Energy Saving Innovations, Non-Exhaustible Sources of Energy and Long-Run: What Would Happen if we Run Out of Oil?



Similar documents
2007/8. The problem of non-renewable energy resources in the production of physical capital. Agustin Pérez-Barahona

ECON20310 LECTURE SYNOPSIS REAL BUSINESS CYCLE

Chapter 4 Technological Progress and Economic Growth

Optimal Paternalism: Sin Taxes and Health Subsidies

Comments on \Do We Really Know that Oil Caused the Great Stag ation? A Monetary Alternative", by Robert Barsky and Lutz Kilian

Universidad de Montevideo Macroeconomia II. The Ramsey-Cass-Koopmans Model

Total Factor Productivity

The Budget Deficit, Public Debt and Endogenous Growth

Macroeconomics Lecture 1: The Solow Growth Model

GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM WITH BANKS AND THE FACTOR-INTENSITY CONDITION

The Real Business Cycle model

Problem 1. Steady state values for two countries with different savings rates and population growth rates.

Note on growth and growth accounting

Calibration of Normalised CES Production Functions in Dynamic Models

Technology and Economic Growth

Intermediate Macroeconomics: The Real Business Cycle Model

FISCAL POLICY* Chapter. Key Concepts

The RBC methodology also comes down to two principles:

Energy and Economics

Technology and Economic Growth

MA Macroeconomics 10. Growth Accounting

Economic Growth. Chapter 11

. In this case the leakage effect of tax increases is mitigated because some of the reduction in disposable income would have otherwise been saved.

CHAPTER 7 Economic Growth I

Preparation course MSc Business&Econonomics: Economic Growth

CHAPTER 7: AGGREGATE DEMAND AND AGGREGATE SUPPLY

Chapter 12. Aggregate Expenditure and Output in the Short Run

The Real Business Cycle Model

TRADE AND INVESTMENT IN THE NATIONAL ACCOUNTS This text accompanies the material covered in class.

Natural Gas market in Spain before market liberalization. Jesús Muñoz San Miguel. Yolanda Hinojosa Bergillos

MASTER IN ENGINEERING AND TECHNOLOGY MANAGEMENT

Chapter 13 Real Business Cycle Theory

VI. Real Business Cycles Models

Market Power and Efficiency in Card Payment Systems: A Comment on Rochet and Tirole

Financial Development and Macroeconomic Stability

Inflation. Chapter Money Supply and Demand

Unraveling versus Unraveling: A Memo on Competitive Equilibriums and Trade in Insurance Markets

Earnings in private jobs after participation to post-doctoral programs : an assessment using a treatment effect model. Isabelle Recotillet

Advertising. Sotiris Georganas. February Sotiris Georganas () Advertising February / 32

6. Budget Deficits and Fiscal Policy

Markups and Firm-Level Export Status: Appendix

The Specific-Factors Model: HO Model in the Short Run

AGGREGATE DEMAND AND AGGREGATE SUPPLY The Influence of Monetary and Fiscal Policy on Aggregate Demand

Aggregate Supply and Aggregate Demand

Growth Accounting. will be at some particular time t as a function of the economy s stock of capital K t

4 Macroeconomics LESSON 6

Chapter 9 Aggregate Demand and Economic Fluctuations Macroeconomics In Context (Goodwin, et al.)

MA Advanced Macroeconomics: 7. The Real Business Cycle Model

Potential GDP and Economic Growth

The Economic Impacts of Reducing. Natural Gas and Electricity Use in Ontario

Long Run Economic Growth Agenda. Long-run Economic Growth. Long-run Growth Model. Long-run Economic Growth. Determinants of Long-run Growth

Lecture 14 More on Real Business Cycles. Noah Williams

The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis

The Solow Model. Savings and Leakages from Per Capita Capital. (n+d)k. sk^alpha. k*: steady state Per Capita Capital, k

MACROECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF VARIOUS PROPOSALS TO PROVIDE $500 BILLION IN TAX RELIEF

2. Real Business Cycle Theory (June 25, 2013)

REAL BUSINESS CYCLE THEORY METHODOLOGY AND TOOLS

Current Accounts in Open Economies Obstfeld and Rogoff, Chapter 2

The Golden Rule. Where investment I is equal to the savings rate s times total production Y: So consumption per worker C/L is equal to:

SAMA Working Paper: POPULATION AGING IN SAUDI ARABIA. February Hussain I. Abusaaq. Economic Research Department. Saudi Arabian Monetary Agency

A Review of the Literature of Real Business Cycle theory. By Student E XXXXXXX

Lecture 3: Growth with Overlapping Generations (Acemoglu 2009, Chapter 9, adapted from Zilibotti)

Practice Problems on Current Account

Keynesian Macroeconomic Theory

UNIVERSITY OF OSLO DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS

Ghana South Korea United States. Real GDP per capita (2005 dollars) Per centage of 1960 real GDP per capita real GDP per capita

Answers to Text Questions and Problems. Chapter 22. Answers to Review Questions

A transition to a Green Economy - A change in paradigm or greener shade of brown?

welfare costs of business cycles

CH 10 - REVIEW QUESTIONS

Moral Hazard. Itay Goldstein. Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania

This paper is not to be removed from the Examination Halls

Econ 303: Intermediate Macroeconomics I Dr. Sauer Sample Questions for Exam #3

Name: Date: 3. Variables that a model tries to explain are called: A. endogenous. B. exogenous. C. market clearing. D. fixed.

