Discussion by Pete Klenow (Stanford University) of: BIG ANSWERS FOR BIG QUESTIONS: THE PRESUMPTION OF MACRO. By Abhijit Banerjee



Similar documents
Total Factor Productivity

Economic Growth. Prof. Fabrizio Zilibotti (University of Zurich) Università Bocconi, Spring 2016

What Capital is Missing in Developing Countries?

How Destructive is Innovation?

EC 591. INTERNATIONAL ECONOMICS Professor R Lucas: Fall 2015 Monday & Wednesday CAS 212

Chapter 11. Development Policymaking and the Roles of Market, State, and Civil Society. Copyright 2009 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

Selected Topics in International Economics

ECON 35101: International Macroeconomics and Trade University of Chicago, Fall Quarter, 2015 Syllabus

Growth Theory Since Solow and the Poverty of Nations: World Bank, April 26, Daron Acemoglu

The Future of US Economic Growth

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES MISSING GAINS FROM TRADE? Marc J. Melitz Stephen J. Redding. Working Paper

Further Discussion of Temporary Payroll Tax Cut During Recession(s) Mark Bils and Pete Klenow, December 12, 2008

Chapter 4 Technological Progress and Economic Growth

Randomized Evaluations of Interventions in Social Service Delivery

Are Poor Management Practices Holding Back Middle-Income Countries

HOW IMPORTANT IS BUSINESS R&D FOR ECONOMIC GROWTH AND SHOULD THE GOVERNMENT SUBSIDISE IT?

Gains from Trade: The Role of Composition

THE CONTRIBUTION OF ECONOMIC FREEDOM TO WORLD ECONOMIC GROWTH,

Technology and Economic Growth

The Future of U.S. Economic Growth

The RBC methodology also comes down to two principles:

ECG784 Topics in Economic Growth and Development

Measuring the Cross-Country Distribution of Gains from Trade

The Future of U.S. Economic Growth

ECONOMIC GROWTH. E0xxxx

SOCIAL AND NONMARKET BENEFITS FROM EDUCATION IN AN ADVANCED ECONOMY

Energy and Economics

Developing and Analyzing Firm-Level Indicators on Productivity and Reallocation

New Perspectives on Population Growth and Economic Development

DOES MORE SCHOOLING CAUSE BETTER HEALTH?

Overview of Growth Research in the Past Two Decades

Book Title: Other People s Money: Debt Denomination and Financial Instability in. Publisher: The University of Chicago Press, Chicago and London

How To Help The World

CEP Work on Economics of Brexit

References on Economic Growth

Problem 1. Steady state values for two countries with different savings rates and population growth rates.

Today s Research on Aging P ROGRAM AND P OLICY I MPLICATIONS Issue 3, May 2007

Accounting for Cross-Country Differences In Income Per Capita*

Research to improve the use and conservation of agricultural biodiversity for smallholder farmers

BIG DATA SCIENTIFIC AND COMMERCIAL APPLICATIONS (ITNPD4) LECTURE: DATA SCIENCE IN MEDICINE

Program Evaluation and the Design of Natural Experiments

Why Does Consumption Lead the Business Cycle?

Discussion of Gertler and Kiyotaki: Financial intermediation and credit policy in business cycle analysis

Episode Five: Place Matters

Exchange Rates and Foreign Direct Investment

Defending the Case for Free Trade. Arvind Panagariya. Several fallacious arguments against free trade were made in the debate on

Area 13 - Elenco delle Riviste di Classe A per Settore Concorsuale

Endogenous Technology Choices and the Dynamics of Wage Inequality

Intermediates Import and Gains from Trade Liberalization

The Japanese Saving Rate

Multinational Firms, FDI Flows and Imperfect Capital Markets

Technology production: A challenge for economic growth and development in Africa

University of Maryland School of Medicine Master of Public Health Program. Evaluation of Public Health Competencies

Expenditure on Health Care in the UK: A Review of the Issues

Education of Health Professionals for the 21 st Century. Barry Kistnasamy

Economic Change in India

Area13 Riviste di classe A

Area 13 - Elenco delle Riviste di Classe A per Settore Concorsuale (AGGIORNATO AL 01/10/2015)

ECONOMIC COSTS OF PHYSICAL INACTIVITY

The Decline of the U.S. Labor Share. by Michael Elsby (University of Edinburgh), Bart Hobijn (FRB SF), and Aysegul Sahin (FRB NY)

A Review of the Literature of Real Business Cycle theory. By Student E XXXXXXX

Top Ten Signs of Declining Business Dynamism and Entrepreneurship in the U.S.* John Haltiwanger University of Maryland and NBER.

