THE LONG-TERM EFFECTS OF HEDGE FUND ACTIVISM



Similar documents
COLUMBIA LAW REVIEW VOL. 115 JUNE 2015 NO. 5 ARTICLES THE LONG-TERM EFFECTS OF HEDGE FUND ACTIVISM. Lucian A. Bebchuk,* Alon Brav,** and Wei Jiang***

DOES THE COMPOSITION OF A COMPANY S SHAREHOLDER BASE REALLY MATTER? By Anne Beyer, David F. Larcker, and Brian Tayan July 31, 2014

The Determinants and the Value of Cash Holdings: Evidence. from French firms

Activist Hedge Funds. Materials from chapter 13 (ST), covering: 1) How does the strategy work? 2) Equity swap 3) Fund performance

The Changing Landscape of Executive Compensation after Dodd-Frank

How Has CEO Turnover Changed?

MARKET REACTION TO ACQUISITION ANNOUNCEMENTS AFTER THE 2008 STOCK MARKET CRASH

Corporate Governance and Shareholder Activism

What drives firms to be more diversified?

Private Equity Newsletter

Institutional Trading, Brokerage Commissions, and Information Production around Stock Splits

The Returns to Hedge Fund Activism

Form of the government and Investment Sensitivity to Stock Price

The Pros and Cons of Corporate Governance Funds in Emerging Markets

on share price performance

Research Debate Regulatory competition and board insulation: Lessons the UK should not learn from the US

WRDS Overview on Corporate Governance Data. Rabih Moussawi

Trade on the news? Information Trading"

Executive Equity Ownership

Journal of Financial and Strategic Decisions Volume 13 Number 2 Summer 2000

Investment Portfolio Philosophy

Market Efficiency: Definitions and Tests. Aswath Damodaran

Top Hedge Funds: The Importance of Reputation in Shareholder Activism

Valuation Effects of Debt and Equity Offerings. by Real Estate Investment Trusts (REITs)

3. LITERATURE REVIEW

Journal Of Financial And Strategic Decisions Volume 9 Number 3 Fall 1996 STOCK PRICES AND THE BARRON S RESEARCH REPORTS COLUMN

Department of Accounting and Finance

Entrepreneurial Shareholder Activism: Hedge Funds and Other Private Investors

Journal Of Financial And Strategic Decisions Volume 8 Number 1 Spring 1995

The Series of Discussion Papers. Conceptual Framework of Financial Accounting

Hedge Fund Activism, Corporate Governance, and Firm Performance

Capital Structure and Ownership Structure: A Review of Literature

Session Title: Trade and the Internal Organization of Firms. Paper Title: Trading favors within Chinese business groups. Discussant: Kathryn Shaw

Autoria: Eduardo Kazuo Kayo, Douglas Dias Bastos

Estimating Private Benefits of Control from Stock Price Changes Around the Announcement of Tender Offer Bid (TOB)

MN5311 RESPONSIBLE INVESTMENT

Stock Market -Trading and market participants

Recent Decisions Show Courts Closely Scrutinizing Fee Awards in M&A Litigation Settlements

Acquisitions as a Means of Restructuring Firms in Chapter 11*

D&O Insurance and SEO Performance: Does Managerial Opportunism Always Hold? Abstract

Hedge Fund Intervention and Accounting Conservatism

SEC PROPOSES PAY VERSUS PERFORMANCE RULES

Hedge Fund Activism, Corporate Governance, and Firm Performance

Corporate Governance and Shareholder Engagement

Research Objectivity Standards

Concentrated Equity Triple Play Higher Returns, Lower Risk, Lower Correlations By C. Thomas Howard, Ph.D. March 13, 2012

UNDERSTANDING THE COST ASSOCIATED WITH DATA SECURITY BREACHES

SEC Delivers Report on Mark-to-Market Accounting Recommends Against Suspension of Fair Value Accounting

for Analysing Listed Private Equity Companies

Evidence on the Contracting Explanation of Conservatism

THE ROLE DIVIDENDS CAN PLAY IN INTERNATIONAL EQUITY INVESTING

Managed funds. Plain Talk Library

I. Introduction I.1. Preface

The Perceived Earnings Quality Consequences of Announcements to Voluntarily Adopt the Fair Value Method of Accounting for Stock-Based Compensation

