Optimal Income Taxation: Mirrlees Meets Ramsey



Similar documents
How To Find Out If A Tax System Is More Efficient

Research Division Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Working Paper Series

On the Consequences of Eliminating Capital Tax Differentials

On the Consequences of Eliminating Capital Tax Differentials

New Dynamic Public Finance. Mikhail Golosov (Yale, New Economic School, and NBER) Aleh Tsyvinski (Yale, New Economic School, and NBER)

Insurance and Opportunities: The Welfare Implications of Rising Wage Dispersion

Insurance and Opportunities: The Welfare Implications of Rising Wage Dispersion

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES TAX BUYOUTS. Marco Del Negro Fabrizio Perri Fabiano Schivardi. Working Paper

Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Reports

Insurance and Opportunities: A Welfare Analysis of Labor Market Risk

Optimal fiscal policy under commitment

Insurance and Taxation over the Life Cycle

Optimal Taxation in a Limited Commitment Economy

Tax Buyouts. Marco Del Negro Federal Reserve Bank of New York

Intermediate Macroeconomics: The Real Business Cycle Model

Insurance and Opportunities: The Welfare Implications of Rising Wage Dispersion

Optimal Age Specific Income Taxation

Optimal Taxation in Theory and Practice

High Marginal Tax Rates on the Top 1%?

Paternalism vs Redistribution: Designing Retirement Savings Policies with Behavioral Agents

College Pricing and Income Inequality

Theoretical Tools of Public Economics. Part-2

Chapter 3: The effect of taxation on behaviour. Alain Trannoy AMSE & EHESS

Social Insurance with Private Insurance Markets. 2 Social Insurance with Endogenous Private Insurance

Notes on Papers on Public Debt & Dynamic Public Finance

Human Capital Risk, Contract Enforcement, and the Macroeconomy

Sustainable Social Security: Four Options

Pareto Efficient Income Taxation with Stochastic Abilities

Optimal Income Taxation with Multidimensional Types

Is There Too Much Inequality in Health Spending Across Income Groups?

Employment Protection and Business Cycles in Emerging Economies

Lecture 3: Growth with Overlapping Generations (Acemoglu 2009, Chapter 9, adapted from Zilibotti)

Behavioral responses to inheritance tax: Evidence from notches in France

On the Effects of Tax-deferred Saving Accounts

UNIVERSITY OF OSLO DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS

Moral Hazard. Itay Goldstein. Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania

Health Insurance Reform: The impact of a Medicare Buy-In

The Life Insurance Demand in a Heterogeneous-Agent Life Cycle Economy

Deposit Insurance without Commitment by Russell Cooper and Hubert Kempf Discussion

Efficiency and Equity

The Taxable Income Elasticity and the Implications of Tax Evasion for Deadweight Loss. Jon Bakija, April 2011

Gains from Trade: The Role of Composition

Wealth vs. Income Taxes in a Model of Credit Constraints and Inequality

Female labor supply as insurance against idiosyncratic risk

Statistics in Retail Finance. Chapter 6: Behavioural models

The Provision of Public Universal Health Insurance: Impacts on Private Insurance, Asset Holdings and Welfare

Segmented Asset Markets and the Distribution of Wealth

How Much Consumption Insurance Beyond Self-Insurance? *

On the Efficiency of Competitive Stock Markets Where Traders Have Diverse Information

LONGEVITY AND ANNUITIES: AN INTRODUCTION

Quantifying the Ine±ciency of the US Social Security System

Optimal Income Taxation with Adverse Selection in the Labor Market

The Elasticity of Taxable Income and the Implications of Tax Evasion for Deadweight Loss

SHARING DEMOGRAPHIC RISK WHO IS AFRAID OF THE BABY BUST?

Welfare Costs of Inflation in a Menu Cost Model

Reaching Universal Health Coverage. through Tax-based Financing Schemes: Challenges of Informal Economy and. Population Ageing

Health Insurance Reform: The impact of a Medicare Buy-In

The Redistributive Benefits of Progressive Labor and Capital Income Taxation, or: How to Best Screw the Top 1%

On the Provision of Insurance Against Search-Induced Wage Fluctuations

Reducing Government Debt in the Presence of Inequality

Notes on indifference curve analysis of the choice between leisure and labor, and the deadweight loss of taxation. Jon Bakija

Reforming the Tax System Lecture II: The Taxation of Savings. December 2015 Richard Blundell University College London

Real Business Cycles. Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Research Department Staff Report 370. February Ellen R. McGrattan

The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis

Cross-subsidization in employer-based health insurance and the effects of tax subsidy reform

