Compulsory licences: necessity or threat?

Similar documents
Intellectual Property and Access to HIV/AIDS Treatment Case Studies

GENEVA STANDING COMMITTEE ON THE LAW OF PATENTS. Fourteenth Session Geneva, January 25 to 29, 2010 PROPOSAL FROM BRAZIL *

RE: Transatlantic Business Concerns about Indian Government IP Policies

EROSION OF EXCLUSIVE MARKETING RIGHTS- BOON FOR THE PHARMACEUTICAL SECTOR

TACD RECOMMENDATIONS ON HEALTH CARE AND INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY AND EUROPEAN COMMISSION SERVICES RESPONSES

Access to Medicines and Vaccines: Implications of Intellectual Property Protection and Trade Agreements

ar gthe international journal of

The Pharmaceutical Industry and the Patent System. Bruce Lehman 1 President, International Intellectual Property Institute

Privilege - pitfalls and obstacles for clients operating in multiple jurisdictions

Training Course on the Public Health Implications of Multilateral Trade Agreements, University of Lausanne (14-18 June 2004)

Profiting from Non-Technological Innovation: The Value of Patenting. Novak druce centre insights No. 8

DISAPPLYING PRE-EMPTION RIGHTS A STATEMENT OF PRINCIPLES

The Role of Government in the Economy

Insurance and compensation in the event of injury in Phase I clinical trials

Implications of change in Government

WIPO TRAINING OF TRAINERS PROGRAM ON EFFECTIVE INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY ASSET MANAGEMENT BY SMALL AND MEDIUM-SIZED ENTERPRISES (SMEs)

South Africa s IP Policy

Are We There Yet? Taking "TRIPS" to Brazil and Expanding Access to HIV/AIDS Medication

Government intervention

English - Or. English DIRECTORATE FOR FINANCIAL AND ENTERPRISE AFFAIRS COMPETITION COMMITTEE

TOWARDS MORE COHERENCE BETWEEN INTERNATIONAL TRADE AND THE RIGHTS OF THE CHILD

THE POTENTIAL IMPACT OF FREE TRADE AGREEMENTS ON PUBLIC HEALTH

Republic of Turkey. Date of acceptance: 9 November 2007 PART 1. Goal, scope, definitions and abbreviations. Goal and scope.

liquidators, it does not provide cover for fraud, dishonesty or misappropriation by the liquidator him or herself.

The dispute is about the sale of a payment protection insurance (PPI) policy in connection with a credit card account with the firm in April 2007.

Beat the AIDS epidemic Press for fair prices and better access to medicines.

Financial Services (Collective Investment Schemes) FINANCIAL SERVICES (EXPERIENCED INVESTOR FUNDS) REGULATIONS 2012

TRADEMARK LICENSE AGREEMENT & GUIDELINES

Innovation Toolbox. Evaluate Idea PREPARED BY: Australian Institute for Commercialisation. and

CANADA Patent Rules as amended by SOR/

ASTRAZENECA GLOBAL POLICY LEGAL AND INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY

NORTHERN TERRITORY ELECTRICITY RING-FENCING CODE

The Principal Fiduciary Duties of Boards of Directors

DESIGN SERVICES AGREEMENT

Parallel Importation: Economic and social welfare dimensions

Part 3: Arbitration Title 1: General Provisions

REGULATION OF SERVICE PROVIDERS IN THE NSW WORKERS COMPENSATION SYSTEM. Submission to WorkCover March 2011

OFFER BY WPP GROUP PLC ("WPP")

JRI S STANDARD TERMS OF PURCHASE. Business Day: a day (other than a Saturday, Sunday or public holiday) when banks in London are open for business.