Business Cycle, Corporate Governance and Bank Performance

Australian Share Fund Class A Units

IPO Waves: An Empirical Analysis of Going-public Decisions in the Netherlands,

SECURITIES TRADING AND INVESTMENT POLICY

Corporate Governance and Operating Performance of Chinese Listed Firms

Investor Performance in ASX shares; contrasting individual investors to foreign and domestic. institutions. 1

THE EFFECT ON RIVALS WHEN FIRMS EMERGE FROM BANKRUPTCY

Asian Economic and Financial Review THE CAPITAL INVESTMENT INCREASES AND STOCK RETURNS

Executive compensation in companies with

PROXY VOTING PROCEDURES AND PRINCIPLES

Graduate Business Programs SDSU College of Business Administration. MBA Program of Study Worksheet. Finance Specialization

Re: File No. S

Hedge Fund Activism, Corporate Governance, and Firm Performance

ETF Total Cost Analysis in Action

Agency Costs of Free Cash Flow and Takeover Attempts

Economics of Bankruptcy Volume I

EMPIRICAL ANALYSES OF THE DOGS OF THE DOW STRATEGY: JAPANESE EVIDENCE. Received July 2012; revised February 2013

A Survey of Blockholders and Corporate Control

Life-Cycle Theory and Free Cash Flow Hypothesis: Evidence from. Dividend Policy in Thailand

Small/Mid-Cap Quality Strategy (including FPA Paramount Fund, Inc. and FPA Perennial Fund, Inc.)

Stock Prices and Business Investment

THIRTY YEARS OF CORPORATE GOVERNANCE: DETERMINANTS & EQUITY PRICES

Lecture 8: Stock market reaction to accounting data

Governance of public corporations continues to move in

FORM ADV PART 2A Brochure

A Piece of the Pie: Alternative Approaches to Allocating Value

DISCLOSURE OF CONTRACTS FOR DIFFERENCES

FIN 500R Exam Answers. By nature of the exam, almost none of the answers are unique. In a few places, I give examples of alternative correct answers.

Report of Investigation Pursuant to Section 21(a) of the Securities Exchange Act of 1934: Netflix, Inc., and Reed Hastings

JPMORGAN CHASE & CO FORM FWP. (Free Writing Prospectus - Filing under Securities Act Rules 163/433) Filed 07/16/14

Synthetic Financing by Prime Brokers

Hedge Fund Activism in Europe

FINANCIAL REPORTING STANDARDS FRS 9

Earnings Announcement and Abnormal Return of S&P 500 Companies. Luke Qiu Washington University in St. Louis Economics Department Honors Thesis

A Study of information asymmetry using Bid-Ask spread on firm value: evidence from Tehran Stock Exchange

Does a Parent-Subsidiary Structure Enhance Financing Flexibility?

Busy Directors and the Performance of Swedish Companies

High Yield Bonds A Primer

Your rights will expire on October 30, 2015 unless extended.

The Stock Market s Reaction to Accounting Information: The Case of the Latin American Integrated Market. Abstract

Chapter 1 The Scope of Corporate Finance

Debtor-in-Possession Financing. Sris Chatterjee * Upinder S. Dhillon ** Gabriel G. Ramírez *** Forthcoming Journal of Banking and Finance, 2005

Economia Aziendale online 2000 Web International Business and Management Review

Preparing For Goodwill Impairments

Transcription:

THE LONG-TERM EFFECTS OF HEDGE FUND ACTIVISM Lucian A. Bebchuk, Alon Brav, and Wei Jiang William J. Friedman and Alicia Townshend Friedman Professor of Law, Economics and Finance and Director of the Program on Corporate Governance, Harvard Law School; Professor of Finance, Fuqua School of Business, Duke University and NBER; Arthur F. Burns Professor of Free and Competitive Enterprise, Columbia Business School. We wish to thank Kobi Kastiel, Song Ma, Bryan Oh and Heqing Zhu for their invaluable research assistance.

