is important to remark that this classic economic issue has not been abandoned, and it has produced a still active scientific debate. For some excellent works see Denicolò (1996), Wright (1999). 3 The phenomenon has been analysed also for the European context: Shankerman (1999) estimates by means of patent renewal data that the value protection provided by EU patents on average does not exceed 20% of the R&D expenditure sustained by the company for the development of the innovative product. 3

4 The paradox emerges when this latter evidence is set against the background of constant increases in the filings of new patents. New yearly patent application in the United States by domestic inventors have increased from around 60,000 in the mid 1980s to more 150,000 in the late 1990s. Some authors have tried to explain this increase in patent filing as an effect of the reforms of the U.S. patent system that strengthened the power of patent holder, but they obtained poor results (Kortum and Lerner, 1998). A second hypothesis, that has attracted the attention of numerous scholars, asserts that patent portfolio are built and managed as real bargaining chips among both horizontal competitors and upstream and downstream companies. The extensive interviews presented in Cohen et al. (2000) 4 suggest that firms patent for reason that go beyond product commercialisation or technology licensing. The most prominent motives include the prevention of rivals from imitating through patenting around, the specific use of patents in negotiations and the prevention of suits. The use of the patent system with objectives that are diverging from the ones it was originally designed for, can potentially result in net social welfare loss and in lower innovation rates. In this perspective, the original approach to the patent system has to be complemented with the investigation of the dynamic effect produced by this kind of strategic firm-level interactions. Purely strategic patenting can be detrimental to social welfare to the extent that companies build large patent portfolios exclusively for the purpose of blocking entrants also on marginal technologies that eventually are not developed and marketed. This situation was originally addressed by Gilbert and Newberry (1982) in their work on preemptive patenting and persistence of monopoly. The authors cite the famous case of SCM Corp. that sought more than $500 million to Xerox Corp. for having maintained a patent thicket in which some inventions were used while others were neither used or licesed to others. With preemptive activity a firm may sustain its monopoly power by spending resources on the development of new technologies, creating sleeping patents and then deny society the use of these technologies. According to this view of intellectual property rights, patent portfolios become valuable assets for the companies to the extent that they can use them to favour collusive anticompetitive agreements. The collusive equilibrium can be sustained by a mechanisms similar to the ones highlighted by the literature on multi-market contact among firms. Stretching the analogy from a multi-market contest to a multi-technology contest, it can be argued that there is a credible threat of retaliation from attacking a company endowed with a large and differentiated patent portfolio. This issue will be further explored and clarified in section three. The previous hypotheses raise relevant questions about the use of patent portfolios as tools to allow the emergence of collusive behaviours among large incumbent firms under the threat of reciprocal infringement suits. Some famous litigation cases in the U.S. have clearly highlighted the enormous costs of the legal proceedings for patent litigation, stressing the plausibility of an effective strategic threat. Previous empirical studies have investigated the phenomenon of patent litigation focussing on the determinants of suit filings (Lanjouw and Shankerman, 2001; Harhoff and Reitzig, 2004), the presence of predatory litigations through preliminary injunctions (Lanjouw and Lerner, 1997) or the factors influencing patent suit duration (Somaya, 4 The paper is based on the Carnegie Mellon Survey that involved 1478 R&D labs belonging to U.S. manufacturing companies. 4

5 2003). A growing theoretical literature is also addressing the new firm-level strategic interactions based on specific tools such as patent cross-licensing (Anton and Yao, 2002), patent thicket (Bessen, 2003), patent pools (Lerner and Tirole, 2000) and patentbased standard agreements (Shapiro, 2003). From the latter researches it clearly emerge how the strategic management of property rights is a strongly sector- specific phenomenon. In particular, industries characterised by complex product - where a single marketed technology requires numerous strictly complementary patents - are expected to be far more heavily affected by strategic patenting. Firms active in complex product industries are exposed to elevated risk of mutual hold-up stemming from the reciprocal ownership of relevant and complementary property rights. Even thought the theoretical literature on the strategic use of IPR is receiving important contributions, there is still a lack of comprehensive evidence of a real implementation by firms of such strategies. This is clearly due to the fact that strategic patenting is an hidden action. The purpose of this work is to try to shed light on the phenomenon through the observation of a publicly observable event - namely the decision to file an opposition to a rival company patent - that can potentially reveal some information about the underlying firm strategies. Our specific contribution is based on the examination of the full population of oppositions to patents filed at the European Patent Office occurred during the years , in the telecommunication industry. This industry involves complex technologies and has been subject to high rates of technological change during the two past decades. Two additional motive for selecting this industry relate to growing market concentration observed for technology producers and to the relevance of patent-based technological standards in recent years. In particular the emergence of the GSM communication protocol has gone through a troublesome history where a key role has been played by patent cross-licensing agreements (Bekkers et al. 2002). Previous researches on opposition to European patents have involved the biotech and pharmaceutical sector (Harhoff and Reitzig 2004) and were substantially focused on the specific characteristics of each patent subject to opposition. In that case, the main objective of the analysis was the investigation of possible correlations between measures of patent quality and the opposition event. Our innovation with respect to these empirical analysis is based on the use of information about the characteristics of the companies involved in the litigation. Furthermore, we have been able to track the complete history of each legal case in order to observe the presence of patterns correlating firms characteristics and the length and final outcomes of the trials. The statistical evidence about the trend in patent opposition in the telecommunication industry confirms the fundamental hypothesis about the existence of economic rationales behind the decision to suit litigations. In fact, the time profile of the number of oppositions follows a path independent from the constant parabolic increase observed for patent filings and grants. In particular, in the telecommunication industry there has been, during the last 5 years, a relative reduction in the incidence of opposed patents. This might be alternatively due to the presence of large standard agreements among equipment producers or to a collusive behaviour in a context of a more concentrated market. Our evidence seems to support the second strategic hypothesis. In fact, the occurrence of oppositions involving two large companies is substantially lower than the case in 5

6 which there is a large company attacking a relatively smaller one. When considering the major patentees in the TLC patent classes the matrix of reciprocal opposition cases is nearly empty. Moreover, threat effect connected to the filing of an opposition in a field dominated by technological complementarities is well represented by the relatively high percentage of patents assigned to smaller or individual patentee that after surviving an opposition attempt are no longer renewed by their owner. The paper is organised according to the following structure. In the next section we will briefly summarise the key legal and organisational features of the European patent system, stressing the main differences with the U.S. contest in order to allow a clearer interpretation of the following empirical evidence and methodology. Section three will be dedicated to the analysis of both the empirical and theoretical literature concerning the determinants and effect of patent litigation and patent opposition. In section four we will clarify our original interpretative model and highlight the research hypotheses. Section five contains a detailed description of the methodology implemented to analyse the patent oppositions and the statistical evidence. Finally, in section six we summarise and discuss our results, suggesting future research developments. 2. The European patent system and patent opposition. The purpose of a patent system is to balance the interest of society in ensuring that the inventor publicly shares his knowledge in order to promote innovation, with the interest of the inventor in receiving protection for his ideas. The protective, informative and pro-competitive functions are reflected in the system structure, which offers a territorial protection and requires a full disclosure of the patented innovation. The effectiveness of such objectives is clearly influenced by the overlapping of the geographical market of the firm and the geographical extension of patent protection. In the Paris Convention of 1883 was signed a first agreement among European Countries for mutual recognition of foreign patents. In 1973 the European Patent Convention designed a centralised process of patent filing within the borders of the European Economic Community according to which the centrally examined paper will be fully valid in all the member countries. Even if there has been a number of subsequent treaties to harmonise the patent law among different countries (Patent Cooperation Treaty; Trips Agreements, 1994) the legal proceedings have yet to be taken at a country level 5. Moreover, it is important to stress that such harmonisation procedure has not directly involved the methods for estimating the recovery of damages from patent infringements. As Reitzig et al. (2003) clearly state, different national jurisdictions provide for number of different methods for calculating damages 6. Since august 2000 the European Commission is supporting the introduction of a community patent whose main innovation will be the institution of an autonomous post grant regime governed by community law. The centralised litigation 5 In case of cross-country suits the risk of forum shopping by the claimant is limited by the Brussels Convention of 1968 which grants international jurisdiction to the court of domicile of the defendant. 6 The methodologies can be summarised into three categories: patentee s own damages, the infrigers profit, and the rule of a reasonable royalty. The application of different indemnification rules can substantially shift the firm level incentives to file a suit. In particular the lacking of an infringers profit rule can strongly favour larger companies towards smaller ones. 6

