On the Interconnection of Networks and Gains from Trade in Business Services



Similar documents
Corporate Income Taxation

Gains from trade in a Hotelling model of differentiated duopoly

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES MISSING GAINS FROM TRADE? Marc J. Melitz Stephen J. Redding. Working Paper

Real Wage and Nominal Price Stickiness in Keynesian Models

Oligopoly and Trade. Notes for Oxford M.Phil. International Trade. J. Peter Neary. University of Oxford. November 26, 2009

MIT PhD International Trade Lecture 9: Increasing Returns to Scale and Monopolistic Competition (Theory)

Hyun-soo JI and Ichiroh DAITOH Tohoku University. May 25, Abstract

Welfare E ecta Ectal model of Trade

Quality differentiation and entry choice between online and offline markets

An optimal redistribution scheme for trade gains

How To Find Out How To Balance The Two-Country Economy

INTERNATIONAL ECONOMICS, FINANCE AND TRADE Vol.I - Economics of Scale and Imperfect Competition - Bharati Basu

Can a Lump-Sum Transfer Make Everyone Enjoy the Gains. from Free Trade?

Unilateral and Multilateral Gains from Trade in International Oligopoly

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES MARKET SIZE, DIVISION OF LABOR, AND FIRM PRODUCTIVITY. Thomas Chaney Ralph Ossa

Imported Inputs and the Gains from Trade

Lecture 9: Keynesian Models

Paid Placement: Advertising and Search on the Internet

Population aging, education and skill premium in international trade

The Greater the Differences, the Greater the Gains?

Economics II: Micro Fall 2009 Exercise session 5. Market with a sole supplier is Monopolistic.

EconS Advanced Microeconomics II Handout on Cheap Talk

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES WHEN DOES LABOR SCARCITY ENCOURAGE INNOVATION? Daron Acemoglu. Working Paper

Optimal insurance contracts with adverse selection and comonotonic background risk

Heterogeneous firms and dynamic gains from trade

Chapter 4. Specific Factors and Income Distribution

The Stock Market, Monetary Policy, and Economic Development

Gains from Trade: The Role of Composition

Labor Market Cycles and Unemployment Insurance Eligibility

Introduction to Macroeconomics TOPIC 2: The Goods Market

The Real Business Cycle Model

Cowles Foundation for Research in Economics at Yale University

Economic Growth: Lectures 2 and 3: The Solow Growth Model

Lectures, 2 ECONOMIES OF SCALE

Discussion of Growing Like China

Technology Licensing by Advertising Supported Media Platforms: An Application to Internet Search Engines

The New Trade Theory. Monopoly and oligopoly in trade. Luca De Benedictis 1. Topic 3. 1 University of Macerata

ECO364 - International Trade

Market Penetration Costs and the New Consumers Margin in International Trade

WELFARE ENHANCING COORDINATION IN CONSUMER COOPERATIVES UNDER MIXED OLIGOPOLY. WP-EMS Working Papers Series in Economics, Mathematics and Statistics

Research Policy and U.S. Economic Growth

The Specific-Factors Model: HO Model in the Short Run

Domestic and Cross-Border Mergers in Unionized Oligopoly

Aggregative Oligopoly Games with Entry 1

The Global Impact of Chinese Growth

UNIVERSITY OF OSLO DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS

Direct Investment Liberalization, Commodity Trade, and Income Distribution: What Can the WTO Do? Kar-yiu Wong University of Washington

Labor Market Cycles, Unemployment Insurance Eligibility, and Moral Hazard

tariff versus quota Equivalence and its breakdown

The E ect of Trading Commissions on Analysts Forecast Bias

University of Saskatchewan Department of Economics Economics Homework #1

LICOS Centre for Transition Economics

Common sense, and the model that we have used, suggest that an increase in p means a decrease in demand, but this is not the only possibility.

The Prison S Dilemma and Its Connections

The Timing of Signaling: To Study in High School or in College?

WORKING PAPER NO DO FALLING ICEBERG COSTS EXPLAIN RECENT U.S. EXPORT GROWTH? George Alessandria Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia

Economic Development and Gains from Trade

On the irrelevance of government debt when taxes are distortionary

GROWTH, INCOME TAXES AND CONSUMPTION ASPIRATIONS

Do capital adequacy requirements reduce risks in banking?

Does horizontal FDI lead to more knowledge spillovers than vertical FDI?

Online shopping and platform design with ex ante registration requirements

Net neutrality and innovation at the core and at the edge

Optimal Investment. Government policy is typically targeted heavily on investment; most tax codes favor it.