Chapter 3: Commodity Forwards and Futures

11.3 BREAK-EVEN ANALYSIS. Fixed and Variable Costs

Chapter 4 Consumption, Saving, and Investment

1 National Income and Product Accounts

= C + I + G + NX ECON 302. Lecture 4: Aggregate Expenditures/Keynesian Model: Equilibrium in the Goods Market/Loanable Funds Market

Energy-Saving Technical Change

Macroeconomic Effects of Financial Shocks Online Appendix

3 The Standard Real Business Cycle (RBC) Model. Optimal growth model + Labor decisions

Chapter 11. Market-Clearing Models of the Business Cycle

Measuring total factor productivity for the United Kingdom

Achieving an Environmental Target with an Emissions Tax under Incomplete Enforcement

Introduction to the Economic Growth course

Optimal Investment. Government policy is typically targeted heavily on investment; most tax codes favor it.

On the relationship between defense and non-defense spending in the U.S. during the world wars

Practice Problems on the Capital Market

Effects of electricity price volatility and covariance on the firm s investment decisions and long-run demand for electricity

The Macroeconomic Effects of Tax Changes: The Romer-Romer Method on the Austrian case

Documento de Trabajo. Trade Liberalization and Wage Inequality. Time Series Evidence from Chile.

Regret and Rejoicing Effects on Mixed Insurance *

Life Cycle Asset Allocation A Suitable Approach for Defined Contribution Pension Plans

Econ 102 Aggregate Supply and Demand

4. In the Solow model with technological progress, the steady state growth rate of total output is: A) 0. B) g. C) n. D) n + g.

Nº 252 Diciembre 2003

Real income (Y)

Why Does Consumption Lead the Business Cycle?

CREATING AN INNOVATION AGENDA TO GENERATE SUSTAINABLE GROWTH, ENERGY EFFICIENCY AND JOBS IN EUROPE

Transcription:

Revista de Economía del Rosario Energy Saving Innovations, Non-Exhaustible Sources of Energy and Long-Run: What Would Happen if we Run Out of Oil? Hernando Zuleta * Universidad del Rosario, Colombia. Received: March 2008 Approved: October 2008 Abstract. We formulate and solve a model of factor saving technological improvement considering three factors of production: labor, capital and energy. The productive activities have three main characteristics: first, in order to use capital goods firms need energy; second, there are two sources of energy: nonexhaustible and exhaustible; third, capital goods can be of different qualities and the quality of these goods can be changed along two dimensions reducing the need of energy or changing the source of energy used in the production process. The economy goes through three stages of development after industrialization. In the first one, firms make use of exhaustible energy and the efficiency in the use of energy is constant. In the second stage, as the price of energy grows the efficiency in its use is increased. In the third stage, the price of exhaustible sources is so high that firms have incentives to use non-exhaustible sources of energy. During this stage the price of energy is constant. In this set up, the end of the oil age has level effects on consumption and output but it does not cause the collapse of the economic system. Keywords: non-exhaustible energy, energy saving innovations, economic growth. JEL classification: 031, 041, Q20. Resumen. Se formula y resuelve un modelo de cambio tecnológico ahorrador de factores de producción que considera tres factores: capital, trabajo y energía. El modelo cuenta con características específicas con respecto a la interacción entre la energía la cual, de acuerdo a su fuente puede ser renovable y no renovable) y el capital. Una vez esta economía se ha definido, se supone que evoluciona en tres etapas luego de su industrialización, durante las cuales el carácter renovable o no renovable de la energía influye su precio relativo, eficiencia y afecta también el nivel agregado de consumo y producción de la economía, sin que esta evolución lleve al colapso del sistema económico. Palabras clave: energía renovable, innovaciones ahorradoras de energía, crecimiento económico. Clasificación JEL: 031, 041, Q20. * Address for correspondence: Economics Department, Universidad del Rosario. Calle 14 # 4-69, Bogotá, Colombia. E-mail: hernando.zuleta84@urosario.edu.co.

204 ENERGY SAVING INNOVATIONS, NON-EXHAUSTIBLE SOURCES AND LONG-RUN 1. Introduction Natural resources have been an important source of wealth all through the history of the world. Every product we consume comes from at least one natural resource, either directly or indirectly. Scarce natural resources such as hydrocarbons have become one of the greatest concerns of our times as both scholars and journalists have foreseen the end of the oil age. In fact, analysts have forecasted the end of important energy sources such as gas and oil. The cries of oil scarcity heard some decades ago were certainly wrong: the world is not about to run out of hydrocarbons. Thanks to advances in exploration technology, there are more proven reserves of oil today than there were three decades ago see Watkins, 2006). However, the question of what is going to happen as we approach the end of the oil age deserves attention The classic supply side effect implies that when the supply of natural resources, especially energy sources, declines their prices raise. This price increase indicates the reduced availability of basic inputs in production, which motivates the use of new forms of energy. Using this logic, in 1932, John R. Hicks introduced the theory of induced innovation, according to which changes in relative factor prices lead to innovations that reduce the need for the relatively expensive factor. This theory has been tested. Kuper and Soest 2003), for example, who found through a panel of sectors of the Dutch economy that energy saving technical progress is particularly significant in periods preceded by high and rising energy prices, whereas the pace of this form of technical change happens to be much slower in periods of low energy prices 1. David Popp 2002) shows that there is a strong positive correlation between energy prices and innovations. With this evidence in mind, we extend the neoclassical growth models introducing the existence of capital goods that make use of energy and model in it, by a very simplified way, the production of energy. In the next section, we motivate the need of considering the finite supply of energy in traditional growth models. Then, we describe and solve the model. Finally we conclude. 2. Machines, Energy and Growth Important episodes in the history of capitalism are related to the invention and use of machines. Capital accumulation is the only source of economic growth during the transition in a Solow-like type of model. In endogenous growth models à la Romer 2 technology is embodied in capital goods, so capital accumulation generates neutral technological change and, for this reason, longrun growth. Finally, in models of factor saving innovations 3 capital abundance stimulates labor-saving innovations and savings are higher in economies where 1 See also Pommeret and Boucekkine 2004). 2 Romer 1986 and 1990). 3 See Kennedy 1964), Zeira 1998), Acemoglu 2002), Boldrin and Levine 2002a), Zuleta 2004), Zuleta 2008) and Peretto and Seater 2007).