SYLLABUS BASICS OF INTERNATIONAL TAXATION. ! States levy taxes by virtue of their sovereignty

The Free Market Approach. The Health Care Market. Sellers of Health Care. The Free Market Approach. Real Income

January GROUP CODE OF CONDUCT

MODEL FORM OF INTERNATIONAL PATENT LICENCE CONTRACT INTRODUCTION

Importing Western Style, Exporting Tragedy: Changes in Indian Patent Law and Their Impact on AIDS Treatment in Africa

AGREEMENT BETWEEN THE GOVERNMENT OF THE ITALIAN REPUBLIC AND THE GOVERNMENT OF ON THE PROMOTION AND PROTECTION OF INVESTMENTS

NORWAY Prepared by Hans Rugset Braekhus Dege Advokatfirma ANS

Philippines Philippines Philippinen. Report Q202. in the name of the Philippine Group by Rogelio NICANDRO

'(0878$/,=$7,21 5(*,0( )25 &$1$',$1 /,)(,1685$1&( &203$1,(6 CONSULTATION PAPER August 1998

GLOBAL ACCESS LICENSING FRAMEWORK

The guidance will be developed over time in the light of practical experience.

Malaysia Takeover Guide

Shoulda, woulda, coulda : the non-infringing alternative in Canada. J Bradley White and Brad Jenkins Osler, Hoskin & Harcourt LLP

Colombia's decision on compulsory license & access to HIV/AIDS medicine LPV/r

Scottish Families Affected by Alcohol and Drugs

The Patents Act 1977 (as amended)

Trade Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights (TRIPS): Protecting patents or patients?

INTELLECTUAL. Hkkjrh; izfrli/kkz vk;ksx UNDER THE COMPETITION ACT, 2002 COMPETITION COMMISSION OF INDIA ADVOCACY BOOKLET

National Trends and Developments in Workers Compensation

European Union Law and Online Gambling by Marcos Charif

PATENT LITIGATION IN MEXICO: OVERVIEW AND STRATEGY

THE TRADE SECRETS DIRECTIVE THE NEW COUNCIL PROPOSAL 1 WOUTER PORS. Bird & Bird The Hague. 1. Introduction and general issues

REPUBLIC OF PORTUGAL. MINISTRY OF PUBLIC WORKS, TRANSPORT AND COMMUNICATIONS The Minister's Office

TESTIMONY LEONARD CHANIN COMMITTEE ON BANKING, HOUSING, AND URBAN AFFAIRS UNITED STATES SENATE ASSESSING THE EFFECTS OF CONSUMER FINANCE REGULATIONS

Enterprise bargaining

DESIGN RIGHT (JERSEY) LAW 200-

INDUSTRIAL PROPERTY ACT, 2010 ARRANGEMENT OF SECTIONS

Unjustified threats on intellectual property rights: Government Response

Lloyd s Accident and Illness Insurance (UK)

FACT SHEET PREPARED BY THE MINISTRY OF JUSTICE ON THE DANGEROUS DRUGS (AMENDMENT) ACT 2015 OVERVIEW

Article 1: Subject. Article 2: Orders - Order Confirmation

EMPLOYMENT CONTRACTS ACT

This Chief Counsel Advice responds to your request for assistance. This advice may not be used or cited as precedent.

The Society of Actuaries in Ireland

Principles and Practices for the Sale of Products and Services by Property and Casualty Insurance Brokers

AGREEMENT BETWEEN THE GOVERNMENT OF NEPAL AND THE GOVERNMENT OF INDIA FOR THE PROMOTION AND PROTECTION OF INVESTMENTS

THE EUROPEAN UNION AND FRANCHISING

Israel LEVITAN, SHARON & CO. Peggy Sharon and Dror Zamir office@levitansharon.co.il. 1. Insurance intermediation activities

SSARS 19. Objectives and Limitations of Compilation and Review Engagements. Hierarchy of Compilation and Review Standards and Guidance

Medical Liability Insurance Related Problems and Damages in Medical Malpractice Lawsuits Stephen Ballantine

Preparing for and responding to influenza pandemics: Roles and responsibilities of Roche. Revised August 2014

From I.P to N.P A Call for a New Paradigm. Dr A. Schwartz

Written evidence for the Department of Business, Innovation and Skills: a small business commissioner

Executive summary and overview of the national report for Denmark

Association of Mortgage Intermediaries response to FSA consultation on the assessment and redress of payment protection insurance complaints CP09/23

Annex 8. Market Failure in Broadcasting

Submission of comments on 'Policy 0070 on publication and access to clinical-trial data'

DTI Consultation on Proposals for a Special Administrator Regime for Energy Network Companies Ofgem s Response

PUBLIC OFFER AGREEMENT

Authority and Power. What is Power?