PROVISIONAL SHEET FOR GRADUATE STUDENT. *Or 9 credit hours of courses in discipline approved by Advisory Committee

Principles on Health Care Reform

Economic Growth. (c) Copyright 1999 by Douglas H. Joines 1

Human Capital in a Developed Economy. Gary S. Becker

ID: U Abstract. Urban growth

The OLI or eclectic approach to the study of foreign direct investment (FDI) was

Lung Cancer a unique model for disease control A partnership program

A Three-Sector Model of Structural Transformation and Economic Development

Pharmacoeconomic, Epidemiology, and Pharmaceutical Policy and Outcomes Research (PEPPOR) Graduate Program

welfare costs of business cycles

JOURNAL RECOMMENDATIONS FOR ACADEMIC PUBLICATION. Alphabetical order

When Does Domestic Saving Matter for Economic. Growth? 1

Economics Course Descriptions

An Education Production Function for Botswanan Secondary Schools

Global Demographic Trends and their Implications for Employment

Review of knowledge capital and growth

Journal rankings: see next pages

Networks and Misallocation:

History & Fast Facts. Academic Programs. Research & Innovation. Education

TRADE AND FOOD SECURITY: A GLOBAL PERSPECTIVE

Management. matters. Stephen J. Dorgan and John J. Dowdy, When IT lifts productivity, The McKinsey Quarterly, 2004, Number 4, pp.,

Single Payer 101 Training Universal Health Care for Massachusetts

Double Master Degrees in International Economics and Development

Chapter 11. Market-Clearing Models of the Business Cycle

Masters of Science in Social Protection Financing (1 Year Full-Time) UMT609

The (mis)allocation of capital

Finance and Economics Course Descriptions

Curriculum for to the PhD Program in Pharmacy Administration

U.S. International Business Travel: Its Impact on U.S. Merchandise Exports. by Maksim Belenkiy and David Riker

Big Data for Population Health and Personalised Medicine through EMR Linkages

Trade Liberalization and Firm Productivity: The Case of India 1

Racial and Ethnic Disparities in Women s Health Coverage and Access To Care Findings from the 2001 Kaiser Women s Health Survey

Physical activity: a major public health priority. Professor Brian Oldenburg School of Public Health & Preventive Medicine, Monash University

The Link Between Openness and Long-Run Economic Growth

The Role of General Practitioners in preventing disease and promoting health in the Nordic countries

Healthcare Information Technology Trends in the Developing World

Industrial Policy in Sustainable Development Strategies

Areas where STATISTICS are used. Government Census, Law, National Defense

Transcription:

Discussion by Pete Klenow (Stanford University) of: BIG ANSWERS FOR BIG QUESTIONS: THE PRESUMPTION OF MACRO By Abhijit Banerjee Brookings Institution Global Economy and Development Conference on What Works in Development? Thinking Big and Thinking Small, Washington, D.C., May 2008.

I found Banerjee s paper a pleasure to read, both provocative and compelling. As Banerjee concedes, the most important questions in development are often macro ones such as how to boost growth in the fashion of China and India in recent decades. But, Banerjee emphasizes, we don t know very much about how to do this despite lots of research effort. So he suggests we largely abandon macro development research and concentrate on micro development questions such as the effect of randomized interventions in health and education. The following Table summarizes Banerjee s position. Welfare Welfare Knowledge = Research Knowledge Research Micro 0 Low High Macro 0? High Low I wholeheartedly agree with the micro row in this Table, so will say no more about it. Instead I will defend the value of doing macro development research. As I consider myself at the micro data end of the macro spectrum, I do this without feeling particularly defensive. I begin by drawing an analogy to potential micro vs. macro divides in medicine and biology. Consider micro researchers in medicine who do carefully controlled clinical trials and lab work. I imagine they might disdain macro medicine, which looks at trends in life expectancy, heart disease, cancer, autism, etc. Their skepticism may

extend to epidemiological studies (reduced form regressions) that relate individual outcomes to a variety of other individual observables. Micro researchers may rightly say we learn little about causality and effective treatments from such macro studies. Similarly, one can imagine a conflict between micro-biologists who study molecular biology, genetics, neuroscience, immunology, embryology, etc. and macro-biologists who study whole ecologies, i.e., populations and how their traits and numbers evolve and interact. A common element in macro medicine, macro biology and macro development is that they each motivate and guide a lot of the micro work that is done. In medicine, macro evidence has documented an obesity epidemic in the U.S., and epidemiological evidence has related obesity to heart disease, diabetes, and other ailments. This macro work has motivated a myriad of micro experiments on what sorts of diet, exercise, and drug interventions might best prevent or treat obesity and its complications. In biology, macro research has documented vanishing diversity of species, and related it to macro factors such as deforestation, pollution, and global climate change. As a result, biologists are studying the consequences of global warming for agriculture and animal populations. Some of these studies take the form of micro experiments, either natural or controlled (unnatural). Stanford is home to a famous biologist who does both macro and micro work, namely Robert Sapolsky. As he describes in A Primate s Memoir (2002), he has spent