H. ZULETA 205 the technology is more capital-intensive. Therefore, also in this type of models the invention and use of machines is the main source of economic growth. Machines, however, need energy in order to be productive and energy sources today are predominantly finite. Thus, economic growth depends also on the supply of energy 4. We consider energy saving innovations and the existence of non-exhaustible sources of energy. Therefore, as exhaustible energetic resources become more expensive, the agents of the economy can adopt technologies that are more efficient in the use of energy or technologies that use non-exhaustible sources of energy. We assume that technology is embodied in capital goods and capital goods of better qualities are more costly. Also, as economies grow they consume more energy so the reserves of exhaustible sources of energy decrease and their price increases. Therefore, economic growth generates incentives to use nonexhaustible sources of energy in a more intensive way. This implies that in the long run, when oil has become exhausted, we will use only non-exhaustible sources of energy. Along the transition, the efficiency in the use of energy grows as exhaustible sources become more expensive. In the same way in which agents innovate in order to save labor and land when these factors become scarce they devote efforts to reduce the need of fossil combustibles. We do not model the invention of technologies. We assume that such technologies exist and are costly. Similarly we do not explain the beginning of the industrial era 5. We assume that the economy starts with a small amount of capital, a given technology, and big reserves of exhaustible sources of energy. Thus, during the first stage of industrialization, firms make use of exhaustible sources of energy and the efficiency in the use of energy is low. In a second stage, the reserves of exhaustible sources of energy are smaller so the price of energy is higher and firms start using more energy-efficient capital goods. Finally, in the third stage the stock of capital becomes big if compared with the reserves of exhaustible sources of energy, so the price of exhaustible sources is high and firms have incentives to use non-exhaustible sources of energy. In the long run, all the energy used in the production process comes from non-exhaustible sources. Finally, there is only progress in the efficiency with which energy is used, but not in the use of labour and capital. This assumption is made for simplicity. We want to focus on the technological changes related to the use of energy. The first studies that explicitly modelled the need of energy in the production process were presented by Stiglitz 1974) and Solow 1974). However they didn t consider the possibility of energy saving innovations or the existence of non-exhaustible sources of energy. Non-exhaustible sources of energy were introduced into economic models by Dasgupta and Heal 1974), Heal 1976) and Nordhaus 1979) and more recently by Manne and Richels 1992) and Tahvo- 4 Finn 1991) studies the problem in relation with business cycles. 5 For explanations about the industrial revolution see Galor2005), Hansen and Prescott 2000) or Zuleta 2006).

206 ENERGY SAVING INNOVATIONS, NON-EXHAUSTIBLE SOURCES AND LONG-RUN nen 1994). However, none of these models consider the possibility of energy saving innovations Tahvonen and Salo, 2001). Finally, Groth and Schou 2002) and Smulders and Nooij 2003) consider the existence of exhaustible sources of energy but do not consider the existence of non-exhaustible sources of energy. 3. The Model 3.1. Consumers We assume that labor supply is inelastic, that population growth is zero and we normalize labor to one. The problem of the representative consumer-worker is the standard one, max c t logc t )β t s.t. a t+1 = a t 1 + r t ) + w t c t 0 where a is the amount of assets at time t, r t is the interest rate, w t is the market wage, c t is the consumption of the representative agent and β is the discount factor. From where, c t+1 c t = β 1 + r t+1 ) 1) 3.2. Producers of Final Goods The production function is a Cobb-Douglas that combines capital and labor. We assume, however, that an energy source e s ) is needed to operate capital goods. There are two sources of energy s), non-exhaustible N) and exhaustible E) differentiated by their cost sǫ [N, E] ). Capital goods can be also of different qualities, they are differentiated by the source of energy they use, e s, and by the efficiency in the use of energy γ S ). Therefore, there is a production function for each quality of capital. Any production function is characterized by A[minK γs,s, γ s e s )] α L 1 α s where K γs,s 1 is the amount of capital of quality γ s designed to operate with energy, e s, γ S is the amount of energy e s needed to operate 1 unit of capital, for this reason we also refer to γ S as the efficiency rate in the use of energy type s. Finally, L s is the amount of labor working with capital goods of type K γs,s. The cost of the firms include the cost of labor wl s, the cost of capital goods p γs,sk γs,s and the cost of energy p s e s. Where p γ,s and p s are the price of capital of quality γ s, s and the price of energy of type s respectively. Firms are price takers and choose the amounts of capital and labor and the