Law of Georgia On the Investment Activity Promotion and Guarantees

BEFORE THE CONTROLLER OF PATENTS, DELHI VERSUS AFFIDAVIT. I, James Packard Love, aged 62 years, do hereby state on solemn affirmation the following:

The Trialogue on Key Information Documents for Investment Products

STERIS Corporation to Contest U.S. Federal Trade Commission's Attempt to Block Synergy Health Acquisition

Econ 101: Principles of Microeconomics

If you are signing for a minor child, you refers to your child throughout the consent document.

Complaints about unauthorised discounts offered by PCCW-HKT Telephone Limited to business customers

GCM Prime Ltd. Risk Warning

Investor Protection for your Standard Life product

ALTERNATIVE TRADING SYSTEM RULES

Pennino Corporation TECHNOLOGY TO IMPROVE LIFE

Transcription:

Page 1 of 5 Compulsory licences: necessity or threat? 23 May 2013 Chemistry World Are compulsory licences for patent-protected drugs a necessary measure, or a threat to innovation? Six international experts give their opinions. Joanna Thurston The use of compulsory licences in India and some other countries is attracting attention around the world, and rightly so. Allowing governments to intervene in patent matters in this way, without an extremely good reason, is a dangerous precedent, which could have unexpected consequences for the countries involved. According to the Trade-Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights (TRIPS) agreement, compulsory licences should only be granted in specific circumstances, including public health crises. For example, if the population of a particular country needs a potentially life-saving invention as quickly as possible and the patent holder is unable or unwilling to meet the demand. Compulsory licences for HIV retroviral efavirenz have been issued in Thailand and Brazil Rungroj Yongrit/EPA/Corbis With this in mind, it is concerning to find so much variation in the legislation and its interpretation. The decision by the Indian Patent Office to impose a compulsory licence against Bayer in 2012, forcing the company to allow a local manufacturer to produce a generic version of the cancer drug Nexavar (sorafenib), has had a particularly unsettling effect on the pharmaceutical industry. In this case, the drug in question is not life-saving, but rather life-extending, and the decision taken by the court seems to be based on making the drug available to as many people as possible, as cheaply as possible, and on promoting local manufacturing. Does this really constitute right and proper use of the legislation? In the UK, the legislation is much tighter. In fact it s hard to think of a time when a compulsory licence would be required. The last time we came close was during the early stages of the Rwanda Aids crisis, where the pressure on big pharma to release large quantities of drugs for export was huge. In this case, the manufacturers met the demand directly with a low cost product, avoiding the need for any enforcement action. For countries like India, which have lucrative generics industries and where consumer demand for all kinds of products, including medicines, is growing rapidly, the desire to interpret the law more loosely must be very tempting. However, there are many reasons why countries should think twice before granting a compulsory licence.