7 procedure will be carried out by a community intellectual property court with first instance and appeal chamber. The dataset involved in this study is based on cases of patent opposition, that is a quite different procedure than patent litigation. The opposition procedure gives the right to any third party to attack a granted patent during a nine months time window after the grant date. It is a centralised suit that if successful- causes the revocation or amendment of the new patent in all the countries for which protection has been asked. If the parties are not satisfied after the first sentence, there is a centralised court of appeal and eventually the trial will move to national courts. The opponent has to substantiate his opposition by presenting evidence that the patent is lacking patentability prerequisites such as novelty, inventive step and sufficient disclosure. The opposition commission at EPO is formed by three members including the original examiner who granted the patent. The main concept underlying the institution of the opposition system is the effective integration of competitors in the quality and novelty control of granted patents. In the U.S. system there is the possibility of a re-examination procedure of a patent, but in this case the third-party challenger is denied a meaningful role in the process while the patentholder maintains direct communications with the examiner. As a result, challengers face powerful incentives to forego re-examination procedure in favour of pure litigation trials, even if the latter are more expensive and time consuming 7. Hall, Harhoff, Graham and Mowery (2003) present an insightful comparative analysis of the institutional settings in Europe and U.S. for patent litigation. Presently the relative efficiency of the European opposition systems is argued by different scholars. Graham et al. (2003) suggest that the adoption of the opposition model based on inter parties re-examination may substantially increase the quality of patent in the U.S.. Similar welfare improving effect are derived trough a theoretical model by Levin and Levin (2002). Several legal characteristics of the opposition procedure turn out to be useful to detect possible strategic behaviours underlying the decision to file the suit. First, we stress that the opposition is directed against a patent holder that has just been granted a new patent 8. Rather often the new patentee is an entrant in the technology domain where the opponent owns previously granted patents 9. Moreover, the new attacked patentee has already incurred the sunk costs associated to the R&D expenditures necessary for the development of the patent, but he has not yet used the patent. Second, after the filing of the opposition, there is no longer a chance of negotiation among the parties. In fact, once an opposition is filed, the EPO commission can carry on the re examination even if the opposition is withdrawn. In this perspective, the filing of an opposition is a more irreversible decision when compared to a traditional legal suit 7 This incentive structure is reflected in the limited incidence of re-examination cases in the U.S. compared to the European opposition. Only 0.2% of USPTO granted patents are subject to reexamination against an average value of 8% of EPO patents subject to opposition. 8 This constitutes a major difference with respect to the standard situation of patent litigation among two firms that are already inside a certain technology market. 9 In principles any third party may file a patent opposition for reasons different from the pure infringement on a previous property right. However, the cases in which the opponent company files a suit for reasons related to limited disclosure or obviousness of the attacked patent are very rare. 7

8 for patent infringements 10. The latter features represent a major difference between the opposition system and the litigation process in the U.S.. The data presented in Somaya (2003) for the U.S. contest, highlight that most of patent suits are dismissed or settled right after the preliminary motions and only a very small fraction actually undergoes the trial. The previous characteristics suggest that there is room for a strategic use of the patent opposition procedure in order to discourage new entrants and favour collusive behaviours among larger incumbents. A first simple intuitive effect is due to the increase in uncertainty following the filing of patent opposition. During the opposition period, the patent is valid and the patentee will necessitate capacity investments both to implement the technological innovation and to sustain the related R&D program. Such investment will have to be planned in a period during which the patentee bears the risk of seeing his patent eventually revoked. The net effect for smaller patent holders is an investment disincentive proportional to the perceived litigation costs in terms of time lag. Since our dataset is based on opposition cases, one may argue that it is somehow biased and covering only partially the phenomenon of patent litigation. However, there are a number of reasons according to which companies should prefer a centralised procedure like the opposition rather than litigation. First, a litigation procedure repeated across more than fifteen European national civil courts can generate very high administrative costs 11. Second, in the case of litigation at national courts, the infringed company that is filing the suit will be subject to an higher degree of uncertainty about the final outcome of the trials. For example, in Italy the patent litigation is part of the ordinary civil proceedings and is usually handled by a single judge who is only legally trained and, unlike members of the EPO Board of Appeal, has no specific technical background. So, in the Italian contest the judge is normally obliged to appoint an expert to acquire the required technical knowledge. In this situation it is fundamental to stress that the expert s opinion is not a proper means of evidence, but rather a means to evaluate and interpret the evidence that has already been taken in the proceeding. The expert cannot have exploration duties leading him to exceed the limit of the burden of the evidence which are exclusive right of the parties (EPOSCRIPT, 2001). Direct consequence of such procedure is a reduced investigation effort and higher uncertainty for the parties. In the case of Germany, a special Federal Patent Court has been created for the cases involving industrial property rights. However this court - composed by technically qualified judges which are usually selected among EPO patent examiners - has power only in the cases of nullity actions but not in the cases of infringements. 3. The economics of patent litigation. Our research builds on the contributions of two close stream of literature. On one side, we develop and try to empirically identify the strategic behaviours predicted by the literature on management of IPR (Bessen, On the other side, we take into account 10 This provision of the opposition process may discourage its use by opponents seeking to force rivals to license their patents (Harhoff and Hall, 2002). 11 The cost of litigation for each national court is estimated to range between and Euro (Eposcript, 2001). 8

9 the results obtained by studies that have specifically focused on patent litigation (Lanjouw and Schankerman, 1997, 2001; Lerner, 1995; Somaya, The prospective management of patent portfolios as bargaining chips has been first tackled by Grindley and Teece (1997) and Hall and Ziedonis (2001) in the semiconductor industry, while Lanjouw and Schankerman (1997, 2001) through a series of papers develop the idea that the probability for a specific patent to be subject to litigation can be analysed by means of the concepts commonly applied in the standard theory on legal suits. According to this latter stream of literature the probability of occurrence of a legal dispute is linked to three dimensions: the size of the stake involved, the degree of uncertainty and the cost of the suit (Meurer, 1989). The extension of these concepts into the area of intellectual property suggests the following statements. First, the probability of opposition is expected to be positively correlated to the economic value of the patent. A large stream of literature has investigated methods to provide consistent measures of patent quality by referring essentially to the number of subsequent citation received (Haroff et al. 1999). Second, the probability that a patent will be subject to litigation is proportional to the degree of informational uncertainty concerning the technology covered by the patent. Higher uncertainty about the future revenues coming from commercial applications of the knowledge embedded in the patent is likely to induce substantial asymmetries in the private evaluation of a patent. In this perspective, in an high-uncertain context the owner of the patent is expected to be less favourable to licensing, given the limited ability to understand the buyer s real estimate of the patent. According to this point patents in frontier technologies should be more subject to litigation. The third determinant derived from the law literature refers to the legal costs of patent litigation. In principles, a company should provide financial resourses for litigation up to the point where such costs equal future expected revenues from patent ownership. Such revenues have to be calculated taking into account not only the standard uncertainty but also the risk of loosing the legal procedure. Lanjouw and Schankerman (2001) carry out an empirical investigation to test the implications of patent litigation on R&D incentives and patent policy in the U.S. The study is based on patent suits and settlements during For each litigation case the authors draw a matching random set from the universe of patents, controlling for technology and year of application. The statistical analysis reveals that, when controlling for the rapid increase in patent filing during recent years, the incidence of patent suits has not been rising 12. By appling a probit model the authors are able to show that litigation is concentrated within firms and patents with specific characteristics. In particular, the probability that a patent is subject to a suit is much higher if it is owned by an individual or a small firm. This result is explained by the fact that patentees with a large portfolio of patents to trade, can manage to produce cooperative resolution among them. Whether this observation can be interpreted as a form of collusion among large innovators with a net negative effect on innovation is still an open issue. However, the reduced bargaining power of smaller patentees appear to be a net weakness point in enforcing their patent rights, that in turn can heavily affect the entry rate in high tech industries. 12 It is interesting to anticipate that this result is fully confirmed by our data on European patents in the telecommunication technologies. 9

10 The strategic use of patents by large companies as been analysed by Lanjouw and Lerner (2001) through the observation of a specific legal procedure: the preliminary injunctions. The owner of a patent can ask for a preliminary injunction preventing an accused infringer from using the patented innovation during the time that a case is being decided. Preliminary injunction can be strategically used by financially secure plaintiffs to go beyond the avoidance of "irreparable harm" and to extract even greater profit by raising the cost of legal disputes. The data proposed by the authors 13 confirm this latter intuition, showing how larger corporate plaintiffs with high levels of cash flow and equivalents are significantly more likely to request preliminary injunctions. Crampes and Langinier (2002) stress how the detection of patent infringement cases can be a difficult and resource consuming process. This is due to the complexity of technologies involving thousands of different patents for a single product 14. Again, the overall effect might be a strong disincentive for smaller entrant companies. Somaya (2003) further investigate the possible strategic implications underlying the decision to file a legal suit and in particular to go to court instead of settling an agreement. The author examines two forms of asymmetric stakes: strategic stakes and mutual hold-up. In the case of strategic stakes, a firm with a patent monopoly can leverage specific strategic assets. The greater the value of a patent, the more difficult it becomes to craft a settlement suitable to both parties. Mutual hold-up occurs when firms depend upon one another for reciprocal access to patents in order to manufacture their products. This is common for companies that specialize in computer operating systems, where individual products consist of several different patented inventions, often owned by different firms. When faced with a patent lawsuit, an operating system manufacturer may protect itself by threatening its rival with a countersuit over another patent. To test these hypotheses, the author looks at patent and litigation data collected by the Federal Judicial Center and the US Patent and Trademark Office for suits filed between in the computer and research medicines industries. Results from a statistical analysis of the data support the strategic stakes hypothesis. A high strategic stake increases the probability that a dispute will be decided in court. However, contrary to prior research, this occurred primarily in the computer industry and not in the pharmaceutical sector. All the previously mentioned empirical analyses were based on U.S. patents. On the European side, Harhoff and Reitzig (2004) have produced a detailed analysis of patent opposition in the area of biotechnology and pharmaceuticals. They apply citation and classification analysis on a large sample of over European patents granted between 1979 and 1996, of which 8.6 percent resulted having been subject to opposition. For each patent they have been able to compute the number of backward citations 15, the number of citations received, the number of IPC classes in which it has been registered, the name of the assignee and its total patent portfolio. By applying different multivariate probit specifications they obtain some relevant results concerning the characteristics of the patents. First, high quality patent measured by citation analysis are more likely to be opposed. Second, the likelihood of opposition 13 The database consists of 250 patent suits and corresponding firm financial status. 14 Grindley and Teece (1997) report how Texas Instruments legal and engineering staff often spent a year to determine the extent of a suspected infringement. 15 In this specific research, the authors add new features to the traditional approach that was commonly based on a simple citation count. In fact, the citation are pre-classified into different categories according to the guidelines for examination issued by the World Intellectual Property Organization. In this way each citation can be weighted according to its relevance for the specific patent. 10