H. ZULETA 207 quality of capital γ s and s) max K t,l t,e i,t [ t=0 s A [ minkγs,t,s, γ s,t e s,t ) ] α t L 1 α t s,t ) ) ) ] t 1 p γs,t,sk γs,t,s p s,t e s,t w t L s,t 1 + r t s.t. K γs,t,s 0 Since the production function is of the Leontief type, firms use capital and energy in such a way that K γs,t,s = γ s,t e s,t. Thus, for analytical convenience we rewrite the problem in the following way: max K t,l t,e i,t t=0 s s.t. A [ Kγs,t,s] α L 1 α s,t ) ) ) t 1 p γs,t,sk γs,t,s p s,t e s,t w t L s,t 1 + r t 0 = K γs,t,s γ s,t e s,t ; 0 K γs,t,s; γ s,t From the solution of the problem we find factor prices, w t = 1 α) A [ k γs,t,s] α 2) p γs,t,s = αa [ k γs,t,s] α 1 λt + µ t ) 3) p s,t = λ t γ s,t 4) p γs,t,s γ s,t K γs,t,s = λ t e s,t κ t 5) where k t is the capital labor ratio, λ t is the multiplier of the first restriction, µ t is the multiplier of the second restriction and κ t is the multiplier of the third restriction. Equations 2 to 4 tell that the price of labor is equal to its marginal productivity; the price of a capital good of any quality) is equal to its marginal productivity equation 3); the price of energy is equal to its marginal productivity equation 4) and finally, equation 5 tells that for any change in the quality of capital goods, the change in the price multiplied by the units of capital must be equal to the savings generated by the increase in efficiency, namely, the marginal cost of innovations is equal to its marginal productivity. Note that if κ t 0 then γ is constant. In other words, only if κ = 0 the technology becomes more efficient as capital gets accumulated. Note also that equation 2 implies that when both sources of energy are used the capital labor ratios must be equal, that is, k γe,t,e = k γn,t,n. Indeed, we are assuming homogenous labor, perfect mobility and perfect competition, so the

208 ENERGY SAVING INNOVATIONS, NON-EXHAUSTIBLE SOURCES AND LONG-RUN marginal productivity of labor does not depend on the type of energy. Similarly, equation 3 implies that when the capital labor ratio is the same regardless of the type of energy used then the price of capital goods must be the same for the two types of capital, p γe,t,e = p γn,t,n. 6 Combining equations 3, 4 and 5 we find that whenever K γt,s > 0, p γs,t,s = αa [ ] α 1 p s,t k γs,t,s 6) γ s,t p γs,t,s γ s,t K γs,t,s = p s,t γ s,t e s,t κ t 7) Since any increase in capital must be accompanied by an increase in energy in order to be productive, the price of a capital good must be equal to its marginal productivity given K γs,t,s γ s,t e s,t ) minus the cost of the additional needs of energy. In the same way, the cost of a technological improvement that reduces the need for energy, this is, the increase in the price of capital multiplied pγs,t ),s by the units of capital used in the production process γ s,t K γs,t,s, must be equal to the cost of the energy needed to produce with K γs,t,s units of capital e p s,t s,t γ s,t ). Note also that if ps,t γ s,t > αa [ k γs,t,s] α 1 then Kγs,t,s = 0, this is, if the price of energy of type s is higher than the marginal productivity of capital K γs,t,s then no capital of type s is used. Indeed, from equation 6 it follows that if p s,t > γ s,t αa [ k γs,t,s] α 1 then final good producers would only demand capital if the price of capital goods of type γ s,t is negative. Therefore, given the technology, if the price of energy N is too high then firms do not have incentives to use this type of energy. However, given the price of energy, technological improvements increases in γ, α or A) can generate incentives to use non-exhaustible sources of energy. Additionally, an exogenous increase in the price of energy of type E can generate incentives for the firms to use only non-exhaustible sources. Finally, ceteris paribus, given the technology, an exogenous increase in p s,t reduces the quantity of capital and, given the stock of capital, an exogenous increase in p s,t increases the efficiency γ s. Summarizing, the price of both types of energy determine whether or not the agents of the economy have incentives to accumulate capital. If the price of exhaustible energy is higher than the marginal productivity of the capital goods that use this energy then it is better not to use this type of capital. However, a way to increase the marginal productivity of capital is buying capital goods which embody more efficient technologies. Therefore, as the price of energy grows, the agents of the economy have incentives to choose more efficient technologies. 6 Equations 3 and 2 also imply that if p N,t > p E,t then only exhaustible energy is used in the production process and if p N,t < p E,t then only non-exhaustible energy is used in the production process

H. ZULETA 209 3.3. Producers of Capital Goods Capital goods producers receive assets from the consumers a t, pay the interest rate r t, build capital goods and receive a price p γs,t,s for any unit of capital of quality γ s,t. The cost of a technology γ s,t can be interpreted in two different ways: i) the cost of inventing and implementing a technology and ii) the cost of copying a new technology and building a similar capital good. If we assume that technology is non-rival, then the cost described in ii) is likely to be smaller than the one described in i). However, if we assume that technology is embodied in goods and that it is costly to reverse engineer and appropriate, the difference between i) and ii) is substantially reduced 7. We assume that the technology to produce capital goods of different qualities exists interpretation ii)), but the cost is increasing in γ s,t. For simplicity, we assume that capital is reversible, that is, people can reduce the existing stock of capital in order to increase consumption. The amount of resources needed to build one unit of capital is an increasing function of the quality of the capital good, K γs,t,s = ϕ γ s,t a, where ϕ is the productivity of the capital good producer and is the same for E and N, so the profits of the capital producers are given by, ) p γs,t,sk γs,t,s a t r t. To keep things simple we assume that each capital producer produces capital goods that use only one type of energy. Since K γt,s = atϕ γ s,t, the free entry condition implies, p γs,t,s = γ s,tr t ϕ 8) Equation 8 tells us that the price of a capital good must be equal to its cost of production. Note also that if p γe,t,e = p γn,t,n. then γ E,t = γ N,t. Therefore from equations 4 and 8 it follows that if both sources of energy are used then the efficiency in the use of energy is the same regardless the type of energy, γ E,t = γ N,t. 3.4. Energy Sources Producers extract e s,t units of source s at period t and receive a price p s,t for each unit. They pay a cost for the extraction of energy given the amount of reserves N t at period t. The evolution of reserves is given by, R s,t+1 = R s,t se s,t where E = 1 and N = 0. For simplicity we assume that the unit cost of extraction is given by { ) φs 1 + ee,t R C e s,t, R s,t ) = s,t if s = E if s = N 7 See Boldrin and Levine, 2002b. φ s