Abstract We test the empirical validity of a claim that has been playing a central role in debates on corporate governance the claim that interventions by activist shareholders, and in particular activist hedge funds, have an adverse effect on the long-term interests of companies and their shareholders. While this myopic activists claim has been regularly invoked and has had considerable influence, its supporters have thus far failed to back it up with evidence. This paper presents a comprehensive empirical investigation of this claim and finds that it is not supported by the data. We study the universe of about 2,000 interventions by activist hedge funds during the period 1994-2007, examining a long time window of five years following the intervention. We find no evidence that interventions are followed by declines in operating performance in the long term; to the contrary, activist intervention are followed by improved operating performance during the five-year period following the intervention. These improvements in long-term performance, we find, are present also when focusing on the two subsets of activist interventions that are most resisted and criticized first, interventions that lower or constrain long-term investments by enhancing leverage, beefing up shareholder payouts, or reducing investments and, second, adversarial interventions employing hostile tactics. We also find no evidence that the initial positive stock price spike accompanying activist interventions fails to appreciate their long-term costs and therefore tends to be followed by negative abnormal returns in the long term; the data is consistent with the initial spike reflecting correctly the intervention s long-term consequences. Similarly, we find no evidence for pumpand-dump patterns in which the exit of an activist is followed by abnormal long-term negative returns. Finally, we find no evidence for concerns that activist interventions during the years preceding the financial crisis rendered companies more vulnerable and that the targeted companies therefore were more adversely affected by the crisis. Our findings that the considered claims and concerns are not supported by the data have significant implications for ongoing policy debates on corporate governance, corporate law, and capital markets regulation. Policymakers and institutional investors should not accept the validity of the frequent assertions that activist interventions are costly to firms and their long-term shareholders in the long term; they should reject the use of such claims as a basis for limiting the rights and involvement of shareholders. Keywords: Corporate governance, short-termism, managerial myopia, long-term value, investor horizons, market efficiency, shareholder activism, hedge fund activism, shareholder rights, takeovers, proxy fights, takeover defenses, hedge funds,. JEL Classification: D21, G12, G23, G32, G34, G35, G38, K22

Table of Contents I. Introduction... 1 II. The Universe of Hedge Fund Activism... 5 III. operating performance... 7 A. Measures of performance... 7 B. Operating Performance Following Activist Interventions... 8 C. Regression Analysis... 11 D. Summary... 13 1. A Clear Pattern... 13 2. Causality vs. Stock Picking... 13 IV. Stock Returns... 15 A. Short-Term Returns... 15 B. Subsequent Reversal?... 17 1. Individual Firm Regressions... 18 2. Buy and Hold Abnormal Returns... 19 3. Portfolio Analysis... 20 4. Summary... 22 C. Pump and Dump?... 23 1. The Question... 23 2. Individual Firm Regressions... 24 3. Buy and Hold Results... 25 4. Portfolio Analysis... 25 D. Summary... 26 V. Activist Interventions that are Especially Resisted... 27 A. Leverage-Enhancing, Payout-Increasing, and Investment-Reducing Interventions... 27 B. Adversarial Interventions... 31 VI. Increased Vulnerability to Economic Shocks?... 34 A. Operating Performance during the Crisis... 34 B. Financial Distress and Delisting during the Crisis... 35 VII. Conclusion... 37