many summers in Kenya studying baboon populations. He combines field observations with blood work to document social and individual correlates with stress hormones. He devotes the rest of his research year to lab work. He says his field work is critical for studying normal social interactions, as opposed to contrived lab environments. The field work motivates much of the lab work he does. Again, macro research tells us the disease, its severity, and its symptoms. Macro work tells us where randomized trials are most urgently needed. In macro development the extent of the disease is the difference in incomes between some African and OECD economies. The symptoms / correlates are low life expectancy, low investment rates in physical and human capital, high fertility rates, political instability, and so on. This macro research has presumably helped motivate the micro experiments on health and education in Africa. I know my own recent work with Chang-Tai Hsieh on China and India (Hsieh and Klenow, 2007b) has been motivated by macro evidence. China and India are poor and populous but growing fast. Macro development accounting leaves unexplained a nontrivial portion of their initial poverty and subsequent growth. Chang and I use micro data on manufacturing plants to assess the potential contribution of allocative efficiency. This particular hypothesis was also motivated by macro evidence, namely that growth took off in China and India in the wake of a series of policy reforms (privatization, trade and FDI liberalization, etc.) designed to improve allocative efficiency.

Like Robert Sapolsky, my Stanford economics colleague Nick Bloom does both macro and micro work. Indian manufacturing firms have lower productivity on average than firms in OECD countries, and Bloom and Van Reenen (2007) documented important differences in managerial practices between Indian and U.S. firms in regards to monitoring (e.g., how well are they tracking whether they are hitting their performance targets?), targets (e.g., are the targets realistic, aimed for, and economically rational?), and incentives (e.g., are people promoted based primarily on tenure or performance?). These macro findings have led Bloom and collaborators (Bloom et al., 2008) to embark on a randomized evaluation of whether management consulting services can improve productivity in Indian firms. Again, macro evidence is usefully motivating micro experimental work. I have mentioned growth and development accounting several times. Banerjee refers to this macro evidence as containing an unhelpfully wide range of estimates. But I do not think this assessment is accurate. I think a macro consensus exists on many points. To name a few: rising workers per capita accounts for one-fifth of growth in much of East Asia (Young, 1995); physical capital intensity accounts for one-fifth of income differences across countries (Mankiw et al. 1992, Hall and Jones 1999); much of China s growth has come from productivity growth in agriculture and movement of workers out of agriculture (Young 2003, Brandt et al. 2008); and productivity differences between rich and poor nations are concentrated in agriculture and investment sectors (Caselli 2005, Hsieh and Klenow 2007a).

Beyond accounting, macro has contributed a slew of robust correlations that help guide micro experimental work. Correlation need not imply causality, of course, but it certainly does not rule it out. Many correlations are later confirmed to be causal in various ways (lung cancer and smoking, earnings and education, life expectancy and income). Here are a few of the facts emphasized by recent macro development research: developing countries import most of their equipment, and from the U.S., Japan and Germany in particular (Eaton and Kortum, 2001); the local-currency return on reproducible capital is no higher in poor than rich countries (Caselli and Feyrer, 2007); the skill premium increases with liberalization of trade and FDI (Goldberg and Pavcnik, 2007); poor countries exhibit greater dispersion of average products of capital and labor across firms within industries (e.g., Hsieh and Klenow, 2007b). It is up to theorists and micro experimentalists to flesh out the causal mechanisms behind these correlations. On the issue of causality, there are some macro instruments. Climate (rainfall, temperature, windspeed and direction, etc.), geography (distance to the other land masses, ruggedness of terrain, etc.), and accidents (e.g., natural deaths of dictators) have been deployed in the last decade. Another strategy is to interact common shocks with different initial conditions. Acemoglu and Johnson (2007) interacted the epidemiological transition with different initial disease burdens to study the effects of reduced mortality on populations and incomes. And many authors have studied the effects of trade liberalization using the differential effect of a country s WTO entry on tariffs across its industries.