210 ENERGY SAVING INNOVATIONS, NON-EXHAUSTIBLE SOURCES AND LONG-RUN where φ N > φ E. In other words, the unit cost of extraction of exhaustible sources of energy depends negatively on the amount of reserves and positively on the amount extracted 8. The unit cost of extraction of non-exhaustible sources is assumed to be constant. We made this assumption for simplicity and does not change the main results of the model. We are aware of the fact that technology in the production of renewable sources of energy has improved substantially in the last decades. However, including this type of progress in the model would accelerate. On the other hand, the marginal costs of aeolian or solar energy could rise as the best sites are used up. Including this type of cost would reduce the steady state capital but would not affect the qualitative results of the model. The profits of the firm are: [p s,t C e s,t, R s,t )] e s,t Since there is free entry, we know that p s,t = C e s,t, R s,t ) so p E,t = φ E 1 + e ) E,t 9) p N,t = φ N 10) Therefore, the unit cost of extraction must be equal to the price of oil. From section 3.2 we know that when the two sources of energy are used, their prices must be equal, p E,t = p N,t, so using equations 9 and 10, φ E 1 + e ) E,t = φ N 11) Note that equation 11 may not hold. Indeed, since φ E < φ N when the capital stock of the economy is small the need of energy e is also small. Then, if the reserves are big, only the the exhaustible source of energy E is used. Therefore, for early stages of development, only exhaustible sources of energy are used. However, once the amount of assets reaches a minimum level, agents have incentives to use non-exhaustible sources too. Moreover, when the reserves decrease the extraction of exhaustible energy e E,t is reduced and both technologies are used. In particular, from equation 11 it follows that the supply of exhaustible energy is given by, ) φn e E,t = 1 12) φ E From where, e E e E = and K E,t K E,t γ E,t γ E,t = 8 High oil prices stimulates investment in exploration and improvement in exploration technology. However, this efforts have no long run effects so, for the sake of simplicity, we can assume away new discoveries.

H. ZULETA 211 So, as the reserves of exhaustible sources of energy decrease, the supply of this type of energy is reduced as well as the amount of capital goods that use this type of energy. This means that as the economy grows the amount of capital goods that make use of exhaustible energy decreases and in the very long run all capital goods will make use of non-exhaustible energy. Note also that equation 11 implies that in the long run the price of energy is constant so the analysis of the long run becomes simpler. Finally, recall that K E,t = γ E,t e E,t so, equation 11 implies that, differentiating, γ E,t = K ) E,t φe φ N φ E γ E,t γ E,t = K E,t K E,t So, when exhaustible sources of energy are used, the growth rate of the efficiency of capital goods energy saving technological change) is equal to the growth rate of capital minus the growth rate of reserves of exhaustible sources of energy. In the long run only non-exhaustible sources are used so = 0 and γ E,t γ E,t = K E,t K E,t = 0 3.5. Equilibrium: Beginning, Transition and Long Run In this section we use the results obtained in the previous sections in order to characterize the equilibrium. We first summarize the most important results in a formal way in propositions 1, 2, 3 and 4. Then, we show how this results relate to the evolution of the industrialized economies. Using equations 6 and 9 we get the price of capital goods and the interest rate when only exhaustible sources of energy are used and technology is constant, p γ0 = αa[k t ] α 1 φ E r t = ϕ αa[k t ] α 1 φ E 1 + e E,t ) 1 + φ E K t )) 13) 14) It is straightforward that rt k t < 0 and rt R t > 0. Therefore, for early stages of development, the interest rate decreases as the economy grows. Now, from equation 1, the behavior of the interest rate translates in to a decreasing trend in the growth rate of consumption. Note also that in the absence of energysaving innovations or alternative sources of energy the economy would collapse. Indeed, if the energy used in the production process is exhaustible, then the amount of reserves decreases period by period and the unitary cost of extraction

212 ENERGY SAVING INNOVATIONS, NON-EXHAUSTIBLE SOURCES AND LONG-RUN grows as well as the price of this type of energy equation 9). Now, once the cost of extraction of exhaustible sources equals the cost of extraction of nonexhaustible sources the two sources of energy are used. This results are formally presented in propositions 1 and 2. Proposition 1. In Equilibrium: i) If p N,t > p E,t then only exhaustible energy is used in the production process, ii) if p N,t < p E,t then only non-exhaustible energy is used in the production process and iii) if p N,t = p E,t both sources of energy are used. Proposition 1 follows from equations 2, 6 and 8 and states that only economies where the price of non-exhaustible energy is relatively low have incentives to use this type of energy. If the price of the two sources of energy is the same, both sources are used in the production process. The capital labor ratio must be the same regardless the type of energy used, otherwise the marginal productivity of labor and the wages would depend on the type of energy used equation 2). If the capital labor ratio is the same, the marginal productivity of capital is also equal and so is the price of the capital goods equation 4). Similarly, if the price of capital goods is equal then the efficiency on the use of energy is the same regardless the type of energy equation 8). Finally, if the price of capital, the efficiency in the use of energy and the capital labor ration are the same then the price of energy must be the same equation 6). Proposition 2. Let s define the amount of assets a as the sum of capital goods: a t = K E,t +K N,t. Given the amount of reserves of exhaustible energy R E, there exists a critical level of assets ã such that for any a < ã only exhaustible energy is used. Proposition 2 follows from section 3.4 and Proposition 1 and implies that only a capital abundant economy has incentives to use non-exhaustible energy. In early stages of development the stock of capital is small and the amount of reserves is big so the price of exhaustible energy is relatively low. For this reason if the assets of the economy are small, only exhaustible energy is used. Now, as the economy develops the stock of capital grows and the amount of reserves decrease so the price of exhaustible energy grows until the point where it is profitable to use non-exhaustible sources of energy. Now, let s recall that the economy has two ways to face the scarcity of exhaustible sources of energy, one is by using non-exhaustible sources of energy and the other one is through energy-saving innovations. We already described the conditions under which the use of non-exhaustible sources is convenient. In the following lines we refer to the incentive to undertake energy saving innovations. From equations 7 and 9 it follows that if the amount of reserves of exhaustible sources of energy is rather big, then the gain derived from energy

