Market Equilibrium in a NonCAPM World. Harry Markowitz. The Q-Group October 16, 2006

Similar documents
Market Efficiency: A Theoretical Distinction and So What? Harry M. Markowitz

Solution: The optimal position for an investor with a coefficient of risk aversion A = 5 in the risky asset is y*:

Review for Exam 2. Instructions: Please read carefully

Review for Exam 2. Instructions: Please read carefully

The CAPM (Capital Asset Pricing Model) NPV Dependent on Discount Rate Schedule

SAMPLE MID-TERM QUESTIONS

AFM 472. Midterm Examination. Monday Oct. 24, A. Huang

The Tangent or Efficient Portfolio

Chapter 2 Portfolio Management and the Capital Asset Pricing Model

ECON4510 Finance Theory Lecture 7

CFA Examination PORTFOLIO MANAGEMENT Page 1 of 6

On the Efficiency of Competitive Stock Markets Where Traders Have Diverse Information

Chapter 1. Introduction to Portfolio Theory. 1.1 Portfolios of Two Risky Assets

Portfolio Performance Measures

Lecture 6: Arbitrage Pricing Theory

CAPM, Arbitrage, and Linear Factor Models

The Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM)

Chapter 13 Composition of the Market Portfolio 1. Capital markets in Flatland exhibit trade in four securities, the stocks X, Y and Z,

Lecture 15: Final Topics on CAPM

ENTREPRENEURIAL FINANCE: Strategy Valuation and Deal Structure

Chap 3 CAPM, Arbitrage, and Linear Factor Models

1 Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM)

Lecture 1: Asset Allocation

Investments. Assignment 1: Securities, Markets & Capital Market Theory. Each question is worth 0.2 points, the max points is 3 points

Chapter 5 Risk and Return ANSWERS TO SELECTED END-OF-CHAPTER QUESTIONS

WEB APPENDIX. Calculating Beta Coefficients. b Beta Rise Run Y X

Chapter 11. Topics Covered. Chapter 11 Objectives. Risk, Return, and Capital Budgeting

Chapter 11. Topics Covered. Chapter 11 Objectives. Risk, Return, and Capital Budgeting

CHAPTER 11: ARBITRAGE PRICING THEORY

Models of Risk and Return

CHAPTER 7: OPTIMAL RISKY PORTFOLIOS

Wel Dlp Portfolio And Risk Management

Lecture 5: Put - Call Parity

Enhancing the Teaching of Statistics: Portfolio Theory, an Application of Statistics in Finance

Example 1. Consider the following two portfolios: 2. Buy one c(s(t), 20, τ, r) and sell one c(s(t), 10, τ, r).

FINANCIAL ECONOMICS OPTION PRICING

Overview of Violations of the Basic Assumptions in the Classical Normal Linear Regression Model

Lecture 4: Properties of stock options

Black-Litterman Return Forecasts in. Tom Idzorek and Jill Adrogue Zephyr Associates, Inc. September 9, 2003

11. OVERVIEW OF THE INVESTMENT PORTFOLIO SOFTWARE

FIN 432 Investment Analysis and Management Review Notes for Midterm Exam

The Capital Asset Pricing Model

1. a. (iv) b. (ii) [6.75/(1.34) = 10.2] c. (i) Writing a call entails unlimited potential losses as the stock price rises.

ENTREPRENEURIAL FINANCE: Strategy, Valuation, and Deal Structure

CAPITAL ASSET PRICES WITH AND WITHOUT NEGATIVE HOLDINGS

Financial Risk Management Exam Sample Questions/Answers

2. Exercising the option - buying or selling asset by using option. 3. Strike (or exercise) price - price at which asset may be bought or sold

ATHENS UNIVERSITY OF ECONOMICS AND BUSINESS

ON THE RISK ADJUSTED DISCOUNT RATE FOR DETERMINING LIFE OFFICE APPRAISAL VALUES BY M. SHERRIS B.A., M.B.A., F.I.A., F.I.A.A. 1.

Investment Philosophies: Introduction

Chapter 7 Risk, Return, and the Capital Asset Pricing Model

CHARACTERISTICS OF INVESTMENT PORTFOLIOS PASSIVE MANAGEMENT STRATEGY ON THE CAPITAL MARKET

Practice Set #4 and Solutions.