11 is positively correlated to the number of designated states, a proxy for the economic relevance of the patent. The contributions deriving from the different empirical approaches can be jointly summarised according to the following points. First, there is evidence at least for the U.S. that the litigation procedure is influenced also by strategic determinants and not only by technological rationales. Second, smaller companies can suffer from the threat of litigation as a consequence of high monitoring and legal costs. Third, asymmetries both in the economic evaluation of a patent and in the width of private patent portfolios can play a major role in the decision to file a suit. Finally, the technological sectors where the possibility of mutual hold-up are higher due to elevated sub-product complementarities are exposed to risk of collusive and anticompetitive agreements between large incumbent companies. 4. Research hypotheses. The strategic use of patent portfolios is a phenomenon whose empirical observation is quite subtle. However, here we claim that is possible to use a publicly observable event the filing of oppositions to infer about the underlying firm-level hidden strategies. Since each patent in principle provides an imperfect protection due to possible grant of close substitute patent, a patent holder has a direct incentive in monitoring the patenting system and in claiming the revocation of new patents that are supposed to infringe his own property rights. However, in complex industries final goods are produced using numerous complementary inventions. This situation poses an additional relevant challenge to firms that have to choose their patent strategy while being often embedded in an thicket of cross-licensing agreements. In such a contest, the development of large patent portfolios gives the firm a relative bargaining power by means of counter-suits reaction and hold-up on complementary patents. In this perspective, the most recent modelling approaches in the literature on patent opposition (Levin and Levin, 2002) can be interestingly coupled with the multimarket contact stream of literature (Bernheim and Whinston, 1990). The core concept of this theoretical literature is that multi-market contacts could influence oligopolistic cooperation by providing firms with a mechanism to check whether colluding is an optimal strategy under the threat of reciprocal strategic retaliations. The notion of multimarket contacts can be stretched to the concept of multi-technology contact. In this latter case the companies are not coupled through overlapping geographical markets, but through overlapping technologies. Two firms active in different technological fields, covered by imperfect patents, might sustain a reciprocal non aggressive strategy eventually leading to a persistent oligopolistic market structures. On the contrary, an entrant does not have enough contracting power to dissuade incumbents from opposing his patent. In a very simple framework, the previous considerations can be summarised as follows. 11

12 Firms A and B have a certain number of patents covering technology domains 1 and 2. The decision for a firm A, that owns a previous patent on a specific technology, to file an opposition against a patent newly granted to firm B for technology 1 can be interpreted as being subject to the following condition. (1) p Π 1 Μ + (1- p) Π 1 D p [ PRET (Π 2 M Π 2 D )] C > Π 1 D (2) PRET = F (relative portfolio size) where p represent the probability of success in the opposition procedure that will give to firm A the right to keep its monopolistic rent over technology Π 1 D is the expected profit that firm A will get when allowing firm B to enter the technology market without filing an opposition. PRET represents the probability of retaliation from the firm B the other technology by means of a counter suit. This probability is hypothesised to be a function of the patent portfolios stocks of the two firms. Different situations can occur with respect to the reciprocal patent portfolio endowments of the two companies. If the patent stock of firm A is close to zero, there is not a second technological market in which the firm can suffer from a retaliation and the third term is ruled out in equation (1). In this case, the constraint on filing an opposition is strictly based on legal cost C. If the patent stocks of the two company are non negligible, but the firm A owns a much larger number of patents there is an higher expected likelihood for firm A to file an opposition. Finally, when the two patent portfolios are numerous and comparable, the risk of retaliation is maximum and the previous constraint is more likely to bind, favouring the instauration of ex-ante settlements. The previous reasoning would suggest the presence of a U-shaped distribution of opposition according to the relative size of patent portfolios. The reciprocal risk of receiving counter suits on complex technology should in general prevent large companies from filing suits among them. On the other side, very small companies endowed with only one patent are expected to file patent suits even against large innovators because they are not suffering a credible retaliation risk on a different segment of their property rights portfolio 17. The previous synthetic analysis jointly interpreted with the considerations presented in section three can be summarised in the following statements: HP1: Large incumbent companies are expected to show mutual opposition rates statistically lower than the ones jointly involving one small and one large patentee. HP2: Larger companies induce higher litigation costs in terms of longer suits. 16 Here we are considering an exogenous probability, independent from firm characteristics. In the empirical section of the paper we have investigate this feature finding that the outcomes of the legal proceedings are indeed independent from the characteristics of the opponent. 17 Somaya (2003) elaborates on the issue of mutual hold-up and patent strategy suggesting that simply having a large patent portfolio may not be an adequate defence against attempted patent enforcement by rivals. Some potential opponents may be focused on specific narrow technologies. In order to account for this specific effect we calculated, for each company involved in an opposition procedure, both the overall patent portfolio and the specific portfolio on four telecommunication patent classes (defined at a fourdigit IPC level). 12

13 In order to test the two previous hypothesis we will split the overall sample of firms involved in at least one opposition either as opponent or opposed into two sub samples of large and small patent holders. The distribution of patent portfolios in the telecommunications sector is highly skewed, with a limited number of companies endowed with very large patent portfolios and a long thin tail of residual patentees. For this reason, we included in the sub sample of large innovators the top 5% of companies in terms of patent portfolio over the years HP3: The presence of overlapping geographical markets should influence the decision to file an opposition. This aspect will be investigated trough the observation of both the nationality of the companies involved in the opposition and the priority state of the opposed patents 18. We expect the use of the opposition procedure on EU patents to be different between European companies and U.S. or Japanese companies. HP4: Smaller companies after receiving an opposition are less likely to continue their innovative activity, since they will not be able to access complementary technological assets. The possible disincentive effect will be measured through the analysis of subsequent patent renewals after the patent has survived the opposition procedure. The decision to let the patent lapse for non payment of renewal fees right after the opposition can be interpreted as a reduced value perceived by the opposed firms. About this latter specific issue, in previous research, Lerner (1995) showed that small young biotechnology firms try to avoid patenting in patent classes characterised by high litigation rates. The analysis will be carried out using a proper control sample of non opposed patents to account for sector specific patent renewal policies. HP5: Participating a standard setting organisation can affect the rate of opposition among member companies. Standard setting, a characteristic peculiar to the network industries and in particular to that of telecommunications, is an extremely fertile ground for strategic patenting behaviour. With respect to this latter point, it is worth mentioning the attempt to influence the standardisation processes in one s own favour using the threat of a patent which is declared indispensable for the definition of the standard but that is not completely disclosed, as in the often cited case of Qualcomm against Ericsson in the process of defining the 3G standard. Another form of strategic behaviour is the refusal to licence a blocking patent or even the voluntary concealment of a fundamental patent in the structure of the standard in order to gain, ex-post, enormous market power thanks to the imposition of the standard. Finally, standard-setting organisations themselves can set up discriminatory strategic behaviour, for example excluding from the consortium whoever is unwilling to concede a free licence for their own patent, or even being the 18 The priority number of a patent indicates the first country in which patent protection has been asked. Companies typically make an initial application for a local patent and then extend it to other patent systems. We will make a broad distinction among patents initia lly applied in Europe, U.S. and Japan. 13

14 victims of hold-ups by the companies who reveal the existence of patents which are fundamental for the definition of a standard after that standard has been completely defined (Shapiro, 2003). On these basis, one should expect that the participation into a standard, which is essentially based on the licensing of a certain number of patents on the FRAND 19 license, strengthens the strategic relationships among participants encouraging non aggressive behaviours also on patents not included in the standard agreement. 19 The acronym stands for Fair Reasonable And Non Discriminatory conditions about royalties. 14

15 5. Dataset and summary statistics Our empirical analysis is based on an original dataset of European patents data extracted and matched from four distinct patent databases provided by the European Patent Office : EUREG, EPODOC, EPIDOS and INPADOC 20. The core data are represented by the population of all the patents in the area of telecommunications that have been subject to opposition during the period The telecommunication technologies have been identified according to 4 specific International Patent Classification classes 21. For each opposed patent we have been able to extract the names of both the assignee company and opponent company. We performed a detailed screening in order to consolidate the name and the ownership structure of the companies through the years involved in the panel. The legal cases characterised by multiple opponents have been duplicated considering the additional patent data of each opponent 22. A set of additional characteristics has been associated to each opposed patent, including the number of forward citations received, the number of patent families and the number of claims. Moreover, for each assignee and opponent we have performed an analysis of patent portfolio at the moment of the opposition in order to obtain measures of size and specialisation in the specific technological field of the opposed patents 23. The overall sample consists of 488 opposed patents and 285 companies and individual inventors, involved either as plaintiffs or as infringers. A random matched sample has been drawn from the population of European patent granted in the four-digit IPC classes selected for the study. For each patent subject to opposition, we extracted a patent granted in the same patent class and in the same semester. For the matched patent we collected data about the patent-specific characteristics and we computed the patent stock portfolio of its assignee at the moment of the grant. The latter data have been used to control for time and industry specific factors that might affect the statistical evidence that will be presented in this section. Before moving to the detailed presentation of our empirical evidence, it is worth remarking that, given the nature of the available data, we are not testing a structural model for patent opposition, but rather presenting a collection of statistical evidence that is expected to give the reader insightful intuitions about the actual dynamics and implications of the patent opposition phenomenon. In the two following tables we show the trend in the number of granted patent and opposed patent in the telecommunication industry from 1980 through The INPADOC database has been explored through the commercial database Delphion [ 21 The selection of the relevant classes has been driven by interviews with patent examiners at EPO. H04B: This subclass covers the transmission of information-carrying signals and includes monitoring and testing arrangements and the suppression and limitation of noise and interference; H04J: This subclass covers circuits or apparatus for combining or dividing signals for the purpose of transmitting them simultaneously or sequentially over the same transmission path; H04L: This subclass covers transmission of signals having been supplied in digital form; H04M: telephonic communication systems combined with other electrical systems. 22 Within the sample these cases have been rare, not exceeding 2% of all the oppositions. A particular case is that of a German legal company that represent an association of broadcasting companies (Interessengemeinschaft für Rundfunkschutzrechte Gmb H). 23 From now on we will refer to large and small company in terms of patent portfolio size. 15