H. ZULETA 213 saving innovations is lower than the cost. Formally, if R t > φ E K t p γ0 ) 2 φ E ) then p ) 2 > φ E 1 + φe K t R t and p ) 2 > p E,t so pγo K t > pe,t e t. Therefore, from equation 7 it follows that there are no incentives to increase the efficiency in the use of energy. However, as the economy develops, the amount of reserves decreases until the point where the incentives for energy-saving innovations appear, this is, R t < φ E K t p γ0 ) 2 φ E As the economy develops and the amount of reserves decreases the economy either begins to use non-exhaustible sources of energy or to undertake energy saving innovations. But which one happens first? This question can be answered using equations 7 and 9 and Proposition 3: Proposition 3. If φ E K t p γ0 ) 2 φ E > R t > K t φe φ N φ E then only exhaustible energy is used and the efficiency in the use of energy grows over time. If ) φ E K t φe γ p γ0 < R 0 ) 2 t < K t φ E φ N φ E then non-exhaustible energy is used and the ) efficiency in the use of energy grows pγ0 with time. Therefore, if ) 2 φ E > φ N φ E then energy saving innovations are adopted over the use of non-exhaustible sources of energy and pγ0 if ) 2 φ E ) < φ N φ E then energy saving innovations are never adopted. Proposition 3 implies that if the efficiency in the use of energy is initially very high, the marginal cost of non-exahustible sources of energy is relatively low, and if the marginal cost of increasing the efficiency in the use of energy is high then energy saving innovations are not adopted. Now, taking into account that all through the XXth Century many technological innovations were actually energy savers see Kuper and Soest, 2003 or Pommeret ) and Boucekkine, pγ0 2004) it is reasonable to assume that ) 2 φ E > φ N φ E. We already showed that the reduction in the amount of reserves of exhaustible sources of energy generates incentives either to use non-exhaustible )

214 ENERGY SAVING INNOVATIONS, NON-EXHAUSTIBLE SOURCES AND LONG-RUN sources of energy or to undertake energy saving innovations. In this setting, the price of exhaustible energy grows up to the point when it becomes equal to the cost of extraction of non-exhaustible sources. While the use of exhaustible energy initially grows, then drecreases and finally vanishes. Proposition 4. Given A and ϕ there exists a steady state where the capital ) 1 )1 labor ratio is given by k 1 α 2 =. αa 2 ϕ φ N β 1 β Proposition 4 follows equation 14 and implies that in the long run the income depends on TFP k k A > 0, the capital share α > 0 and the discount factor k β > 0 as it is usual in growth models). Additionally, the steady state stock of capital also depends on the steady state price of energy φ N and on the productivity in the production of capital goods ϕ. The productivity of capital goods production positively affects the steady state stock of capital k ϕ ). > 0 Finally, note that if either A or ϕ grow, for any given reason, then there is long run growth. In other words, if we extend the model assuming constant growth rate for A, then in the long run this model would look like the standard exogenous growth model. 3.5.1. The History The industrial revolution was characterized by the generalization of capital intensive technologies. In terms of our model, the industrial revolution would be the invention of capital goods and it is natural to think that the technology embodied in the earliest capital goods developed was characterized by a positive γ, that is, even if the first technology was not very efficient in the use of energy, it was not completely inefficient. Therefore, the first years of the industrial age were characterized by a big amount of reserves R, a small amount of capital and a given technology γ. Under such circumstances exhaustible resources were likely to be cheap so there were no incentives neither to use non-exhaustible sources of energy nor to to increase the efficiency in the use of energy. However, the amount of reserves R decreased as the economy was producing, so the price of exhaustible energy grew generating incentives to adopt energy saving innovations 9. Finally, the amount of reserves decreased despite the energysaving innovations so the price of exhaustible energy kept growing up to the point where the use of non-exahustible sources of energy became profitable. Under such conditions, the economy went through three stages of development after industrialization. In the first one, reserves of exhaustible sources of energy are big compared with the stock of capital, firms make use of exhaustible sources of energy and the efficiency in the use of energy is constant. In the second stage, as the price of energy grows, the efficiency in the use of 9 The assumption we make about new discoveries does not affect the qualitative results of the model.