Intergenerational Persistence of Earnings: The Role of Early and College Education

Lecture notes on Moral Hazard, i.e. the Hidden Action Principle-Agent Model

Health Insurance Reform: The impact of a Medicare Buy-In

Reducing Government Debt in the Presence of Inequality

3 Price Discrimination

The RBC methodology also comes down to two principles:

Parameter and Model Uncertainties in Pricing Deep-deferred Annuities

Cross-subsidization in employer-based health insurance and the effects of tax subsidy reform

Universidad de Montevideo Macroeconomia II. The Ramsey-Cass-Koopmans Model

Bailouts and Financial Innovation: Market Completion Versus Rent Extraction

The Real Business Cycle Model

Thomas Piketty Academic year

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

Optimal Taxation with Permanent Employment Contracts

The Case for a Progressive Tax: From Basic Research to Policy Recommendations

Non-exclusive Dynamic Contracts, Competition, and the Limits of Insurance

3 The Standard Real Business Cycle (RBC) Model. Optimal growth model + Labor decisions

The Optimal Taxation of Height: A Case Study of Utilitarian Income Redistribution

VI. Real Business Cycles Models

Graduate Macro Theory II: The Real Business Cycle Model

Asset Prices And Asset Quantities

HARVARD JOHN M. OLIN CENTER FOR LAW, ECONOMICS, AND BUSINESS

Unemployment Insurance Savings Accounts in a life-cycle model with job search

Volatility, Productivity Correlations and Measures of. International Consumption Risk Sharing.

Public Insurance against Idiosyncratic and Aggregate Risk: The Case of Social Security and Progressive Income Taxation

The Cost of Financial Frictions for Life Insurers

Comparing return to work outcomes between vocational rehabilitation providers after adjusting for case mix using statistical models

Real Business Cycle Models

WORKING PAPER NO PRIVATE EQUITY PREMIUM IN A GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM MODEL OF UNINSURABLE INVESTMENT RISK

Optimal Social Insurance Design: UI Benefit Levels

Health Insurance and Retirement Incentives

Tail-Dependence an Essential Factor for Correctly Measuring the Benefits of Diversification

Class Notes, Econ 8801 Lump Sum Taxes are Awesome

Optimal Unemployment Insurance with Sequential Search

How Much Insurance in Bewley Models? *

Transcription:

Optimal Income Taxation: Mirrlees Meets Ramsey Jonathan Heathcote FRB Minneapolis Hitoshi Tsujiyama Goethe University Frankfurt Ohio State University, April 17 2014

The views expressed herein are those of the authors and not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis or the Federal Reserve System

How should we tax income? What structure of labor income taxation offers best trade-off between benefits of public insurance and costs of distortionary taxes? Systems currently in place combine: Tax rates that increase with income Transfers that decline with income Proposals for a flat tax system with universal transfers Friedman (1962) Mirrlees (1971)

This Paper We compare 3 tax and transfer systems: 1. Affine tax system: T (y) = τ 0 + τ 1 y constant marginal rates with lump-sum transfers 2. HSV tax system: T (y) = y λy 1 τ increasing marginal rates without transfers 3. Optimal tax system fully non-linear

Main Findings Best tax and transfer system in the HSV class better than the best affine tax system More valuable to have marginal tax rates increase with income than to have lump-sum transfers Welfare gains moving from the current tax system to the optimal one are tiny

Mirrlees Approach to Tax Design: Mirrlees (1971), Diamond (1988), Saez (2001) Planner only observes earnings = productivity effort Think of planner choosing earnings x and cons. c for each unobservable productivity type α Include incentive constraints, s.t. each type prefers the earnings level intended for their type Allocations are constrained efficient Trace out tax decentralization T(x(α)) = x(α) c(α)

Novel Elements of Our Analysis 1. Our model has a distinct role for private insurance Standard decentralization of efficient allocations delivers all insurance through tax system Very progressive taxes 2. We use a SWF that rationalizes amount of redistribution embedded in observed tax system Analyzes typically assume utilitarian social welfare function Strong desire for redistribution 3. Explore whether simple Ramsey-style tax functions can come close to decentralizing efficient allocations Affine tax function HSV tax function

Static environment Environment 1 Heterogeneous individual labor productivity w Log productivity is sum of two independent stochastic components α no private insurance ε private insurance log w = α + ε planner sees neither component of productivity (later introduce a third productivity component κ that the planner can observe)

Environment 2 Common preferences u(c, h) = log(c) h1+σ 1 + σ Production linear in aggregate effective hours exp(α + ε)h(α, ε)df α df ε = c(α, ε)df α df ε + G