16 Table 1 Total number of patent opposition in TLC classes. oppositions Source: Our elaboration on EPO data. Table 2 Total number of paten granted in TLC classes granted patent in TLC classes Source: Our elaboration on EPO data. The time profile of patent grants in the four main patent classes representing the TLC industry shows a steadily increasing trend, while a much diverging trend can be appreciated for the absolute levels of patent oppositions. The ratios of opposed to granted patent shown in Table 3 are slightly smaller than the ones presented by Harhoff and Reitzig (2004), but they highlight the economic relevance of the analysed phenomenon The authors estimated an average value of 8%. The d ifference is likely to be related to the different role of patents for different industries. See Jaffe and Trajtenberg (2002) for an extensive discussion. 16

17 Table 3 Incidence of opposition per 100 granted patents in TLC patent classes by time intervals. Years Oppositions per 100 granted patents Source: our elaboration on EPO data. From the evidence presented in table 1 and 2 some interesting patterns emerge. First, it is clear how there is not a pure statistical relationship between the number of filed patents and number of oppositions. On the contrary, there must be some kind of underlying economic determinant that shifts over time the propensity to use this legal procedure in order to protect patents. There are two peaks in the incidence of oppositions respectively at the end of the 80s and around year 1996, while in more recent years there has been a constant decreasing trend. The two peaks might be associated with the period immediately before the emergence of two crucial standards in mobile communications: GSM s and UMTS s ones. The increased technological uncertainty preceding the constitution of such standards might have plausibly strengthen the incentives to use legal tools to block rivals and defend own patent portfolios. However, when observing the time trend of patenting (and oppositions) in the telecommunication industry, it is important to recall that this sector has undergone relevant shocks in the European countries linked to market liberalisation processes. Even if these policy interventions have directly affected service providers rather than technology producers it might be argued that the upsurge in oppositions in mid 90s is related to the industry liberalisation. We claim that - with specific reference to the phenomenon of patent opposition - this institution exerted only a second order effect. For each opposed patent included in the sample we have tracked the complete legal history after the filing of the opposition. A patent subject to opposition can be either fully upheld, revoked or amended. In the latter case a number of claims are removed from the patent. The aggregated statistics about the final outcomes of the centralised opposition procedures show that about 40% of opposed patents have been revoked, 25% have been amended, in 30% of the cases the opposition has been rejected by the court and in 5% of the case the opposition procedure is spontaneously withdrawn by the opponent company before the verdict of the EPO commission (Table 4). In order to perform an initial analysis based on firm characteristics we selected among the overall companies involved in the opposition, a set of large innovators. This companies belong to the upper 5% in the distribution of patent portfolios in the TLC 17

18 patent classes 25. Such sub sample of major innovators consists of 12 companies that represent 53% of all the opponent and 34% of all the opposed patent holder within our dataset. Table 4 Final outcome of opposition procedure. Opposition Full Sample Sample Excluding Major Innovators Major Innovators Patent Revoked 39,1% 40,6% 36,1% Patent Amended 23,7% 22,6% 25,1% Termination of Opposition 5,0% 3,3% 8,5% Opposition Rejected 32,2% 32,5% 30,3% Source: Our elaboration on INPADOC data. It is interesting to note that percentages of the different outcomes do not substantially change when we restrict the analysis to the patents belonging to the large companies 26. This should support the hypothesis that the patent re-examination performed by the EPO commission is strictly based on technological issues and that the examiners are not influenced by reputation effects. The only relevant difference is in the incidence of cases in which the opponent decides to withdraw the opposition previously filed before the EPO verdict (Termination of Opposition in Table 4). The latter percentage is higher when the opposed patent belongs to a major innovator, suggesting that a threat effect might be active. From the data in table 3 we can as well induce that there are no relevant quality ex-ante differences between the patent granted to the large innovators and to other firms. This evidence will be important to exclude the possibility of quality effect when interpreting subsequent results about the companies involved in oppositions. In order to pinpoint other possible patent-specific characteristics, that may produce spurious biases on our observations about strategic determinants, we have computed the average number of patent families 27 and patent claims by opposition outcome. We have as well computed the previous values for the patent control sample. The data in Table 5 suggest that there are no relevant bias in the subset of patent subject to opposition with respect to the non opposed patents. The only significant difference relates to the higher average number of claims for the opposed patents that have been eventually amended. This evidence seems to support the hypothesis that at least in the telecommunication sector - these idiosyncratic characteristics of a single patent are one but a minor determinant of patent suit filings. This paves the way to our hypothesis that firms characteristics are a major factor in determining the decision to file the opposition. 25 The distribution of patent portfolio is rather skewed, the major innovators are the following: Alcatel, AT&T, Ericsson, Lucent, Motorola, NEC, Nokia, Nortel, NTT, Philips, Qualcomm, Siemens. 26 The incidence of revoked patent is slightly larger than the ones obtained by Harhoff and Reitzig (2004). In the biotechnology sector 30% of opposed patent were eventually revoked. 27 The number of patent families is the number of countries, also non European, for which protection has been asked. This parameter can be interpreted to some extent as a proxy for the commercial value of the patent and for the potential geographical extension of the patent-holder s final market. 18

19 Table 5 Average and median number of patent families and patent claims for different outcomes of the opposition procedure. Number of patent families Number of patent claims Amended Patent mean median Opposition Rejected mean median 9 10 Patent Revoked mean median Control Sample mean median 9 8 Source: our elaboration on EPO data. One of the possible dimensions to observe firm-level strategies for the management of their patent portfolios is the payment of the renewal fees (Schankerman, 1999). By a theoretical perspective, the firm is expected to pay the renewal fees until such incremental cost equals expected revenues from the future exploitation of patent rights. Quite surprisingly, a relatively high percentage (14%) of survived patents 28 are not renewed in the first four years after the end of the opposition procedure 29 (Table 6). This might be a somehow contrasting result with respect to Haroff and Reitzig (2002) that associated patent opposition to higher patent quality, measured by patent citation analysis. However, it is important to recall that they were working on the single-product pharmaceutical sector, while in the telecommunication industry, where technological complementarities are fundamental, the filing of an opposition from a competitor can be interpreted as a threatening signal of subsequent non-collaborative relationships that eventually lowers the private value of the opposed patent. Even more interestingly, the incidence of non renewed patent is clearly different for the two sub-samples of large and small companies. For the former we found a percentage of non renewed patent of about 11%, while for the latter the percentage raises to 17%. For a clearer interpretation of this evidence, we calculated the renewal rate also for the patent included in the control sample. The difference between the sub-samples of large and small innovators is more evident when taking into account work in progress patent 30. These are cases of patent opposition for which there was not yet evidence from the legal database INPADOC of a final decision by the EPO court at the moment of this study. 28 The survived patents include the cases of opposition rejected, patent amended and spontaneous opposition withdrawal by the opponent. 29 The European patent system gives to the patentee the initial possibility to choose the number of countries in which protection will be provided. After the granting, each patent holder has to pay an individual renewal fee for every country. We considered a patent not fully renewed if it lapsed in at least three quarters of the total number of countries. This is due to avoid the risk of including among the nonrenewed sub sample those patent that expired only in minor countries. 30 The data about patent opposition outcomes has been extracted between Oct and Jan

20 Table 6 Percentages of patents non renewed during the four years after the end of the opposition and during the work in progress period. Patent renewal Full Sample Sample Excluding Major Innovators Major Innovators Control Sample % Survived non renewed 14,5% 17,3% 11,0% 9.8% % WP non renewed 20,1% 25,4% 6,7% Source: Our elaboration on INPADOC data. Even if the renewal policy can differ between large and small patentees for a range of factors, such discrepancy can be a signal of lower contracting power for smaller companies that prefer to stop investing on a technology even after winning the legal suit. In fact, the technological dynamics in the telecommunication sector are cumulative and the risk of incurring new oppositions on second-generation products can discourage smaller innovators 31. The third hypothesis presented in section three suggested that the decision to file a patent opposition might be somehow conditioned by the degree of final market overlapping among the companies involved. It is possible to assign each European patent to the country in which it was originally filed. This information can be interpreted as a proxy of the main geographical coverage of the patentee. When analysing the distribution of the country priorities of the opposed patents, some clear pattern emerge. While in the full population of European patents in the telecommunications classes non-eu priorities account for nearly 54% of total patents, such percentage decreases to 39% in the sample of patents subject to opposition. This evidence suggests that the geographical effect, if any, is rather weak. Alternatively, it is also plausible that patents already in force in the U.S. are more powerful and so less likely to be opposed. Table 7 Percentages of patents with EU, US and JP priority in the TLC classes. Years Priority Full Population Opposed Patents EU 68,21 % 75,81 % US 20,55 % 15,03 % JP 11,24 % 9,16 % Years Priority Full Population Opposed Patents EU 49,51 % 56,26 % US 28,97 % 25,36 % JP 21,52 % 18,36 % Source: Our elaboration on EPO and INPADOC data. In order to analyse the possible strategic effects underlying the decision to file patent opposition we focus on the sub sample of 12 large innovators. We have computed a simple matrix to identify the aggregated pattern of legal oppositions specifically 31 Scotchmer (1991, 1996) presents an insightful analysis of the issue of cumulativeness in complex product innovation and patent law. 20

Patent Litigation with Endogenous Disputes

Patent Litigation with Endogenous Disputes Patent itigation with Endogenous Disputes Presentation at the AEA Annual Meeting January 6, 006 Session: Intellectual Property, itigation, and Innovation By James Bessen and Michael J. Meurer James Bessen

More information

Yearbook. Building IP value in the 21st century. Beyond the unitary patent: nothing new under the sun?