H. ZULETA 215 energy gets increased. In the third stage the stock of capital becomes rather big once compared with the reserves of exhaustible sources of energy, so the price of exhaustible sources is so high that firms have incentives to use non-exhaustible sources of energy. Along this stage the price of energy is constant. 4. Conclusions and Discussion Throughout this paper, we formulate and solve a classical growth model of factor saving technological improvement, considering three factors of production, labor, capital and energy. The productive activities were characterized as follows: first, in order to use capital goods firms need energy; second, there are two sources of energy: one non-exhaustible and the other exhaustible; third, capital goods can be of different qualities and the quality of such goods can be changed in two dimensions, either by reducing the need of energy or by changing the source of energy used in the production process. According to this model, the economy goes through three stages of development after industrialization. In the first one, reserves of exhaustible sources of energy are big compared with the stock of capital, firms make use of exhaustible sources of energy and the efficiency in the use of energy is constant. In the second stage, the reserves of exhaustible sources of energy are smaller so the price of energy is bigger and firms start using more efficient capital goods. During this stage, as the price of energy grows the efficiency in the use of energy gets increased. Finally, in the third stage, the stock of capital becomes big if compared with the reserves of exhaustible sources of energy so the price of exhaustible sources is so high that firms have incentives to use non-exhaustible sources of energy. Along this stage the price of energy is constant. The existence of long-run growth does not depend on the reserves of exhaustible sources of energy but on the technological progress in the production of capital goods, the cost of extraction of non-exhaustible energy and the total factor productivity in the production of final goods. There are many important issues regarding the relation between sources of energy and economic growth that remain unaddressed. First, we are ignoring the negative externality that produces the use of exhaustible sources of energy. Second, we are assuming competitive markets whereas oil reserves are geographically concentrated and the biggest part of the extraction business is managed by few firms 10. Third, we are assuming away improvements in the extraction technology as well as new discoveries. All these issues deserve attention and may be topics for further research. However, in order to keep things simple we decide not to address them here. Additionally, the main conclusions of our work would remain the same regardless of the simplifying assumptions. 10 25% of the world s proven reserves of oil sit under the parched deserts of Saudi Arabia. Russia, by contrast, sits atop barely 5% of the world s reserves. Iraq controls about 10%.

216 ENERGY SAVING INNOVATIONS, NON-EXHAUSTIBLE SOURCES AND LONG-RUN References Acemoglu, D. 2002). Directed Technical Change. Review of Economic Studies 694), 781-809. Blanchard, O. 1998). Revisiting European Unemployment: Employment, Capital Accumulation and Factor Prices. NBER WP 6566, Geary Lecture, ESRI. Boldrin, M., Levine, D.K. 2002a). Factor Saving Innovations. Journal of Economic Theory 1051), 18-41. Boldrin, M., Levine, D.K. 2002b). Perfectly Competitive Innovations. Research Department Staff Report 303, Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis. Dasgupta, P., Heal, G. 1974). The Optimal Depletion of Exhaustible Resources. Review of Economic Studies 41, 3-28. Finn, M.G. 1991). Energy price shocks, capacity utilization and business cycle fluctuations. Discussion Paper 50, Institute for Empirical Macroeconomics 50, Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis. Galor, O. 2005). From Stagnation to Growth: Unified Growth Theory. Handbook of Economic Growth, hilippe Aghion & Steven Durlauf ed.), Handbook of Economic Growth, volume 1, chapter 4, pages 171-293 Elsevier. Gylfason, T., Zoega, G. 2001). Natural Resources and Economic Growth: The Role of Investment. CEPR Discussion Papers 2743, C.E.P.R. Discussion Papers. Groth, Ch., Schou, P. 2002). Can Non-renewable Resources Alleviate the Knife-edge Character of Endogenous Growth? Oxford Economic Papers 543), 386-411. Hansen, G.D., Prescott, C. 2002). Malthus To Solow. American Economic Review 924), 1205-1217. Heal, G. 1976). The Relationship Between Price and Extraction Costs for a Resource with Backstop Technology. Bell Journal of Economics 72), 371-378. Hicks, J.R. 1932). The Theory of Wages. London: Macmillan. Kennedy, C. 1964). Induced Bias in Innovation and the Theory of Distribution. Economic Journal LXXIV, 541-547. Manne, A., Richels, R. 1992). Buying the Greenhouse Insurance: The Economic Costs of CO2 Emission Limits. Cambridge Mass.: MIT Press. Kuper, G.H., van Soest, D.P. 2003). Path-Dependence and Input Substitution: Implications for Energy Policy Modelling. Energy Economics 254), 397-407. Norhaus, W. 1979). The Efficient Use of Energy Resources. Yale University Press.

H. ZULETA 217 Peretto, P., Seater, J. 2007). Augmentation or Elimination? Working paper http://www.econ.duke.edu/ peretto/factoreliminatingtechchange.pdf Popp, D. 2002). Induced Innovation and Energy Prices. American Economic Review 921), 160-180. Pommeret, A., Boucekkine, R. 2004). Energy Saving Technical Progress and Optimal Capital Stock: The Role of Embodiment. Economic Modelling 213), 429-444. Romer, P. 1986). Increasing Returns and Long-run Growth. Journal of Political Economy 945), 102-137. Smulders, S., Nooij, M. 2003). The Impact of Energy Conservation on Technology and Economic Growth. Resource and Energy Economics 25, 59-79. Solow, R. 1956). A contribution to the Theory of Economic Growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics 70, 65-94. Tahoven, O. 1994). Carbon Dioxide Abatement as a differential Game. European Journal of Political Economy 19, 685-705. Tahoven, O., Salo, S. 2001). Economic Growth and Transitions between Renewable and Nonrenewable Energy Sources. European Economic Review 458), 1379-1398. Watkins, G.C. 2006). Oil scarcity: What have the past three decades revealed? Energy Policy 345), 508-514. Zeira, J. 1998). Workers, Machines and Economic Growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics 1134), 1091-1118. Zuleta, H. 2004). A Note on Scale Effects. Review of Economic Dynamics 71), 237-242. Zuleta, H. 2006). Seasons Savings and GDP. Mimeo ITAM. http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract id=901794. Zuleta, H. 2008). Factor Saving Innovations and Factor Income Shares. Review of Economic Dynamics, forthcoming. Appendix Proof of Proposition 1. In Equilibrium: i) If p N,t > p E,t then only exhaustible energy is used in the production process, ii) if p N,t < p E,t then only non-exhaustible energy is used in the production process and iii) if p N,t = p E,t both sources of energy are used. Proof. a) From equation 2 it follows that when both sources of energy are used the capital labor ratios must be equal, that is, k γe,t,e = k γn,t,n. b) From equation 6 it follows that when k γe,t,e = k γn,t,n the price of the two capital goods must be equal, that is, p γn,t, N = p γe,t, E. c) From equation 8 it follows that when p γn,t, N = p γe,t, E the price of the two sources of energy must be equal, that is, p N,t = p E,t