Planner s Problems Seeks to maximize SWF denoted W(α, ε) Takes G as given Takes private insurance for ε as given Only observes total income y = earnings plus private insurance income taxes must be based on income Think of planner as choosing consumption and income for each private type (α, ε) Include incentive constraints s.t. each private type (α, ε) prefers the income level intended for their type

Timeline 1. First Stage Planner offers menu of contracts {c( α, ε), y( α, ε)} Agents draw idiosyncratic α and report α 2. Second Stage Agents buy private insurance against insurable shock ε Draw ε, receive insurance payments and report ε Work sufficient hours to deliver y( α, ε) Receive consumption c( α, ε)

Limitations of Our Analysis 1. We abstract from life-cycle uninsurable shocks Farhi and Werning, 2010; Golosov, Troshkin and Tsyvinkski 2011 2. We abstract from distortions to skill investment Heathcote, Storesletten and Violante, 2013; Guvenen, Kuruscu and Ozkan, 2012; Krueger and Ludwig, 2013

First result: Cannot condition on ε Offered contracts take the form {c( α), y( α)} Private insurance markets utility cost of delivering resources independent of ε undercuts planner s ability to condition allocations on ε Planner cannot take over private insurance Distinct roles for public and private insurance Note: if ε were observable, public insurance would be better than private

Planner s Problem: Second Best max c(α),y(α) s.t. W(α)U(α, α)dfα y(α)dfα c(α)df α + G U(α, α) U(α, α) α, α where U(α, α) max h(ε),b(ε) s.t. { } log c( α) h(ε;α, α)1+σ 1+σ df ε Q(ε)B(ε; α, α)dε = 0 exp(α + ε)h(ε; α, α) + B(ε; α, α) = y( α) ε price of insurance E Q(ε)dε = E df ε

Planner s Problem: Second Best Substituting the solution to the second problem into the first { ( ) } 1+σ W(α) log c(α) Ω y(α) exp(α) df α max c(α),y(α) subject to y(α)dfα c(α)df α + G ( ) 1+σ ( 1+σ log c(α) Ω y(α) exp(α) log c( α) Ω y(ã) exp(α)) α ( exp(ε) 1+σ σ df ε ) σ where Ω 1+σ Standard Mirrlees Problem Solution can be decentralized with income (consumption) taxes

Planner s Problem: Ramsey max τ s.t. W(α) { u(c(α, ε), h(α, ε))dfε } dfα y(α, ε)dfα df ε c(α, ε)df α df ε + G where c(α, ε) and h(α, ε) are the solutions to { } max log(c(α, ε)) h(α,ε)1+σ 1+σ df ε c(α,ε),h(α,ε),b(α,ε) s.t. Q(ε)B(α, ε)dε = 0 c(α, ε) y(α, ε) T(y(α, ε); τ) ε where y(α, ε) exp(α + ε)h(α, ε) + B(α, ε)

Baseline Tax System Assume the current US tax / transfer system is given by T (y; λ, τ) = y λy 1 τ Functional form introduced by Feldstein (1969), Persson (1983), and Benabou (2000) Closely approximates US tax & transfer system (Heathcote, Storesletten, and Violante, 2014) τ indexes progressivity of the tax system

Fit of HSV Tax Function Log of post government income 8.5 9 9.5 10 10.5 11 11.5 12 12.5 13 8.5 9 9.5 10 10.5 11 11.5 12 12.5 13 Log of pre government income Estimated on PSID data for 2000-2006 Households with head / spouse hours 260 per year Estimated value for τ = 0.151, R 2 = 0.96

Social Welfare Want to compare welfare under US tax scheme just described to various alternatives What SWF should we use for this comparison? Our view: current tax system embeds particular social preference for redistribution What taste for redistribution is consistent with observed progressivity (τ = 0.151)?

Social Welfare Assume SWF takes the form W(α) = exp( θα) θ controls taste for redistribution (e.g. θ = 0 : utilitarian) Assume US govt choosing a tax system in HSV class T (y) = y λy 1 τ What value for θ rationalizes observed choice for τ? Empirically-Motivated SWF: θ US that solves τ (θ US ) = τ US

Social Welfare In general, solve for θ US numerically Special case: If F s are normal then { } θ US = (1 τ US ) + 1 1 1 v α 1+σ (1 g US )(1 τ US ) 1 θ is increasing in τ and g θ is decreasing in v α and σ As σ, if θ = θ US, then τ US delivers first best Use θ US as baseline for welfare comparisons focus on relative efficiency of alternative tax systems