Macro development research consists of much more than cross-country growth regressions, however. Much of the work is not even particularly empirical. Examples include the classic growth theories of Lucas (1988), Romer (1990), Grossman and Helpman (1991), and Aghion and Howitt (1992), as well as the more recent work of Acemoglu (2007), Jones (2008), and others. I will not dwell on this theoretical literature because Banerjee readily (and predictably!) concedes that random evaluations must be combined with theorizing. We will always need general equilibrium models to fill in the gaps between results of randomized trials, and to do welfare analysis. In the past decade I have organized the NBER Summer Institute Growth Meeting with Chad Jones. The overwhelming majority of papers have been neither empirical nor theoretical, but instead what might be called quantitative theory (to use Prescott s phrase). This literature typically identifies exogenous driving forces (such as observable policy distortions documented by the World Bank s Doing Business studies), then calibrates a model to obtain a quantitative sense of how these driving forces might affect aggregates (income, investment, schooling, etc.) across time or countries. Like strictly theoretical work, I would argue such quantitative theorizing is a vital complement to micro empirical research. To sum up, I agree with everything Banerjee has written about the positive value of micro empirical work in development. But I am less sympathetic with his nihilism toward macro development research. To me, macro research remains enormously valuable alongside more definitive but narrower micro research.

References Acemoglu, Daron (2007), Introduction to Modern Economic Growth, forthcoming, Princeton University Press. Acemoglu, Daron and Simon Johnson (2007), Disease and Development: The Effect of Life Expectancy on Economic Growth, Journal of Political Economy 115 (December): 925-985. Aghion, Philippe and Peter Howitt (1992), A Model of Growth Through Creative Destruction, Econometrica 60 (March): 323-351. Loren Brandt, Chang-Tai Hsieh, and Xiaodong Zhu (2008), Growth and Structural Transformation in China, forthcoming in China's Great Economic Transformation, L. Brandt and T.G. Rawski, eds. (Cambridge University Press, New York). Bloom, Nick and John van Reenen (2007), Measuring and Explaining Management Practices Across Firms and Countries, Quarterly Journal of Economics 122 (November): 1351-1408. Bloom, Nick, Benn Eifert, Aprajit Mahajan, David McKenzie, John Roberts, Erik Jensen and Tom Heller (2008), Why are Indian Firms Poorly Managed? A Survey and Randomized Field Intervention, work in progress. Caselli, Francesco (2005), Accounting for Cross-Country Income Differences, Handbook of Economic Growth, P. Aghion and S. Durlauf, eds. (North Holland). Caselli, Francesco and James Feyrer (2007), The Marginal Product of Capital, Quarterly Journal of Economics 122 (May): 535-568. Eaton, Jonathan and Samuel S. Kortum (2001), Trade in Capital Goods, European Economic Review 45 (June): 1195-1235. Pavcnik, Nina and Pinelopi K. Goldberg (2007), Distributional Effects of Globalization in Developing Countries, Journal of Economic Literature 45 (March): 39-82. Grossman, Gene M. and Elhanan Helpman (1991), Innovation and Growth in the Global Economy, MIT Press, Cambridge. Hall, Robert E. and Charles I. Jones (1999), Why Do Some Countries Produce So Much More Output per Worker than Others? Quarterly Journal of Economics 114 (February): 83-116. Hsieh, Chang-Tai and Peter J. Klenow (2007a), Relative Prices and Relative Prosperity, American Economic Review 97 (June): 562-585.

Hsieh, Chang-Tai and Peter J. Klenow (2007b), Misallocation and Manufacturing TFP in China and India, NBER Working Paper 13290 (August). Jones, Charles I. (2008), Intermediate Goods, Weak Links, and Superstars: A Theory of Economic Development, unpublished paper (February). Lucas, Robert E. Jr. (1988), On the Mechanics of Economic Development, Journal of Monetary Economics 22 (July): 3-42. Mankiw, N. Gregory, David Romer, and David N. Weil (1992), A Contribution to the Empirics of Economic Growth, Quarterly Journal of Economics 107 (May): 407-437. Romer, Paul M. (1990), Endogenous Technological Change, Journal of Political Economy 98 (October): S71-S102. Sapolsky, Robert M. (2002), A Primate's Memoir: A Neuroscientist's Unconventional Life Among the Baboons, Scribner Press. Young, Alwyn (1995), The Tyranny of Numbers: Confronting the Statistical Realities of the East Asian Growth Experience, Quarterly Journal of Economics 110 (August): 641-680. Young, Alwyn (2003), Gold into Base Metals: Productivity Growth in the People's Republic of China During the Reform Period, Journal of Political Economy 111 (December): 1220-1261.