RATIONALIZATION AND SPECIALIZATION

Unemployment Insurance in the Presence of an Informal Sector

Optimal Unemployment and Disability Insurance*

Information Gatekeepers on the Internet and the Competitiveness of. Homogeneous Product Markets. By Michael R. Baye and John Morgan 1.

Capital markets, nancial intermediaries, and liquidity supply

Contract Law and the Boundaries of the Firm

Pricing Health Bene ts: A Cost-Minimization Approach

INTEGRATION VERSUS OUTSOURCING IN INDUSTRY EQUILIBRIUM*

Business models for media rms: Does competition matter for how they raise revenue?

Lecture 1: The intertemporal approach to the current account

Exchange Rate Pass-Through, Markups, and Inventories

CHAPTER 7: AGGREGATE DEMAND AND AGGREGATE SUPPLY

How Does the Life Settlement A ect the Primary Life Insurance Market?

TRADE WITH SCALE ECONOMIES AND IMPERFECT COMPETITION (CONT'D)

Employment Protection and Business Cycles in Emerging Economies

International Pricing with Costly Consumer Arbitrage

Market Power and Efficiency in Card Payment Systems: A Comment on Rochet and Tirole

Import Substitution and Economic Growth

the transmission channels of monetary policy the fragility of the nancial system the existence of nancial cycles

1 Further Pricing Relationships on Options

Class Notes, Econ 8801 Lump Sum Taxes are Awesome

Real Business Cycle Theory. Marco Di Pietro Advanced () Monetary Economics and Policy 1 / 35

Implications of Intellectual Property Rights for Dynamic Gains from Trade

How To Model Fair Trade

Employee Stock Options, Financing Constraints, and Real Investment

A. GDP, Economic Growth, and Business Cycles

Pareto gains from trade: a dynamic counterexample

4. Only one asset that can be used for production, and is available in xed supply in the aggregate (call it land).

Short Run Market Equilibrium. The market supply curve is found by horizontally adding the supply curves of individual rms. If there are m rms, we have

Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Reports. Deficits, Public Debt Dynamics, and Tax and Spending Multipliers

Adverse selection, moral hazard and. propitious selection 1

Dollar Pricing, the Euro and Monetary Policy Transmission

Optimal Paternalism: Sin Taxes and Health Subsidies

Three Essays on Monopolist Second-degree Discrimination Strategies in the Presence of Positive Network E ects by Gergely Csorba

Midterm Exam - Answers. November 3, 2005

Volatility, Productivity Correlations and Measures of. International Consumption Risk Sharing.

Transcription:

Toru Kikuchi / Journal of Economic Research 8 (2003) 69{76 69 On the Interconnection of Networks and Gains from Trade in Business Services Toru Kikuchi 1 Kobe University Received 1 April 2003; accepted 1 November 2003 Abstract Using a two-country model of monopolistic competition with country-speci c communications networks, this note establishes a link between gains from trade in intermediate business services and gains from the interconnection of networks. Keywords: Monopolistic competition; Interconnection of communications networks; Trade in intermediate business services JEL classi cation: D43; F12 1 Introduction Ever since the seminal work of Ethier (1979), intra-industry trade in intermediate business services (e.g., business software development, accounting, data processing) has been one of the major aspects of trade theory. Harris (1998) explores an important relationship between trade in business services and advancement in communications networks (e.g., the Internet, mobile telecommunications networks). 2 1 Graduate School of Economics, Kobe University 2-1, Rokkodai Nada,Kobe,Japan, (e-mail) kikuchi@econ.kobe-u.ac.jp. The author is grateful to James Atsu Amegashie, David Anderson and two anonymous referees for helpful comments. The author is also grateful to the Department of Economics at Simon Fraser University for generous support and hospitality over the period in which this paper was written. 2 Along this line, Kikuchi(2002) develops a two-country trade model that emphasizes theroleofcommunicationsnetworksin determining comparative advantages. See, also, Kikuchi(2003).

70 On the Interconnection of Networks and Gains from Trade in Business Services He emphasizes that advanced networks will facilitate the enhancement of international trade in intermediate business services.evidence of this includes, for example, the fact that sophisticated software engineers from India can deliver their services to the United States and Europe via the Internet. In the trade theory literature, however, relatively little is known about the welfare consequences of trade in intermediate business services via communications networks. The main contribution of this note is to establish a link between gains from trade in intermediate business services and gains through network e ects. These links are obtained by introducing the concept of `interconnected networks' into the workhorse two-country model of monopolistic competition (i.e., Krugman, 1980). In this model, a country is treated as a collection of regions which produce di erentiated business services and exchange them via a country-speci c communications network. The welfare e ects of the international exchange of services are examined on the basis of this model. Trade liberalization in the service sector can be interpreted as the interconnection of countryspeci c networks. It will be shown that the distribution of gains from the interconnection of networks will be varied according to the degree of substitution between business services. The next section develops a model of monopolistic competition in which business services are traded via country-speci c networks. Section 3 deals with the question of the distribution of gains from the interconnection of networks. 2 The Model Suppose that there are two countries in the world, Home and Foreign, and that they are similar in regard to consumers' preferences and production technologies but not necessarily in regard to size. There is only one primary factor of production: labor. There are two sectors: the competitive sector which uses only business services as inputs, and the monopolistically competitive sector which produces a large variety of business services. A country might be thought of as a collection of regions among which business services are exchanged via a countryspeci c communications network. Each region is endowed with L units