Page 2 of 5 Patent protection and the commercial opportunity it presents are intended to compensate the patent holder for their investment in research and development, which is likely to have taken a number of years. If countries grant compulsory licences too freely, innovators are deprived of the full benefit of their monopoly rights. As a result, big pharma could be discouraged from investing in drugs that only have a market in developing countries for example, for conditions like malaria or dysentery. Collaborating with companies in such countries also becomes unattractive. Ultimately, such countries could become isolated, with less control over drugs that may be needed to treat their populations in the future. Short-term considerations based on cost and availability should not overshadow the importance of nurturing the drug discovery process that benefits everyone. Joanna Thurston is a partner and patent attorney at Withers & Rogers Siraprapha Rungpry During December 2006 January 2007, Thailand s Ministry of Public Health issued compulsory licences on three patented drugs. The health minister at the time took a strong view against expensive patented drugs and believed that these licences were the solution to improving access to medicines. The legitimacy of these licences was debated extensively, both in Thailand and abroad. Despite the controversy, compulsory licences on three further drugs were announced by the health minister by early 2008. Governments should refrain from issuing compulsory licences in all but the most severe circumstances, for instance severe shortages of drugs, or a state of war. The Thai Patent Act reflects an effort to strike a balance between the critical needs of the public and firm protection of intellectual property (IP) rights. The section of the law that permits compulsory licences is limited to: 1 Carrying out any service for public consumption or for the defence of the country 2 The preservation or acquisition of natural resources and the environment 3 Preventing or alleviating a severe shortage of food or medicine 4 Other public interests Thus, an argument could be made that the intent of the law is to restrict the use of a compulsory licence only to those (rare) situations where it is crucial and cannot be avoided. Moreover, prior consultation and negotiation (in good faith) with the patent owners should always take place before the ministry steps in to issue a compulsory licence. Demand for Tamiflu (oseltamivir) has prompted governments to consider compulsory licences Richard Chung/Reuters/Corbis In the cases above, unfortunately, the underlying justifications and the validity of the compulsory licences are problematic. The totality of circumstances regarding access to medicines was not as severe as in other countries, and would not otherwise merit the issuance of compulsory licences on these six particular drugs. As a matter of public policy, it is highly doubtful whether compulsory licences benefit patients and improve the healthcare system in the long run. Given the high costs of drug development, it is difficult to justify forcing the patent owners to give up their IP rights. If they are frequently employed without proper grounds, such

Page 3 of 5 interventions will reduce investment in research and development of new drugs and the availability of drugs in the Thai market, which will harm Thai patients in the long term. Siraprapha Rungpry is a consultant at Tilleke & Gibbins Prashant Reddy On 9 March 2012, the Indian Patent Office (IPO) issued its very first compulsory licence for a pharmaceutical drug, since India re-introduced patent protection for pharmaceutical products in 2005. The drug in question, Nexavar, manufactured by Bayer, was prescribed for the treatment for both liver cancer and kidney cancer. The licencee was required to pay Bayer royalties at 6% of its net sales, a negligible amount, given that the licencee was selling the drug at a fraction of Bayer s original price. The IPO granted the licence on the grounds that the drug was not being made available to Indian patients at an affordable price and also that the drug was being imported instead of being manufactured in India. Both reasons have their basis in the text of the 1970 Indian Patents Act. The IPO s decision predictably came under heavy criticism from the pharmaceutical industry on the grounds that it would be a disincentive to innovate and dissuade potential investors from participating in the inherently risky business of pharmaceutical innovation. The crux of the compulsory licence debate between the pharmaceutical industry of the developed world and the governments of the developing world is the very idea of such licences in patent law. The innovator pharmaceutical industry and their governments view compulsory licences solely through the prism of competition law or scenarios of national emergencies. The developing world views them in the context of human rights, where every patient is entitled to life-saving medicine. The competition law argument authorises compulsory licences only when the patentee is found to be abusing its monopoly rights. One such area was airplane technology, which suffered from stunted growth until the US government forced the Wright Brothers to license their patent to competitors. Similarly, during the anthrax crisis or the bird-flu pandemic, there was demand even in the western world for compulsory licences to be issued as the treatments in both cases were patented. The human rights perspective, taken by developing countries like India, is not really grounded in such economic theory. It presumes that incentives to innovate will not be affected by a compulsory licence in just one territory of a globalised market. The only objective of a human rights policy is to make sure drugs are affordable for patients, most of whom lack public or private medical insurance policies. Similarly, developed countries oppose laws that require patented inventions to be manufactured in all the territories where they are sold on the grounds that patentees should have the freedom to decide how and where to manufacture their products. Developing countries on the other hand are hungry for technology transfer. The difference in perspectives between the developing world and developed world is stark, with no right answer. Prashant Reddy is studying law at Stanford Law School, US Darren Smyth Compulsory licences fundamentally violate a patentee s monopoly right, and should only be applied in exceptional cases. The essential bargain at the heart of the patent system that the reward for disclosing an invention is a temporary monopoly right is almost universally accepted internationally, across all technologies. This should be interfered with only in grave circumstances. In pharmaceuticals, the patentee will not only have invested resources into developing the drug, but will also (usually) have funded the regulatory approval process.