Calibration Frisch elasticity = 0.5 σ = 2 Progressivity parameter τ = 0.151 (HSV 2014) Govt spending G s.t. G/Y = 0.188 (US, 2005) var(ε) = 0.193: estimated variance of insurable shocks (HSV 2013) var(α) = 0.273: total variance of wages is 0.466

Wage Distribution Heavy right tail of labor earnings distribution, well-approximated by Pareto distribution (Saez, 2001) Assume Pareto tail reflects uninsurable wage dispersion F α : Exponentially Modified Gaussian EMG(µ, σ 2, a) α is the sum of independent Normal and Exponential random variables F ε : Normal N( vε 2, v ε) log(w) = α + ε is itself EMG w is Pareto-Lognormal log(wh) is also EMG, given our utility function, market structure, and HSV tax system

Distribution for α 0.83439 0.30903 0.11446 0.04239 0.01570 0.00581 0.00215 0.00080 0.00030 0.00011 0.00004 0.00002 0.00001 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 Density (log scale) Data (SCF 2007) NORMAL EMG 9.22 9.50 9.77 10.05 10.32 10.59 10.87 11.14 11.42 11.69 11.97 12.24 12.52 12.79 13.06 13.34 13.61 13.89 14.16 14.44 14.71 14.99 15.26 15.53 15.81 16.08 16.36 16.63 16.91 17.18 17.46 17.73 18.01 Log Labor Income Use micro data from the 2007 SCF to estimate α by maximum likelihood a = 2.2

Numerical Implementation Maintain continuous distribution for ε Assume a discrete distribution for α Baseline: 10,000 evenly-spaced grid points α min : $5 per hour (12% of the average = $41.56) α max : $3,075 per hour ($6.17m assuming 2,000 hours = 99.99th percentile of SCF earnings distn.) Set µ and σ 2 to match E [e α ] = 1 and target for var(α) given a = 2.2

Wage Distribution x 10-3 8 7 6 Density 5 4 3 2 1 0 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 Hourly Wages

Social Welfare Function 3 2.5 Relative Pareto Weight 2 1.5 1 0.5 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 exp(alpha)

Quantitative Analysis Focus on four cases: 1. HSV tax function: T (y) = y λy 1 τ 2. Affine tax function: T (y) = τ 0 + τ 1 y 3. Cubic tax function: T (y) = τ 0 + τ 1 y + τ 2 y 2 + τ 3 y 3 4. Mirrless tax function (second best allocation)

Quantitative Analysis: Benchmark Tax System Tax Parameters Outcomes welfare Y mar. tax TR/Y HSV US λ 0.836 τ 0.151 0.311 0.018 Affine τ 0 0.116 τ 1 0.303 0.58 0.41 0.303 0.089 Cubic τ 0 0.032 τ 1 0.126 τ 2 0.064 τ 3 0.003 0.05 0.79 0.289 0.017 Mirrlees 0.11 0.82 0.287 0.003

Quantitative Analysis: Benchmark Moving to affine tax system is walfare reducing Increasing marginal rates more important than lump-sum transfers Moving to fully optimal system generates only tiny gains (0.1%) The optimal marginal tax rate is around 30% Almost no need for transfers

HSV Tax Function Log Consumption 6 4 2 0-2 -4 Mirrlees Ramsey Hours Worked 1.2 1 0.8 0.6 0.4-2 0 2 4 alpha -2 0 2 4 alpha Marginal Tax Rate 0.6 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.2 0.1 0-2 0 2 4 alpha Average Tax Rate 1 0.5 0-0.5-1 -2 0 2 4 alpha

Affine Tax Function Log Consumption 6 4 2 0-2 -4 Mirrlees Ramsey Hours Worked 1.2 1 0.8 0.6 0.4-2 0 2 4 alpha -2 0 2 4 alpha Marginal Tax Rate 0.6 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.2 0.1 0-2 0 2 4 alpha Average Tax Rate 1 0.5 0-0.5-1 -2 0 2 4 alpha

Cubic Tax Function Log Consumption 6 4 2 0-2 -4 Mirrlees Ramsey Hours Worked 1.2 1 0.8 0.6 0.4-2 0 2 4 alpha -2 0 2 4 alpha Marginal Tax Rate 0.6 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.2 0.1 0-2 0 2 4 alpha Average Tax Rate 1 0.5 0-0.5-1 -2 0 2 4 alpha

Quantitative Analysis: Sensitivity What drives the results? 1. Empirically-motivated SWF Utilitarian SWF: θ = 0 2. Eliminate insurable shocks: ṽ α = v α + v ε and ṽ ε = 0 3. Wage distribution has thin Log-Normal right tail: α LN