Toru Kikuchi / Journal of Economic Research 8 (2003) 69{76 71 of labor, and labor is assumed to be physically immobile across regions. Home (Foreign) consists of m(m )regions. Without loss of generality, Home is assumed to be larger than Foreign (m >m ). Each region's production function of the nal good is as follows: 3 Ã 1 nx µ X = x µ! i ; 0 <µ<1; (1) i where n is the number of available intermediate business services, x i is the quantity of service i, and1=(1 µ) > 1 is the elasticity of substitution between every pair of services. Business services are supplied by monopolistically competitive rms. The central assumption is that both the production and the distribution of services require communications through the country-speci c network, which is provided by the natural monopolist. To get on the network, each service rm has to pay a xed fee, w, where w is the wage rate. 4 Once each rm gets on the network, it has a constant marginal cost, w. With the number of service rms being very large, the elasticity of demand for each service becomes 1=(1 µ). Thus each service is priced at a markup over marginal cost: p = w=µ. Withn rms, the pro t of each rm, ¼, is given as: ¼ = px w( + x). Thus the level of output thatgenerateszeropro tsisgivenby¹x = µ= (1 µ). If a region does not exchange business services with other regions, the output level of that region becomes X = n (1 µ)=µ (n¹x): (2) The number of services produced within a region is given by n =(1 µ)l=. In what follows, units are chosen such that n = 1: each region is assumed to produce one type of service, and without exchange, that is the only service available to the region. At monopolistically competitive equilibrium, each region specializes in a di erent service. 3 One may think of this as the utility of households that are consuming di erentiated consumption goods. 4 This assumption implies (a) that there are aggregate constant returns in providing communications services, and (b) that the pricing of communications services is done on an average-cost basis. See Harris (1998).

72 On the Interconnection of Networks and Gains from Trade in Business Services Consider the Home autarky equilibrium in which m regions' services are exchanged via a Home-speci c communications network. In this case, service rms in each region send their own services to other regions via the network. At the same time, the volume of services importsineachregionisgivenby¹x(m 1)=m. This implies that, in each region, nal good producers assemble m types of services provided via the network. Each region produces the following amount of output: X = m (1 µ)=µ ¹x. Thus, one can think of Home (Foreign) itself as representing a network of size m(m ). The total amount of the Home output becomes: V A mx A = m (m (1 µ)=µ ¹x) =m 1=µ ¹x; where superscript A represents the autarky value. This shows that the productivity per region (V=m) rises as the total number of regions increases. The productivity bene ts of communications are the gains from trade that accrue from increased specialization in the provision of business services. 5 3 Gains from the Interconnection of Networks This section investigates the welfare consequences of trade in business services. Before turning to the analysis, some terminology needs to be clari ed. First, `trade in services' is synonymous with the `interconnection of country-speci c networks': through the interconnected networks, every service rm sends its service to the other country. Second, gains from the interconnection of networks are measured in terms of changes in the level of total output. Suppose that two countries of size m and m are connected through the internationally interconnected networks: Home-speci c network and Foreign-speci c network are interconnected. 6 In this case, both coun- 5 In the literature of network economics, network e ects denote positive externality, which is di erent from the simple proportional increase of output with the increased service diversity discussed here (e.g., Katz and Shapiro, 1985). However, in this model, to keep matters simple, it is assumed that there is no positive externality, although it is important to include the positive externality e ect. 6 It is natural to assume that there is an additional cost of interconnection for each network. However, to keep matters simple, assume that there are no additional costs.