Tax Cognizant Portfolio Analysis: A Methodology for Maximizing After Tax Wealth

FOUNDATIONS OF PORTFOLIO THEORY

Combining decision analysis and portfolio management to improve project selection in the exploration and production firm

Module 3: Correlation and Covariance

LESSON 28: CAPITAL ASSET PRICING MODEL (CAPM)

Asset Management Contracts and Equilibrium Prices

CHAPTER 10 RISK AND RETURN: THE CAPITAL ASSET PRICING MODEL (CAPM)

Lecture 3: CAPM in practice

An introduction to Value-at-Risk Learning Curve September 2003

I.e., the return per dollar from investing in the shares from time 0 to time 1,

A Simple Utility Approach to Private Equity Sales

Computer Handholders Investment Software Research Paper Series TAILORING ASSET ALLOCATION TO THE INDIVIDUAL INVESTOR

Finance Theory

1 Portfolio mean and variance

Black Scholes Merton Approach To Modelling Financial Derivatives Prices Tomas Sinkariovas Words: 3441

inefficiency of stock portfolios The efficient market capitalization-weighted Matching the market is an inefficient investment strategy.

Sensitivity Analysis 3.1 AN EXAMPLE FOR ANALYSIS

Problem Set 6 - Solutions

t = Calculate the implied interest rates and graph the term structure of interest rates. t = X t = t = 1 2 3

Lecture 8: Stock market reaction to accounting data

M.I.T. Spring 1999 Sloan School of Management First Half Summary

Linear Programming. March 14, 2014

ANALYSIS AND MANAGEMENT

Monika Goel Online Classes FINANCIAL, TREASURY AND FOREX MANAGEMENT Module II (C.S Professional Course)

Using Microsoft Excel to build Efficient Frontiers via the Mean Variance Optimization Method

Chapter 9. The Valuation of Common Stock. 1.The Expected Return (Copied from Unit02, slide 36)

Lecture 05: Mean-Variance Analysis & Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM)

MBA 8230 Corporation Finance (Part II) Practice Final Exam #2

Lecture Notes: Basic Concepts in Option Pricing - The Black and Scholes Model

Optimal Risky Portfolios Chapter 7 Investments Bodie, Kane and Marcus

Chapter 2 Supply Chain Performance: Achieving Strategic Fit and Scope (24)

Simple linear regression

Instructor s Manual Chapter 12 Page 144

Short Sale. Dr. Patrick Toche

Asymmetry and the Cost of Capital

Benchmarking Low-Volatility Strategies

Univariate Regression

Chapter 6 The Tradeoff Between Risk and Return

Chicago Booth BUSINESS STATISTICS Final Exam Fall 2011

Chapter 5. Conditional CAPM. 5.1 Conditional CAPM: Theory Risk According to the CAPM. The CAPM is not a perfect model of expected returns.

Interest in foreign investment has been high among U.S. investors in

Chapter 11, Risk and Return

Caput Derivatives: October 30, 2003

Review Jeopardy. Blue vs. Orange. Review Jeopardy

ECONOMIA DEGLI INTERMEDIARI FINANZIARI AVANZATA II MODULO ASSET MANAGEMENT LECTURE 3

Trading to hedge: Static hedging

Transcription:

Market Equilibrium in a NonCAPM World Harry Markowitz The Q-Group October 16, 2006 1

See Market Efficiency: A Theoretical Distinction and So What? Financial Analyst Journal 2005 Vol. 61, No. 5 pp. 17-30 Financial Market Simulation Journal of Portfolio Management 30 th Anniversary Issue September 2004, pp 142-152 Bruce Jacobs, Ken Levy, and Harry Markowitz 2

CAPM is an elegant theory. With the aid of some simplifying assumptions it reaches dramatic conclusions about practical matters. 3

For example How to choose an investment portfolio? Just buy the market. How to forecast expected returns? Just forecast betas. How to price a new security? (see above) 4

CAPM s simplifying assumptions make it easier to deduce properties of market equilibria. Like computing trajectories assuming there is no air. But before betting the ranch that the feather and the brick will hit the ground at the same time, it is best to consider the implications of some of the omitted complexities. 5

This lecture (1) Mostly explores the implications of generalizing one of the CAPM s simplifying assumptions. (2) Briefly describes a program for computing market equilibria for complex market models. 6

Distinguish between the statement the market is efficient, in the sense that market participants have accurate information and use it correctly to their benefit, and the statement the market portfolio is a mean-variance efficient portfolio. Under some assumptions the two statements are equivalent: 7

Specifically, if we assume A1. Transaction costs and other illiquidities can be ignored A2. All investors hold mean-variance efficient portfolios A3. All investors hold the same (correct) beliefs about means variances, and covariances of securities, and--in addition-- A4. Every investor can lend all she or he has or can borrow all she or he wants at the risk-free rate 8