218 ENERGY SAVING INNOVATIONS, NON-EXHAUSTIBLE SOURCES AND LONG-RUN From a), b) and c) it follows that if p γn,t, N p γe,t, E then only one source of energy is used. Now, suppose that for some initial conditions p E,t < p N,t. From equation 6 it follows that the producers of final goods are willing to pay more for the capital goods that make use of exhaustible energy. However, the cost of production is identical for the two types of capital so in equilibrium only capital goods that use exhaustible energy are used a similar argument can be made for an increase in p E,t ). Proof of Proposition 2. Define the amount of assets a as the sum of capital goods: a t = K E,t + K N,t. Given the amount of reserves of exhaustible energy R E and the efficiency in the use of energy γ, there exists a critical level of assets ã such that for any a < ã only non non-exhaustible energy is used. [ )] Proof. Define ã = γr φe E φ N 1, ) a) a < ã implies K E,t γr φn E,t φe 1 ) ) b) K E,t γr φn E,t φe 1 implies e E,t < R φn E,t φe 1 ) ) c) e E,t < R φn E,t φe 1 implies ee,t > φn φ E 1 and φ E 1 + ee,t > φ N ) d) φ E 1 + ee,t > φ N implies p N,t > p E,t Finally, form Proposition 1 it follows that if p N,t > p E,t then only exhaustible energy is used in the production process. ) pγ0 Proof of Proposition 3. If ) 2 φ E < φ N φ E then energysaving innovations are never adopted. ) Proof. a) From the proof of Proposition 2 it follows that if R t > Kt φe γ t φ N φ ) E then φ E 1 + ee,t R s,t < φ N and p N > p E, so there are no incentives to use nonexhaustible sources of energy. b) From equations 7 and 9 it follows that R t > φe K t p, then γ 0) 2 φ ) E p γ0 ) 2 > φ E 1 + φe K t R t and p ) 2 > p E,t so pγo K t > pe,t e t, so from equation 7 it follows that there are no incentives to increase the efficiency in the use of energy. Therefore, K t c) If φe p > R t > K φe t then only exhaustible energy is γ 0) 2 φ E used and the efficiency in the use of energy grows with time. K t φ N φ E ) d) If φe p < R t < K φe t then non-exhaustible energy is γ 0) 2 φ E used and the efficiency in the use of energy grows with time. φ N φ E )

H. ZULETA 219 From c) and d) it follows that as K grows and R decreases and at some point the inequalities change sign, that the adoption energy saving innovations or the use of non-exahustible energy become profitable. What happens first? ) pγ0 If ) 2 φ E < φ N φ E, inequality c) changes its sign first and firms start using non-exhaustible sources without energy saving innovations. Note that in this case the price of energy is constant and equal for renewable and exhaustible sources. So if given the price of energy there are no incentives to undertake energy saving innovations then the efficiency in the use of energy remains constant along the transition. pγ0 If ) 2 φ E ) > φ N φ E, inequality d) changes sign first and firms undertake energy saving innovations without using non-exhaustible sources of energy. However, as long as capital goods use exhaustible sources of energy R decreases so sooner or later inequality 1 will also change sign. Proof of Proposition 4. Proof. Claim 1: If p N,t < p E,t and p N,t and r are constant then γ N,t, p γn,t,n and k γn,t,n are constant. From equation 3 if r is constant then p γs,t,s is a linear function of γ s,t. Defining Ω = rt ϕ, the function is given by p γ s,t,s = Ωγ s,t. Now, from equation 7 pγ s,t,s γ s,t = ps,t γ s,t k γs,t,s = k γn,t,n is constant. e s,t K γs,t,s ps,t so γ s,t e s,t K γs,t,s = Ω. Rearranging, p s,t e s,t ) 1 K γs,t,s ) 1 = Ωγ s,t. Since e s,t γ s,t = K γs,t,s we get γ s,t = p s,t 2 Ω and p γs,t,s = Ω p s,t 2 Ω. Therefore, if p N,t and r t are constant then γ N,t and p γn,t,n are constant. Finally, from equation 6 it follows that γ s,t αa [ ) α 1 k γs,t,s] γs,t Ω = p s,t, rearranging, 1 αa γ ps,t s,t + γs,t 2 Ω)) 1 α. Therefore, if p N,t and r t are constant then Claim 2: the interest rate decreases as the capital stock grows and the reserves of energy sources are consumed. Using equations 6 and 9 we get the price of capital goods and the interest rate, p γ0 = αa[k t ] α 1 φ E r t = ϕ αa[k t ] α 1 φ E 1 + e E,t ) 1 + φ E It is straightforward that rt k t < 0 and rt R t > 0. K t ))

220 ENERGY SAVING INNOVATIONS, NON-EXHAUSTIBLE SOURCES AND LONG-RUN From the solution of the consumer problem, equation 1, if there exists a steady state is must be characterized by 1 + r) = 1 β We have showed that in the long run the price of energy is given by φ N so it is possible to characterize the steady state using equations 10 and 13, k = αa ϕ 2 φ N β 1 β ) 1) 1 1 α 2