Toru Kikuchi / Journal of Economic Research 8 (2003) 69{76 73 tries will gain through an increase in the range of available business services. In each region, nal good producers assemble m + m types of services provided via the interconnected networks. Thus the total amount of the Home output becomes: 7 V T mx T = m (m + m ) (1 µ)=µ ¹x; where superscript T represents the trading equilibrium. Increases in the level of output in each country are calculated as: V V T V A =[m (m + m ) (1 µ)=µ m 1=µ ]¹x; (3) V V T V A =[m (m + m ) (1 µ)=µ m 1=µ ]¹x: (4) Subtracting (4) from (3) yields the relationship V V =[(m m ) (m + m ) (1 µ)=µ m 1=µ + m 1=µ ]¹x: (5) 7 Since the zero-pro t output ¹x remainsconstantinthismodel,thereareneither gains nor loss from changes in each rm's average cost. Thus, the gains from trade come solely through increased service diversity. Krugman (1979) develops a di erent model in which trade leads to an increase in scale of production as well as an increase in diversity.

74 On the Interconnection of Networks and Gains from Trade in Business Services Figure 1. Figure 1 plots the relationship between V V and µ. This shows that gains from the interconnection of networks might be asymmetrical between the two countries. This surprising feature can be summarized as follows: Proposition: If the elasticity of substitution is below (above) the cuto level, the larger country will gain more (less) than the smaller one from the interconnection of networks. Two special cases warrant further attention. First, given that µ < 0:5 holds, the di erence in gains grows as µ decreases, i.e., the value placed on variety increases. The reason is as follows. From (2),

Toru Kikuchi / Journal of Economic Research 8 (2003) 69{76 75 it follows that X is convex (concave) in the number of available services when µ<(>)0:5. 8 Thus, given that µ<(>)0:5 holds, the larger (smaller) a country is, the more it gains from interconnection. This result is quite contrary to the one from the competitive analysis (i.e., the smaller country gains more than the larger country). 9 It also implies that there might be asymmetric incentives for interconnection. Thus, when network e ects are incorporated into trade models, the argument for trade gains might require modi cation. Next, consider the case in which µ =0:5. Here the value of the Home network before interconnection takes place is m 2, in accordance with `Metacalfe's Law' which says that the usefulness of a network is proportional to the m 2 of the number of people it connects. In this case, from (5), one can conclude that each country gets equal value from interconnection (i.e., V V = 0). The intuition behind this is fairly simple. On one hand, each region in the larger country gets a bit of extra value from connecting to the smaller country, but there are many regions. On the other hand, each region in the smaller country gains more through an increase in the number of available services, but there are fewer regions in the smaller country. 10 This implies that, given the particular value of the elasticity of substitution, gains from interconnection are split more or less equally, even among countries of di erent size. As Varian (2000) suggests, this gives some rationale for why settlement-free interconnection is common among large backbone providers of the Internet. Though the model presented here is extremely simple and crucially dependent on several restrictive assumptions, it establishes a link between the workhorse trade model of monopolistic competition and network e ects. Furthermore, the analysis presented here provides at least some grounds for the widespread concern over gains from the interconnection of networks. 8 By using (2), it is easy to calculate that partialx=partialnj n¹x=const: = [(1 µ)=µ]n (1 2µ)=µ (n¹x), and @ 2 X=@n 2 j n¹x=const: =[(1 µ)(1 2µ)=µ 2 ]n (1 3µ)=µ (n¹x). 9 This is known as Mill's Paradox. See Chipman (1965). 10 One can also interpret this result as follows: V canbeexpressedas V = m v; where v measures gains from trade per region. For the larger country m is greater than m, but v is smaller than v. Thus, whether V is greater than V or not depends on the value of variety.

76 On the Interconnection of Networks and Gains from Trade in Business Services References Chipman, J. S.,\A survey of the theory of international trade: part 1, the classical theory," Econometrica 33, 1965, 477{519. Ethier, W. J.,\Internationally decreasing costs and world trade," Journal of International Economics 9, 1979, 1{24. Harris, R. G.,\Internet as the GPT," in: Helpman, E., ed., General Purpose Technologies and Economic Growth, MIT Press, Cambridge, 1998, 145{166. Katz, M. L. and C. Shapiro,\Network externalities, competition, and compatibility,"american Economic Review 75, 1985, 424{440. Kikuchi, T.,\Country-speci c communications networks and international trade in a model of monopolistic competition," Japanese Economic Review 53, 2002, 167{176. Kikuchi, T.,\Interconnectivity of communications networks and international trade," Canadian Journal of Economics 36, 2003, 155{167. Krugman, P.,\Increasing returns, monopolistic competition, and international trade," Journal of International Economics 9, 1979, 469{ 479. Krugman, P., \Scale economies, product di erentiation, and pattern of trade," American Economic Review 70, 1980, 950{959. Varian, H. R.,\Market structure in the network age," in: Brynjolfsson, E. and B. Kahin, eds., Understanding the Digital Economy, MIT Press, Cambridge, 2000, 137{150.