Then Conclusion 1 follows: C1. The market portfolio is a mean-variance efficient portfolio C1 also follows if A4 is replaced by A4 A4. Investors can sell short without limit and use the proceeds of the sale to buy long positions For example, A4 says that any investor can deposit $1,000 with a broker, short $1,000,000 worth of one security, and buy long $1,001,000 worth of another security. 9

In addition to C1, A1 through A4 (or A1 through A4 ) imply C2. In equilibrium, the expected return for each security depends only on its beta (the regression of its returns against the return on the market). This relationship between the security s expected return and its beta is a simple linear relationship. C2 is the basis for the CAPM s prescriptions for risk adjustment and asset valuation. C1 and C2 do not follow from assumptions A1 through A3 if A4 (or A4 ) is replaced by a more realistic description of the investor s investment constraints. 10

Example, This first example assumes that investors cannot sell short or borrow. Later we note that the same results hold if investors can borrow limited amounts or can sell short but are subject to Reg T or a similar constraint. The example assumes A1 through A3. 11

Table 1 Example Inputs Standard Security Expected Return Deviation 1 0.15% 0.18% 2 0.10% 0.12% 3 0.20% 0.30% The example assumes returns are uncorrelated. Later we note that similar results follow for correlated risks. 12

Assume that the investor can choose any portfolio that meets the following constraints: and X + X + X = 1 2 3 1.0 X 0, X 0, X 0 1 2 3 (1) (2) 13

In Figure 1, X 1 -- the fraction invested in Security 1--is plotted on the horizontal axis; X 2 -- is plotted on the vertical axis; and X 3 -- the fraction invested in the third security--is given implicitly by the relationship X = 1 X X 3 1 2 14

The market portfolio M is not efficient for either the investor with or without nonnegativity constraints (2) 15

Figure 1 shows that if Table 1 were equilibrium beliefs then the market portfolio would not be mean-variance efficient portfolio. But can these be equilibrium beliefs? Consider the following Simple Market: 16

Inhabitants of an island live on coconuts and the produce of their own gardens. The island has three enterprises, namely, three coconut farms. Once a year, a market convenes to trade the shares of the three farms. Each year, the resulting prices of shares turn out to be the same as those of preceding years. Thus, the only source of uncertainty of return is the dividend each stock pays during the year--which is the stock s pro rata share of the farm s production. 17

It is shown in Appendix of the paper that means, variances and covariances of coconut production exist that imply the efficient set in Figure 1-- or any other three-security efficient set that we cite. With such a probability distribution of returns, the market is rational, in the sense that each participant knows the true probability distribution of returns and each seeks and achieves mean-variance efficiency. Nevertheless, in contrast to the usual CAPM conclusion, the market portfolio is not an efficient portfolio. It also follows that there is no representative investor. 18

Arbitrage? Suppose that most investors are subject to the nonnegativity requirement (2), but one investor can short, in the CAPM sense. (Perhaps the CAPM investor has surreptitious access to a vault containing stock certificates that he or she can borrow temporarily without posting collateral) Would this CAPM investor arbitrage away the inefficiency in the market portfolio? 19

The CAPM-constrained investor should not short the market 20

Thus, unlimited arbitrage has limited power to bring the market towards an efficient portfolio 21

Expected Returns and Betas. If Assumptions 1-4 or 1-4 are true, then Conclusion 2 follows: Expected returns are linearly related to the betas of each security. E 1 = a + bβ 1 E 2 = a + bβ 2 E 3 = a + bβ 3 where β i is the coefficient of regression of the return on the ith security against the return on the market. These equations do not necessarily hold if A1-A3 are true but neither A4 nor A4 is true. 22

Table 2 Betas vs. P Security Percent in P cov i,p = P i V i beta i,p 1 0.70% 0.0227 0.52 2-0.25-0.0036-0.08 3 0.55 0.0495 1.12 Note: var(p) = 0.0440; Beta i,p = cov i,p / var / P) Table 3 Betas vs. M Security Percent in M cov i,m = M i V i beta i,m 1 0.30 0.0097 0.36 2 0.19 0.0027 0.10 3 0.51 0.0459 1.71 Note: var(m) = 0.0268; beta i,m = cov i,m /var(m) 23

24

Suppose limited borrowing, e.g. 100% Table 4 Example Inputs Including Cash Expected Standard Security Return Deviation 1 0.15% 0.18% 2 0.10% 0.12% 3 0.03% 0.00% 25