Page 4 of 5 India s refusal to grant a patent for the cancer treatment imatinib has also caused controversy Sanjeev Gupta/EPA/Corbis In general, I consider that only two scenarios justify a compulsory licence: genuine emergency or public need; or egregious conduct on the part of the patentee. Examples might be a health epidemic, or refusal to supply in a territory, or only at a discriminatory price. I am absolutely opposed to a compulsory licence being available simply because a patentee does not manufacture in a particular jurisdiction. And I am similarly opposed to a compulsory licence being granted on the basis of price alone. I am of course sympathetic to the distress felt in areas where some pharmaceuticals may be unaffordable to many. But I do not see the emasculation of the patent system as a sustainable answer. It may work in a few cases to allow a generic manufacturer to undercut a patent holder, but the result will be that patent holder will stop offering that drug in that country in order to make it harder for their technology to be expropriated. And it may ultimately lead to companies withdrawing from a country altogether. Perhaps a country would be content to have a generic-only drug market, but even that will lead to, effectively, the developed world underwriting healthcare everywhere else. This is not a sustainable model. Darren Smyth is a partner and patent attorney at EIP Caio Rodrigues da Silva and Leonor Galvão To date, compulsory licences have only been declared by the health ministry in Brazil on the basis of public interest. The Brazilian government has previously used this argument to negotiate price reductions with antiretroviral manufacturers: in 2001, Roche accepted a price reduction of 40% for nelfinavir and in 2005 a price reduction was negotiated with Abbott for the combination lopinavir and ritonavir. In 2007, however, after refusing a 30% price reduction for the HIV antiretroviral efavirenz, manufactured by Merck & Co, the health ministry declared public interest in the drug and granted a compulsory licence. The main argument was cost given the large patient population (42% of the total) being treated with efavirenz, acquiring generic versions would save approximately $235 million ( 154 million) over five years. The perception of Brazil will not be the same, the president of Merck & Co s Latin American division said at the time, adding that the company was reviewing its investment plan in Brazil. A Merck & Co spokesperson also said this was a chilling signal... about the attractiveness of undertaking risky research on diseases that affect the developing world. The most controversial issue in this discussion is the concept of public interest: how it is ascertained and defined. A detailed and transparent explanation of the circumstances motivating public interest is essential. Unfortunately, the compulsory licence of efavirenz patents did not even make reference to the ordinance of the health ministry, which officiated the public interest on efavirenz. This omission renders the legality of the decision questionable, since it is impossible to evaluate the real presence of public interest and the necessity of a compulsory licence. Worldwide, compulsory licence rulings bring controversy, even when foreseen in international trades and supported by laws. This is especially true when the terms and conditions are not consistently defined, leaving room for interpretations that dangerously affect legal and institutional security, and which may favour arbitrary decisions.

Page 5 of 5 Merck & Co s intellectual property was seized and it was not given the right to contest the decision. This brings uncertainty for research-based companies and jeopardises how Brazilian intellectual property and pharma investment are seen worldwide. Since then, the Brazilian government has not exercised or discussed any compulsory licences and it appears that it will refrain from doing so in the future. The indirect damages to the country s economy that have resulted far surpass the benefits of buying efavirenz at a reduced price. Caio Rodrigues da Silva is an associate and Leonor Galvão is managing partner of the patent practice at Murta Goyanes