Yearbook. Building IP value in the 21st century. Beyond the unitary patent: nothing new under the sun? Beyond the unitary patent: nothing new under the sun? Anna Barlocci and Mathieu de Rooij, ZBM Patents & Trademarks Yearbook 2015 Building IP value in the 21st century 12 13 14 ZBM Patents & Trademarks

More information

Determinants of Patent Litigation in Germany

Determinants of Patent Litigation in Germany Determinants of Patent Litigation in Germany by Katrin Cremers Centre for European Economic Research (ZEW), Mannheim 14. März 2005 Abstract: This paper presents an empirical analysis of the determinants

More information

Profiting from Non-Technological Innovation: The Value of Patenting. Novak druce centre insights No. 8

Profiting from Non-Technological Innovation: The Value of Patenting. Novak druce centre insights No. 8 Profiting from Non-Technological Innovation: The Value of Patenting Business METHODS Novak druce centre insights No. 8 contents 01 Introduction: An Unexplored Area 02 Patenting Non-Technological Innovation

More information

Intellectual Property Strategy in the Global Cosmetics Industry A Soap Opera

Intellectual Property Strategy in the Global Cosmetics Industry A Soap Opera Intellectual Property Strategy in the Global Cosmetics Industry A Soap Opera Dietmar Harhoff University of Munich and CEPR Bronwyn H. Hall University of California, Berkeley and NBER Why are we doing this?

More information

LITIGANT REPUTATION AND THE ECONOMICS OF PATENT LITIGATION IN THE UNITED STATES: 1996-2010

LITIGANT REPUTATION AND THE ECONOMICS OF PATENT LITIGATION IN THE UNITED STATES: 1996-2010 LITIGANT REPUTATION AND THE ECONOMICS OF PATENT LITIGATION IN THE UNITED STATES: 1996-2010 JAVAD ESKANDARIKHOEE * UNIVERSITY OF DELAWARE JANUARY 2014 JOB MARKET PAPER ABSTRACT Patent litigation in the

More information

Patents in Europe 2013/2014

Patents in Europe 2013/2014 In association with Unitary patent and Unified Patent Court: the proposed framework Rainer K Kuhnen Patents in Europe 2013/2014 Helping business compete in the global economy Unitary patent and Unified

More information

Ryerson Digital Media Zone Online Resources Patent Essentials

Ryerson Digital Media Zone Online Resources Patent Essentials Maya Medeiros Lawyer, Patent Agent, Trademark Agent T: +1 416.216.4823 maya.medeiros@nortonrosefulbright.com http://www.nortonrosefulbright.com/people/99601/maya- medeiros PATENT ESSENTIALS WHAT IS A PATENT?

More information

FRAND Commitment - The case against improper antitrust intervention

FRAND Commitment - The case against improper antitrust intervention FRAND Commitment - The case against improper antitrust intervention Oxford 9 March 2009 Prof. Damien Geradin Introduction Standard setting is of crucial importance for the economy FRAND regime has operated

More information

Draft Report of the Dispute Settlement Subcommittee, Intellectual Property Policy Committee, Industrial Structure Council

Draft Report of the Dispute Settlement Subcommittee, Intellectual Property Policy Committee, Industrial Structure Council Draft Report of the Dispute Settlement Subcommittee, Intellectual Property Policy Committee, Industrial Structure Council October 2002 Table of Contents Chapter 1 Overview and Problems of Legal Systems

More information

CPI Antitrust Chronicle March 2013 (Special Issue)

CPI Antitrust Chronicle March 2013 (Special Issue) CPI Antitrust Chronicle March 2013 (Special Issue) Standard Setting Organizations Can Help Solve the Standard Essential Patents Licensing Problem Kai-Uwe Kühn, Fiona Scott Morton, & Howard Shelanski www.competitionpolicyinternational.com

More information

Legal FAQ: Introduction to Patent Litigation

Legal FAQ: Introduction to Patent Litigation Legal FAQ: Introduction to Patent Litigation by charlene m. morrow and dargaye churnet 1. Who enforces a patent? The U.S. Patent and Trademark Office grants a patent. Contrary to popular belief, a patent

More information

CONFLICT RESOLUTION, PUBLIC GOODS AND PATENT THICKETS

CONFLICT RESOLUTION, PUBLIC GOODS AND PATENT THICKETS 12 04 (R1) March 25, 2013 ESMT Working Paper CONFLICT RESOLUTION, PUBLIC GOODS AND PATENT THICKETS DIETMAR HARHOFF, UNIVERSITY OF MUNICH GEORG VON GRAEVENITZ, UNIVERSITY OF EAST ANGLIA IN LONDON STEFAN

More information

Patent Litigation in Germany An Introduction (I)

Patent Litigation in Germany An Introduction (I) Patent Litigation in Germany An Introduction (I) By Prof. Dr. Heinz Goddar, Dr. jur. Carl-Richard Haarmann Prof. Dr. Heinz Goddar Senior Partner, Boehmert & Boehmert, Munich, and Honorary Professor for

More information

Norway Advokatfirmaet Grette

Norway Advokatfirmaet Grette This text first appeared in the IAM magazine supplement Patents in Europe 2008 April 2008 Norway By Amund Brede Svendsen and Svein Ruud Johansen, Advokatfirmaet Grette, Oslo 1. What options are open to

More information

International Patent Litigation and Jurisdiction. Study of Hypothetical Question 1 Under the Hague Draft Convention and Japanese Laws

International Patent Litigation and Jurisdiction. Study of Hypothetical Question 1 Under the Hague Draft Convention and Japanese Laws International Patent Litigation and Jurisdiction Study of Hypothetical Question 1 Under the Hague Draft Convention and Japanese Laws Yoshio Kumakura Attorney at Law Nakamura & Partners 1 The 1999 Draft

More information

GLOSSARY OF PATENT TERMINOLOGY

GLOSSARY OF PATENT TERMINOLOGY Economic Analysis and Statistics Division Directorate for Science, Technology and Industry GLOSSARY OF PATENT TERMINOLOGY Applicant...2 Applicant country...2 Application for a patent...2 Application date...2

More information

IP Litigation in Europe and in Germany

IP Litigation in Europe and in Germany & P A R T N E R P A T E N T A T T O R N E Y S D Ü S S E L D O R F M U N I C H IP Litigation in Europe and in Germany Dr. Dirk Schulz Outline - Patent litigation in Europe - German patent litigation system

More information

IP-Litigation in Germany. German and European Patent, Trademark and Design Attorneys Lawyers

IP-Litigation in Germany. German and European Patent, Trademark and Design Attorneys Lawyers IP-Litigation in Germany German and European Patent, Trademark and Design Attorneys Lawyers What is a litigation team in Germany? In contrast to litigation procedures in certain jurisdictions, in particular

More information

Patent Litigation in Europe - Presence and Future

Patent Litigation in Europe - Presence and Future Patent Litigation in Europe - Presence and Future Innovation Support Training Program (ISTP) Module 2 / November 27, 2006 Christian W. Appelt German and European Patent and Trademark Attorney Patent Litigation

More information

Two Papers on Internet Connectivity and Quality. Abstract

Two Papers on Internet Connectivity and Quality. Abstract Two Papers on Internet Connectivity and Quality ROBERTO ROSON Dipartimento di Scienze Economiche, Università Ca Foscari di Venezia, Venice, Italy. Abstract I review two papers, addressing the issue of

More information

PATENT INFORMATION AND CORPORATE CREDIT RATINGS: AN EMPIRICAL STUDY OF PATENT VALUATION BY CREDIT RATING AGENCIES

PATENT INFORMATION AND CORPORATE CREDIT RATINGS: AN EMPIRICAL STUDY OF PATENT VALUATION BY CREDIT RATING AGENCIES PATENT INFORMATION AND CORPORATE CREDIT RATINGS: AN EMPIRICAL STUDY OF PATENT VALUATION BY CREDIT RATING AGENCIES Peter Neuhaeusler, Carl Benedikt Frey, Knut Blind Patent Statistics for Decision Makers

More information

HARVARD. Lucian Arye Bebchuk. Discussion Paper No. 226 12/1997. As published in 3 The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics and the Law 551-554 (1998)

HARVARD. Lucian Arye Bebchuk. Discussion Paper No. 226 12/1997. As published in 3 The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics and the Law 551-554 (1998) ISSN 1045-6333 HARVARD JOHN M. OLIN CENTER FOR LAW, ECONOMICS, AND BUSINESS SUITS WITH NEGATIVE EXPECTED VALUE Lucian Arye Bebchuk Discussion Paper No. 226 12/1997 As published in 3 The New Palgrave Dictionary

More information

Knowledge. Practical guide to competition damages claims in the UK

Knowledge. Practical guide to competition damages claims in the UK Knowledge Practical guide to competition damages claims in the UK Practical guide to competition damages claims in the UK Contents Reforms to damages litigation in the UK for infringements of competition

More information

LEGAL PROTECTION INSURANCE THE PROBLEMS TO BE SOLVED. Jean-Marie Rutsaert (B) Comité Européen des Assurances

LEGAL PROTECTION INSURANCE THE PROBLEMS TO BE SOLVED. Jean-Marie Rutsaert (B) Comité Européen des Assurances LEGAL PROTECTION INSURANCE THE PROBLEMS TO BE SOLVED Jean-Marie Rutsaert (B) Comité Européen des Assurances BRIEF OVERVIEW OF LEGAL PROTECTION INSURANCE IN EUROPE On most European insurance markets (with