Sensitivity: Utilitarian SWF Utilitarian SWF stronger taste for redistribution Want higher tax rates and larger transfers Optimal HSV still better than optimal affine Tax System Tax Parameters Outcomes welfare Y mar. tax TR/Y HSV US λ : 0.836 τ : 0.151 0.311 0.018 HSV λ : 0.821 τ : 0.295 1.38 6.02 0.436 0.068 Affine τ 0 : 0.233 τ 1 : 0.452 0.45 6.43 0.452 0.220 Mirrlees 1.53 6.15 0.440 0.122

Sensitivity: No Insurable Shocks No insurable shocks larger role for public redistribution Want higher tax rates and larger transfers Optimal HSV still better than optimal affine Tax System Tax Parameters Outcomes welfare Y mar. tax TR/Y HSV US λ : 0.836 τ : 0.151 0.311 0.018 HSV λ : 0.839 τ : 0.192 0.12 1.64 0.346 0.033 Affine τ 0 : 0.156 τ 1 : 0.360 0.21 1.97 0.360 0.139 Mirrlees 0.23 2.11 0.361 0.081 Utilitarian SWF + No insurable shocks Lump-sum transfers more important Optimal HSV worse than optimal affine

Sensitivity: Log-Normal Wage Log-normal distribution thin right tail Optimal HSV worse than optimal affine Optimal affine nearly efficient Tax System Tax Parameters Outcomes welfare Y mar. tax TR/Y HSV US λ : 0.836 τ : 0.151 0.311 0.018 HSV λ : 0.826 τ : 0.070 0.27 3.10 0.239 0.005 Affine τ 0 : 0.068 τ 1 : 0.250 0.34 2.67 0.250 0.042 Mirrlees 0.35 2.71 0.249 0.042

Why Distribution Shape Matters Want high marginal rates at the top when (i) few agents face those marginal rates, but (ii) can capture lots of revenue from higher-income households 1 0.9 Benchmark Log-normal 0.8 Coefficient (1-F(y))/(yf(y)) 0.7 0.6 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.2 0.1 0 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 Income y

Efficient Marginal Tax Rates: Sensitivity 0.6 Benchmark Utilitarian No Insurable Shocks Log-Normal 0.5 Marginal Tax Rate 0.4 0.3 0.2 0.1 0-2 -1.5-1 -0.5 0 0.5 1 1.5 2 alpha

Extension: Coarse Grid Coarse grid Mirrlees Planner can do much better Gives Mirrlees planner too much power if true distribution continuous # of grid points Welfare (relative to HSV) Affine Mirrlees First Best 25 0.58 3.82 8.80 100 0.58 1.17 8.79 1,000 0.58 0.21 8.80 10,000 0.58 0.11 8.80 100,000 0.58 0.10 8.80

Extension: Coarse Grid 0.6 0.5 25 grids 10 2 grids 10 3 grids 10 4 grids 10 5 grids Marginal Tax Rate 0.4 0.3 0.2 0.1 0-2 -1 0 1 2 3 4 alpha

Extension: Type-Contingent Taxes Productivity partially reflects observable characteristics (e.g. education, age, gender) Some fraction of uninsurable shocks are observable: α α + κ Heathcote, Perri & Violante (2010) estimate variance of cross-sectional wage dispersion attributable to observables, v κ = 0.108 Planner should condition taxes on observables: T(y; κ) Consider two-point distribution for κ (college vs high school)

Extension: Type-Contingent Taxes Significant welfare gains relative to non-contingent tax Conditioning on observables marginal tax rates of 20% System Outcomes wel. Y mar. TR/Y HSV US λ : 0.827,τ : 0.151 0.311 0.017 0.015 HSV λ L : 0.988, τ L : 0.180 λ H : 0.694, τ H : 0.059 1.34 4.64 0.212 0.043 0.061 Affine τ L 0 : 0.140, τ L 1: 0.151 1.39 5.20 0.199 τ H 0 : 0.095, τ H 1 : 0.224 Mirrlees 1.46 5.20 0.200 0.126 0.137 0.103 0.136

Conclusions Moving from current HSV system to optimal affine system is welfare reducing Increasing marginal rates more important than lump-sum transfers Moving from current HSV system to fully optimal system generates tiny welfare gains Ramsey and Mirrlees tax schemes not far apart: can approximately decentralize SB with a simple tax scheme Important to measure the gap in terms of allocations and welfare, not in terms of marginal tax rates Want to condition both transfers and tax rates on observables