Again, the market portfolio M is not mean-variance efficient. 26

Generalizations Suppose that there are n securities (for n = 3 or 30 or 3,000), not all expected returns are the same, and the n securities have a nonsingular covariance matrix. If the only constraint on the choice of portfolio is i= 1 = 1 then the portfolios that minimize portfolio variance V P for various values of portfolio expected return E P lie on a single straight line in (n-1)-dimensional portfolio space. n X i 27

Next, consider an investor subject to a no-shorting constraint X i 0, = 1,, n The critical line algorithm (CLA) begins with the portfolio that is 100 percent invested in the security with highest expected return. It traces out the set of efficient portfolios in a series of iterations. Each iteration computes one piece (one linear segment) of the piecewise linear efficient set. Each successive segment has either one more or one less security than the preceding segment. 28

If the analysis includes a risk-free asset (or, equivalently, risk-free lending), the last segment to be computed (the one with the lowest portfolio mean and variance) is the one and only segment that contains the risk free asset (Tobin 1958) 29

If the universe consists of, say 10,000 securities, and if all securities are to be demanded by someone, then this universal efficient frontier must contain at least 10,000 segments. If investors have sufficiently diverse risk tolerances, they will choose portfolios on different segments. The market portfolio is a weighted average of individual portfolios and typically is not on any efficient segment. 30

This characterization of efficient sets remains true if limited borrowing is allowed, as illustrated in Figure 5. It also remains true when short selling is permitted but is subject to a Reg T or similar constraint (see Jacobs, Levy, Markowitz 2005) n i= 1 X + X X = 1, i 2n+ 1 2n+ 2 2n i= 1 i + X = 2 2n+ 3 and X 0, with i= 1,..., 2n+ 3 i X Portfolio with maximum expected return typically contains two variables at positive levels. 31

As before, CLA traces out the efficient frontier in a series of iterations--each iteration producing one piece of the piecewise linear efficient set, each piece having one more or (occasionally) one less nonzero variable than did the preceding piece. If there are 10,000 securities each demanded by someone, the efficient set has at least 10,000 linear segments. Typically the market portfolio is on none of these. 32

Thus, again, typically The market portfolio is not mean-variance efficient. There is not a linear relationship between expected returns and betas. There is no representative investor 33

Results presented so far have been negative: What s not true in a NonCAPM world. Now, something somewhat more positive: How to compute equilibrium prices in some noncapm worlds Answer: Use JLMSim with its (new) CME (Capital Market Equilibrium) modus operandi as opposed to its original DA (Dynamic Analysis) modus operandi. 34

For example, Black-Litterman find expected returns which imply given market weights assuming CAPM (and adjust these according to the users views or prior ). Problem: CAPM does not have the same equilibrium expected returns as models with real-world constraints. 35

If CAPM expected returns are assumed for a population of investors subject to real-world short and borrowing constraints then typically Their demands for various securities will not add up to the market portfolio. The risky assets of cautious investors, who hold cash, will equal the market portfolio. When the holdings of less cautious are added, the totals will not add up to the target weights: 36

37

Originally, JLMSim was developed as an asynchronous simulator to help think through dynamic consequences of more complex models. All investors in current JLMSim seek mean-variance efficiency. For a particular simulation run, the JLMSim user specifies: How many securities How many investor templates For each investor template: How many investors are to be created from this template How frequently do they reoptimize What k used in maximizing E-kv. What probability distribution of initial wealth Random deposits and withdrawals 38

How many trader templates What rules do traders of this template use to Set initial bid and asked prices Modify bids and offers, or cancel orders, if order not completed in a timely manner How many statisticians What rules do they use to estimate means, variances and covariances Etc. 39

Now, equilibrium expected returns can be computed for markets with real-world constraints by using JLMSim in its CME (Capital Market Equilibrium) rather than its DA (Dynamic Analysis) mode of operation. With the CME modus operandi the statistician estimates expected return by increasing estimates for securities under target weights, decreasing them for securities over target weights. The system converges fairly rapidly: 40

Max, Min and Avg IntraMonth Deviation From Target Weights for Sec 0 For Case with 8 "Securities," and Investors with Diverse Risk Aversions 0.0500 0.0400 0.0300 Deviation 0.0200 0.0100 0.0000 1 3 5 7 9 11 13 15 17 19 21 23 25 27 29 31 33 35 37 39 41 43 45 47 49 51 53 55 57 59 61 63 65 67 69 71 73 75-0.0100-0.0200 Month 41

In sum, If investors cannot borrow all they want at the risk-free rate or short without limit and use the proceeds to buy long positions Then The market portfolio is not necessarily efficient; Expected returns are not a linear function of betas; There is no representative investor. But One can calculate equilibrium expected returns 42