More information

Finland. Contributing firm Roschier Brands, Attorneys Ltd

Finland. Contributing firm Roschier Brands, Attorneys Ltd Finland Contributing firm Roschier Brands, Attorneys Ltd Author Asta Uhlbäck Legal framework Finnish design registrations are regulated by the Registered Designs Act (221/1971), as amended. The act is

More information

Efficient alternative dispute resolution (ADR) for intellectual property disputes

Efficient alternative dispute resolution (ADR) for intellectual property disputes 13.1 Efficient alternative dispute resolution (ADR) for intellectual property disputes More and more rights holders are recognizing the benefits of using private neutral mechanisms that allow parties to

More information

Present Situation of IP Disputes in Japan

Present Situation of IP Disputes in Japan Present Situation of IP Disputes in Japan Feb 19, 2014 Chief Judge Toshiaki Iimura 1 1 IP High Court established -Apr.1.2005- l Appeal cases related to patent rights etc. from district courts nationwide

More information

Intellectual Property Right Protection in the Software Market

Intellectual Property Right Protection in the Software Market Intellectual Property Right Protection in the Software Market Yasuhiro Arai Aomori Public College 153-4, Yamazaki, Goushizawa, Aomori-city, Aomori 030-0196, Japan March 01 Abstract We discuss the software

More information

Patent Litigation Insurance

Patent Litigation Insurance Business School W O R K I N G P A P E R S E R I E S Working Paper 2015-621 Patent Litigation Insurance Anne Duchêne http://www.ipag.fr/fr/accueil/la-recherche/publications-wp.html IPAG Business School

More information

COUNCIL OF THE EUROPEAN UNION. Brussels, 29 September 2009 13707/09 LIMITE PI 93

COUNCIL OF THE EUROPEAN UNION. Brussels, 29 September 2009 13707/09 LIMITE PI 93 COUNCIL OF THE EUROPEAN UNION Brussels, 29 September 2009 13707/09 LIMITE PI 93 WORKING DOCUMENT from: General Secretariat of the Council to: Working Party on Intellectual Property (Patents) No. prev.

More information

The Consolidate Patents Act 1)

The Consolidate Patents Act 1) Consolidate Act No. 108 of 24 January 2012 The Consolidate Patents Act 1) Publication of the Patents Act, cf. Consolidate Act No. 91 of 28 January 2009 as amended by section 20 of Act No. 579 of 1 June

More information

Strategies for Worldwide Patent Litigation. Moderator: John R. Thomas Panelists: Trevor M. Cook, Jamison E. Lynch, Mark D. Selwyn

Strategies for Worldwide Patent Litigation. Moderator: John R. Thomas Panelists: Trevor M. Cook, Jamison E. Lynch, Mark D. Selwyn Strategies for Worldwide Patent Litigation Moderator: John R. Thomas Panelists: Trevor M. Cook, Jamison E. Lynch, Mark D. Selwyn Global IP Litigation Strategy: Why Is It Important? Trend toward globalization

More information

How To Plan A Patent Portfolio

How To Plan A Patent Portfolio Patent Strategy for Emerging Companies Enterprise Works University of Illinois July 12, 2011 Chirag Shah CEO Mogambo Solutions alexandria chicago minneapolis champaign Outline Business and Patent Portfolio

More information

IN THE UNITED STATES BANKRUPTCY COURT FOR THE DISTRICT OF DELAWARE MEMORANDUM OPINION 2

IN THE UNITED STATES BANKRUPTCY COURT FOR THE DISTRICT OF DELAWARE MEMORANDUM OPINION 2 IN THE UNITED STATES BANKRUPTCY COURT FOR THE DISTRICT OF DELAWARE IN RE: Specialty Products Holdings Corp., et al. Bankruptcy No. 10-11780 Debtor(s) 1 Chapter 11 (Jointly Administered) Related to Doc.

More information

Resolving IP and Technology Disputes Through WIPO ADR. Getting back to business

Resolving IP and Technology Disputes Through WIPO ADR. Getting back to business Resolving IP and Technology Disputes Through WIPO ADR Getting back to business Intellectual property (IP) is a central component of today s knowledge economy, and its efficient exploitation is of growing

More information

LESSONS FOR PATENT POLICY FROM EMPIRICAL RESEARCH ON PATENT LITIGATION

LESSONS FOR PATENT POLICY FROM EMPIRICAL RESEARCH ON PATENT LITIGATION LESSONS FOR PATENT POLICY FROM EMPIRICAL RESEARCH ON PATENT LITIGATION by James Bessen * Michael J. Meurer ** This Article reviews empirical patent litigation research to reveal patent policy lessons.

More information

THE EFFECT OF SETTLEMENT IN KAPLOW S MULTISTAGE ADJUDICATION

THE EFFECT OF SETTLEMENT IN KAPLOW S MULTISTAGE ADJUDICATION THE EFFECT OF SETTLEMENT IN KAPLOW S MULTISTAGE ADJUDICATION Abraham L. Wickelgren Professor Louis Kaplow s article, Multistage Adjudication, presents an extremely useful framework for thinking about how

More information

U.S. DEPARTMENT OF JUSTICE/FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION WORKSHOP AND COMMENT PROCEEDING ON PATENT ASSERTION ENTITIES

U.S. DEPARTMENT OF JUSTICE/FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION WORKSHOP AND COMMENT PROCEEDING ON PATENT ASSERTION ENTITIES U.S. DEPARTMENT OF JUSTICE/FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION WORKSHOP AND COMMENT PROCEEDING ON PATENT ASSERTION ENTITIES COMMENTS OF THE APPLICATION DEVELOPERS ALLIANCE The Application Developers Alliance ( Alliance

More information

Yearbook. Building IP value in the 21st century. Taking a ride on the Birthday Train. KUHNEN & WACKER Intellectual Property Law Firm Christian Thomas

Yearbook. Building IP value in the 21st century. Taking a ride on the Birthday Train. KUHNEN & WACKER Intellectual Property Law Firm Christian Thomas Published by Yearbook 2016 Building IP value in the 21st century Taking a ride on the Birthday Train KUHNEN & WACKER Intellectual Property Law Firm Christian Thomas KUHNEN & WACKER Intellectual Property

More information

Patents in Europe 2015/2016

Patents in Europe 2015/2016 In association with The proposed structure of the Unified Patent Court system in Europe Rainer K Kuhnen, KUHNEN & WACKER Intellectual Property Law Firm Patents in Europe 2015/2016 Helping business compete

More information

Patent Litigation. Quick Guide to Proceedings in Germany HEUKING KÜHN LÜER WOJTEK

Patent Litigation. Quick Guide to Proceedings in Germany HEUKING KÜHN LÜER WOJTEK Patent Litigation Quick Guide to Proceedings in Germany HEUKING KÜHN LÜER WOJTEK Table of Contents I. Advantages of litigating in Germany 3 II. Patent Litigation System 4 III. Infringement and Nullity

More information

SYLLABUS FOR THREE MONTHS INSTITUTIONAL TRAINING OF EXAMINERS OF PATENTS & DESIGNS

SYLLABUS FOR THREE MONTHS INSTITUTIONAL TRAINING OF EXAMINERS OF PATENTS & DESIGNS SYLLABUS FOR THREE MONTHS INSTITUTIONAL TRAINING OF EXAMINERS OF PATENTS & DESIGNS INDEX Module Duration Page No.. Introduction to the Intellectual Property Rights. week 7 Day Role of IP in business and

More information

IPR Policy as Strategy ISBN: 978-3-945185-04-9. December 2015. The Battle to Define the Meaning of FRAND

IPR Policy as Strategy ISBN: 978-3-945185-04-9. December 2015. The Battle to Define the Meaning of FRAND December 2015 ISBN: 978-3-945185-04-9 IPR Policy as Strategy The Battle to Define the Meaning of FRAND Bowman Heiden Center for Intellectual Property (CIP) Department of Technology Management and Economics

More information

U.S. Litigation (Strategic Preparations and Statistics)

U.S. Litigation (Strategic Preparations and Statistics) U.S. Litigation (Strategic Preparations and Statistics) Thomas K. Scherer Federal and State Court, ITC actions Considerations of speed and remedies involved Eastern District of Texas Considerations of

More information

Patents for software?

Patents for software? European Patent Office Munich Headquarters Erhardtstr. 27 80469 Munich Germany Tel. + 49 (0) 89 2399-0 Fax + 49 (0) 89 2399-4560 The Hague Patentlaan 2 2288 EE Rijswijk Netherlands Tel. + 31 (0) 70 340-2040

More information

Cases COMP/AT.39740 Google Google s revised proposed commitments BEUC response to the questionnaire

Cases COMP/AT.39740 Google Google s revised proposed commitments BEUC response to the questionnaire Cases COMP/AT.39740 Google Google s revised proposed commitments BEUC response to the questionnaire Contact: Kostas Rossoglou/ Augusta Maciulevičiũtě digital@beuc.eu Ref.: X/2013/078-25/11/2013 BUREAU

More information

Would the U.S. Benefit from Patent Post-grant Reviews? Evidence from a 'Twinning' Study

Would the U.S. Benefit from Patent Post-grant Reviews? Evidence from a 'Twinning' Study Would the U.S. Benefit from Patent Post-grant Reviews? Evidence from a 'Twinning' Study Stuart J.H. Graham* and Dietmar Harhoff** *Georgia Institute of Technology **University of Munich, CEPR and ZEW June

More information

IN THE INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY HIGH COURT OF JAPAN. Defendant.

IN THE INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY HIGH COURT OF JAPAN. Defendant. IN THE INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY HIGH COURT OF JAPAN APPLE JAPAN S SUCCESSOR OF SUIT, APPLE JAPAN LLC. Plaintiff, v. SAMSUNG ELECTRONICS CORP. Defendant. SUBMISSION OF PROFESSOR DANIEL F. SPULBER IN RESPONSE

More information

Inspections and Access to Evidence in

Inspections and Access to Evidence in Inspections and Access to Evidence in Patent Litigation 10 th Annual Conference on Intellectual Property Law & Policy at Fordham IP Law Institute April, 12 th 2012, New York by Dr. Klaus Grabinski Judge

More information

Patent Litigation. Inventions of mission and additional remuneration due to the inventor for such inventions

Patent Litigation. Inventions of mission and additional remuneration due to the inventor for such inventions PATENTS Patent Litigation The most interesting Court decisions concerning patent litigations published in 2004 and early in 2005 focus on employee s inventions, on a French style file wrapper estoppel

More information

ESMT BUSINESS BRIEF. Exploitative Abuses. Lars-Hendrik Röller, ESMT. ESMT No. BB-107-002 ISSN 1866 4024

ESMT BUSINESS BRIEF. Exploitative Abuses. Lars-Hendrik Röller, ESMT. ESMT No. BB-107-002 ISSN 1866 4024 Business Brief Consolidation Index: Critical Success Factors for Industry Consolidation 1 ESMT No. BB-107-002 ESMT BUSINESS BRIEF Lars-Hendrik Röller, ESMT ISSN 1866 4024 2 Business Brief Consolidation

More information

The revival of crossborder

The revival of crossborder The revival of crossborder injunctions The European Court of Justice recently breathed new life into the phenomenon of cross-border injunctions a cost-effective tool originally developed by the Dutch courts

More information

Guide to WIPO Services

Guide to WIPO Services World Intellectual Property Organization Guide to WIPO Services Helping you protect inventions, trademarks & designs resolve domain name & other IP disputes The World Intellectual Property Organization

More information

Litigation and Settlement in Patent Infringement Cases

Litigation and Settlement in Patent Infringement Cases Litigation and Settlement in Patent Infringement Cases Claude Crampes and Corinne Langinier July 2001 Abstract A patent is not a perfect protection against imitation. It only grants the patentholder the

More information

The Software Patent Experiment *

The Software Patent Experiment * The Software Patent Experiment * BY ROBERT HUNT AND JAMES BESSEN O ver the past two decades, the scope of technologies that can be patented has been expanded to include many items previously thought unsuitable

More information

Response to European Commission inquiry into the European business insurance sector pursuant to Article 17 of Regulation 1/2003

Response to European Commission inquiry into the European business insurance sector pursuant to Article 17 of Regulation 1/2003 Response to European Commission inquiry into the European business insurance sector pursuant to Article 17 of Regulation 1/2003 Executive summary The ABI believes the Commission is correct to place business

More information

BOSTON UNIVERSITY SCHOOL OF LAW

BOSTON UNIVERSITY SCHOOL OF LAW BOSTON UNIVERSITY SCHOOL OF LAW WORKING PAPER SERIES, LAW AND ECONOMICS WORKING PAPER NO. 06-13 A COMMENT ON DO PATENTS FACILITATE FINANCING IN THE SOFTWARE INDUSTRY? JAMES E. BESSEN The Boston University

More information

ETSI Guidelines for Antitrust Compliance Version adopted by Board #81 on 27 January 2011

ETSI Guidelines for Antitrust Compliance Version adopted by Board #81 on 27 January 2011 Page 71 ETSI Guidelines for Antitrust Compliance Version adopted by Board #81 on 27 January 2011 A Introduction ETSI, with over 700 member companies from more than 60 countries, is the leading body for

More information

The trademark lawyer as brand manager

The trademark lawyer as brand manager The trademark lawyer as brand manager This text first appeared in the IAM magazine supplement Brands in the Boardroom 2005 May 2005 For further information please visit www.iam-magazine.com Feature The

More information

The Benefits of Patent Settlements: New Survey Evidence on Factors Affecting Generic Drug Investment

The Benefits of Patent Settlements: New Survey Evidence on Factors Affecting Generic Drug Investment The Benefits of Patent Settlements: New Survey Evidence on Factors Affecting Generic Drug Investment by Bret Dickey 1 Jonathan Orszag 2 July 23, 2013 3 1 Bret Dickey is an Executive Vice President with

More information

STEERING COMMITTEE ON THE MEDIA AND NEW COMMUNICATION SERVICES (CDMC)

STEERING COMMITTEE ON THE MEDIA AND NEW COMMUNICATION SERVICES (CDMC) Strasbourg, 9 January 2012 CDMC(2011)018Rev8 STEERING COMMITTEE ON THE MEDIA AND NEW COMMUNICATION SERVICES (CDMC) Draft declaration of the Committee of Ministers on the desirability of international standards

More information

Innovation in the Shadow of Patent Litigation

Innovation in the Shadow of Patent Litigation Innovation in the Shadow of Patent Litigation Yann Ménière, Sarah Parlane To cite this version: Yann Ménière, Sarah Parlane. Innovation in the Shadow of Patent Litigation. Review of Industrial Organization,

More information

Marketing Ingenuity and Invention an Innovation Guidebook

Marketing Ingenuity and Invention an Innovation Guidebook The following is an extraction from Marketing Ingenuity and Invention: an Innovation Guidebook, a publication from the Wisconsin Innovation Service Center. Marketing Ingenuity and Invention an Innovation

More information

Intellectual Property Rights in the USA

Intellectual Property Rights in the USA Intellectual Property Rights in the USA Intellectual Property Office is an operating name of the Patent Office Contents Intellectual property rights in the USA What are intellectual property rights? International

More information

Insurance claims and losses in Spain. Procedural aspects of the Spanish legal system

Insurance claims and losses in Spain. Procedural aspects of the Spanish legal system Insurance claims and losses in Spain. Procedural aspects of the Spanish legal system Further information If you would like further information, please contact a person mentioned below or the person with

More information

Credit Card Market Study Interim Report: Annex 4 Switching Analysis

Credit Card Market Study Interim Report: Annex 4 Switching Analysis MS14/6.2: Annex 4 Market Study Interim Report: Annex 4 November 2015 This annex describes data analysis we carried out to improve our understanding of switching and shopping around behaviour in the UK

More information

Hasty compromise could be costly. Potential gains from EU Patent large. The value of a well-designed EU Patent. CPB Policy Brief 2012/05

Hasty compromise could be costly. Potential gains from EU Patent large. The value of a well-designed EU Patent. CPB Policy Brief 2012/05 Potential gains from EU Patent large Hasty compromise could be costly CPB Policy Brief 2012/05 The value of a well-designed EU Patent Bas Straathof Sander van Veldhuizen Henry van der Wiel The value of

More information

STATISTICAL SIGNIFICANCE AND THE STANDARD OF PROOF IN ANTITRUST DAMAGE QUANTIFICATION

STATISTICAL SIGNIFICANCE AND THE STANDARD OF PROOF IN ANTITRUST DAMAGE QUANTIFICATION Lear Competition Note STATISTICAL SIGNIFICANCE AND THE STANDARD OF PROOF IN ANTITRUST DAMAGE QUANTIFICATION Nov 2013 Econometric techniques can play an important role in damage quantification cases for

More information

Five years of trademark opposition in Benelux: a review. Nederlandsch Octrooibureau

Five years of trademark opposition in Benelux: a review. Nederlandsch Octrooibureau Five years of trademark opposition in Benelux: a review Nederlandsch Octrooibureau Five years of trademark opposition in Benelux: a review Although there are certain limitations to the Benelux opposition

More information

Credible Discovery, Settlement, and Negative Expected Value Suits

Credible Discovery, Settlement, and Negative Expected Value Suits Credible iscovery, Settlement, and Negative Expected Value Suits Warren F. Schwartz Abraham L. Wickelgren Abstract: This paper introduces the option to conduct discovery into a model of settlement bargaining

More information

ASEAN IPR SME Helpdesk Guide: Protecting your IP at Trade Fairs in Southeast Asia. Contents. 1. Protecting your IP at trade fairs. 2.

ASEAN IPR SME Helpdesk Guide: Protecting your IP at Trade Fairs in Southeast Asia. Contents. 1. Protecting your IP at trade fairs. 2. ASEAN IPR SME Helpdesk Guide: Protecting your IP at Trade Fairs in Southeast Asia Contents 1. Protecting your IP at trade fairs 2. Advance planning 3. Attending the trade fair 4. Taking action against

More information

Competing for the Market and the Market for Ideas: Antitrust & Innovation Policy Implications

Competing for the Market and the Market for Ideas: Antitrust & Innovation Policy Implications Competing for the Market and the Market for Ideas: Antitrust & Innovation Policy Implications Scott Stern, MIT, Northwestern, and NBER Joshua Gans, University of Melbourne FTC Microeconomics Conference,

More information

The basics of an Intellectual Property Program

The basics of an Intellectual Property Program Technology Insights The basics of an Intellectual Property Program Inside: Features of an Intellectual Property Program What is intellectual property? Role of CEOs and CFOs Foreign patents or copyrights

More information

Making a cross border claim in the EU

Making a cross border claim in the EU Making a cross border claim in the EU serving the community through the administration of justice Using the European Order for Payment procedure or the European Small Claims procedure Version: 2.0 Date

More information

INTERNET USAGE AND THE POTENTIAL EFFECT IN YOUR MANAGEMENT OF YOUR PATENT PROGRAM. Steven D. Hemminger. Lyon & Lyon, LLP

INTERNET USAGE AND THE POTENTIAL EFFECT IN YOUR MANAGEMENT OF YOUR PATENT PROGRAM. Steven D. Hemminger. Lyon & Lyon, LLP INTERNET USAGE AND THE POTENTIAL EFFECT IN YOUR MANAGEMENT OF YOUR PATENT PROGRAM Steven D. Hemminger Lyon & Lyon, LLP {1} Much has been written and said about the Internet and the benefits for a company

More information

GADSBY WICKS SOLICITORS EXPLANATION OF LEGAL TERMS

GADSBY WICKS SOLICITORS EXPLANATION OF LEGAL TERMS EXPLANATION OF LEGAL TERMS Affidavit: After the event litigation insurance: Application notice: Bar Council: Barrister: Basic Charges: Before the Event Legal Expenses Insurance: Bill of costs: Bolam test:

More information

All About Motions To Dismiss

All About Motions To Dismiss All About Motions To Dismiss Edna Sussman Motions to dismiss can be big winners or big losers. IT CAN BE one of the most satisfying experiences for a litigator. You pinpointed the fatal flaw in your opponent

More information

ECOLE DES MINES DE PARIS Collège doctoral T H E S E. pour obtenir le grade de Docteur de l École des Mines de Paris Spécialité «Économie industrielle»

ECOLE DES MINES DE PARIS Collège doctoral T H E S E. pour obtenir le grade de Docteur de l École des Mines de Paris Spécialité «Économie industrielle» ECOLE DES MINES DE PARIS Collège doctoral N attribué par la bibliothèque T H E S E pour obtenir le grade de Docteur de l École des Mines de Paris Spécialité «Économie industrielle» présentée et soutenue

More information

How To Price Bundle On Cable Television

How To Price Bundle On Cable Television K. Bundling Brown and in Cable P. J. Alexander Television Bundling in Cable Television: A Pedagogical Note With a Policy Option Keith Brown and Peter J. Alexander Federal Communications Commission, USA

More information

Insolvency of members of a group of companies

Insolvency of members of a group of companies Comments to the new EU regulation on insolvency proceedings Insolvency of members of a group of companies Alberto Díaz Moreno Professor of Corporate & Commercial Law, Universidad de Sevilla Academic Counsel,

More information

Case 8:04-cv-01787-MJG Document 142 Filed 08/16/05 Page 1 of 20 IN THE UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT FOR THE DISTRICT OF MARYLAND

Case 8:04-cv-01787-MJG Document 142 Filed 08/16/05 Page 1 of 20 IN THE UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT FOR THE DISTRICT OF MARYLAND Case 8:04-cv-01787-MJG Document 142 Filed 08/16/05 Page 1 of 20 IN THE UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT FOR THE DISTRICT OF MARYLAND DR. MARC L. KOZAM * d/b/a MLK SOFTWARE, et al. * Plaintiffs * vs. CIVIL

More information

An Enhanced European Patent System

An Enhanced European Patent System An Enhanced European Patent System The Select Committee The Preparatory Committee An Enhanced European Patent System In December 2012 the Council of the European Union and the European Parliament agreed

More information

TACD RECOMMENDATIONS ON HEALTH CARE AND INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY AND EUROPEAN COMMISSION SERVICES RESPONSES

TACD RECOMMENDATIONS ON HEALTH CARE AND INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY AND EUROPEAN COMMISSION SERVICES RESPONSES TRANSATLANTIC CONSUMER DIALOGUE WASHINGTON MEETING, 10-12 FEBRUARY 2000 TACD RECOMMENDATIONS ON HEALTH CARE AND INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY AND EUROPEAN COMMISSION SERVICES RESPONSES The Commission Services

More information

Idiosyncrasies of the Software Development Process and their Relation to Software Patents: Theoretical Considerations and Empirical Evidence

Idiosyncrasies of the Software Development Process and their Relation to Software Patents: Theoretical Considerations and Empirical Evidence Idiosyncrasies of the Software Development Process and their Relation to Software Patents: Theoretical Considerations and Empirical Evidence Knut Blind and Jakob Edler Fraunhofer Institute for Systems

More information

A primer in Entrepreneurship

A primer in Entrepreneurship Prof. Dr. Institutefor Strategy and Business Economics Where we are: Step 1 Step 2 Developing Successful Business Ideas 2008 Prentice Hall Chapter 5: Industry and Competitor Analysis Table of Contents

More information

IN THE APPELLATE COURT OF ILLINOIS FIRST DISTRICT

IN THE APPELLATE COURT OF ILLINOIS FIRST DISTRICT 2016 IL App (1st) 150810-U Nos. 1-15-0810, 1-15-0942 cons. Fourth Division June 30, 2016 NOTICE: This order was filed under Supreme Court Rule 23 and may not be cited as precedent by any party except in

More information

Global Guide to Competition Litigation Poland

Global Guide to Competition Litigation Poland Global Guide to Competition Litigation Poland 2012 Table of Contents Availability of private enforcement in respect of competition law infringements and jurisdiction... 1 Conduct of proceedings and costs...

More information

COMMISSION RECOMMENDATION. of 12.3.2014. on a new approach to business failure and insolvency. (Text with EEA relevance) {SWD(2014) 61} {SWD(2014) 62}

COMMISSION RECOMMENDATION. of 12.3.2014. on a new approach to business failure and insolvency. (Text with EEA relevance) {SWD(2014) 61} {SWD(2014) 62} EUROPEAN COMMISSION Brussels, 12.3.2014 C(2014) 1500 final COMMISSION RECOMMENDATION of 12.3.2014 on a new approach to business failure and insolvency (Text with EEA relevance) {SWD(2014) 61} {SWD(2014)

More information

FSFE response to Consultation on Patents and Standards: A modern framework for standardisation involving intellectual property rights

FSFE response to Consultation on Patents and Standards: A modern framework for standardisation involving intellectual property rights European Commission, DG Enterprise and Industry Unit A4 - Industrial Competitiveness Policy for Growth Avenue d'auderghem 45, 1040 Bruxelles, Belgium FSFE response to Consultation on Patents and Standards:

More information

Differentiated IP Regimes for Environmental & Climate Technologies. Keith Maskus ICCG ICARUS International Workshop Venice, May 20, 2011

Differentiated IP Regimes for Environmental & Climate Technologies. Keith Maskus ICCG ICARUS International Workshop Venice, May 20, 2011 Differentiated IP Regimes for Environmental & Climate Technologies Keith Maskus ICCG ICARUS International Workshop Venice, May 20, 2011 Background Critical needs for new mitigation and adaptation technologies.

More information

(Notices) COUNCIL AGREEMENT. on a Unified Patent Court (2013/C 175/01)

(Notices) COUNCIL AGREEMENT. on a Unified Patent Court (2013/C 175/01) 20.6.2013 Official Journal of the European Union C 175/1 IV (Notices) NOTICES FROM EUROPEAN UNION INSTITUTIONS, BODIES, OFFICES AND AGENCIES COUNCIL AGREEMENT on a Unified Patent Court (2013/C 175/01)

More information

RULES OFTHE COURT OF ARBITRATION IN MATTERS CONCERNING INTERNET DOMAIN NAMES AT THE POLISH CHAMBER OF INFORMATION TECHNOLOGY AND TELECOMMUNICATIONS

RULES OFTHE COURT OF ARBITRATION IN MATTERS CONCERNING INTERNET DOMAIN NAMES AT THE POLISH CHAMBER OF INFORMATION TECHNOLOGY AND TELECOMMUNICATIONS RULES OFTHE COURT OF ARBITRATION IN MATTERS CONCERNING INTERNET DOMAIN NAMES AT THE POLISH CHAMBER OF INFORMATION TECHNOLOGY AND TELECOMMUNICATIONS The following provisions constitute the Rules Court of

More information

Table of Contents CLAUDIA MILBRADT 1 ANETTE GARTNER 3

Table of Contents CLAUDIA MILBRADT 1 ANETTE GARTNER 3 Table of Contents 1. Introduction CLAUDIA MILBRADT 1 2. The European Patent with Unitary Effect and its Enforcement ANETTE GARTNER 3 2.1 Background 4 2.1.1 The European Patent: A "Bundle" of National Patents

More information

Patents for software?

Patents for software? Where to get additional help Visit our website www.epo.org Patents for software? European law and practice > Patent search on www.epo.org/espacenet > European Patent Register on www.epo.org/register >

More information

A primer in Entrepreneurship

A primer in Entrepreneurship Prof. Dr. Institute for Strategy and Business Economics Spring semester2008 Chapter 5: Industry and Competitor Analysis Table of Contents I. Industry Analysis II. IV. The Importance of Industry Versus

More information

Application of Patent Litigation Strategies to Biosimilars: Is there a difference?

Application of Patent Litigation Strategies to Biosimilars: Is there a difference? Application of Patent Litigation Strategies to Biosimilars: Is there a difference? Kristof Roox, Partner Crowell & Moring Brussels (kroox@crowell.com) November 19, 2009 Berlin, Germany I. Overview of strategies

More information

LexisNexis CourtLink Best Practice Guide

LexisNexis CourtLink Best Practice Guide LexisNexis CourtLink Best Practice Guide What is LexisNexis CourtLink? It s a better way to perform docket and document research and gather critical intelligence on key players. It also makes it easy to

More information

between Italy and Switzerland

between Italy and Switzerland Roadmap on the Way Forward in Fiscal and Financial Issues between Italy and Switzerland Taking note of the recent developments in the area of international taxation, in particular: the commitment of the

More information

Dutch Unfair Prejudice. And. Collective claim Proceedings

Dutch Unfair Prejudice. And. Collective claim Proceedings Dutch Unfair Prejudice And Collective claim Proceedings Höcker Advocaten, The Netherlands Yvette Borrius SHORT INTRODUCTION DUTCH REMEDIES UNFAIR PREJUDICE The most effective mechanism at the disposal

More information