The Long-term Effects of Activism I. INTRODUCTION This paper focuses on a claim that has been playing a central role in debates over shareholder activism and corporate governance. According to this myopic activists claim, activist shareholders with short investment horizon, especially activist hedge funds, push for actions that are profitable in the short term but are detrimental to the long term interests of companies and their long-term shareholders. The problem, it is claimed, results from the failure of short-term market prices to reflect the long term costs of actions sought by short-term activists. As a result, activists seeking a short term spike in a company s stock price have an incentive to seek actions that would increase short-term prices at the expense of long-term performance, such as cutting excessively investments in long-term projects or the reserve funds available for such investments. In this paper, we conduct a systematic empirical investigation of the myopic activists claim, focusing on interventions by activist hedge funds. Such funds have been playing an increasingly central role in the corporate governance landscape in general and shareholder activism in particular. 1 We find that the myopic activists claim is not supported by the data. Our findings have important policy implications for ongoing policy debates on corporate governance and the rights and role of shareholders. The myopic activists claim has far been put forward by a wide range of prominent writers. Such concerns have been expressed by significant legal academics, 2 noted economists and business school professors, 3 prominent business columnists, 4 important business organizations, 5 and top corporate lawyers. 6 Furthermore, those claims have been successful in influencing important public officials and policy makers. For example, Chancellor Leo Strine and Justice Jack Jacobs, two prominent 1 See, e.g., Marcel Kahan and Edward B. Rock, Hedge Funds in Corporate Governance and Corporate Control, 155(5) U. PA. L. REV. 1021 (2007). 2 See, e.g., William W. Bratton and Michael L. Wachter, The Case Against Shareholder Empowerment, 158 U. PA. L. REV. 653 54 (2010). 3 See, e.g., THE KAY REVIEW OF UK EQUITY MARKETS AND LONG-TERM DECISION MAKING, FINAL REPORT, 9 (2012); Justin Fox and Jay W. Lorsch, The Big Idea-What Good Are Shareholders?, 48 HARV. BUS. REV. 50, 51 (2012). 4 See, e.g., Joe Nocera, What is Business Waiting For?, N.Y. TIMES, August 16, 2011; Andrew Sorkin, Shareholder Democracy Can Mask Abuses, N.Y. TIMES, February 25, 2013. 5 See, e.g., The Aspen Institute, Overcoming Short-Termism: A Call for a More Responsible Approach to Investment and Business Management, at 2 3 (2009), available at http://www.aspeninstitute.org/sites/default/files/content/docs/business%20and%20society%20program/ov ercome_short_state0909.pdf. 6 See, e.g., Martin Lipton and Steven A. Rosenblum, A New System of Corporate Governance: The Quinquennial Election of Directors, 58 U. CHI. L. REV. 187 88, 203, 210 12 (1991). 1

Delaware judges, have expressed strong concerns about short-sighted activism. 7 When serving as SEC chairman, William Donaldson expressed concerns about such activism. 8 And concerns about intervention by activists with short horizons persuaded the SEC to limit use of the proxy rule adopted in 2010 to shareholders that have held their shares for more than three years. 9 The policy stakes are substantial. Invoking the long-term costs of activism has become a standard move in arguments for limiting the role, rights, and involvement of shareholder activists. In particular, such arguments have been used to support, for example, takeover defenses, impediments to shareholders ability to replace directors, limitations on the rights of shareholders with short holding periods. As one of us analyzes in detail in other work, the claim that activist interventions are detrimental to the long-term interests of shareholders and companies cannot be derived from theory even assuming the existence of inefficient capital markets and short activist horizons. 10 The claim is a factual proposition that can be empirically tested. However, those advancing the myopic activists claim have thus far failed to back their claims with any large sample empirical evidence. Some supporters of the claim seem to assume the validity of their claim, failing to acknowledge the empirically contestable nature of their claim and the need for evidence, while other supporters of the claim have offered their experience as evidence. 11 At the same time, financial economists have produced significant empirical work on hedge fund activism. 12 There is evidence that the filing of 13D schedules public disclosures of the purchase of a significant stake by an activist are accompanied by significant positive stock price reactions as well as subsequent improvements in operating performance. However, 7 See Leo E. Strine, Jr., One Fundamental Corporate Governance Question We Face: Can Corporations Be Managed for the Long Term Unless Their Powerful Electorates Also Act and Think Long Term?, 66 BUS. LAW. 1, 26 (2010); Jack B. Jacobs, Patient Capital : Can Delaware Corporate Law Help Revive It?, 68 WASH. & LEE L. REV. 1645, 1649, 1657 63 (2011). 8 See CFA Center for Finance Integrity & Business Roundtable Institute for Corporate Ethics, Breaking the Short-Term Cycle: Discussion and Recommendations on How Corporate Leaders, Asset Managers, Investors and Analysts Can Refocus on Long-Term Value, at 1, 3 (2006), available at http://www.darden.virginia.edu/corporate-ethics/pdf/short-termism_report.pdf. (statement of William Donaldson); 9 See Facilitating Shareholder Director Nominations, Exchange Act Release Nos. 33-9136; 34-62764; IC- 29384, 75 Fed. Reg. 56,668, 106 7 (Aug. 25, 2010). 10 See Lucian A. Bebchuk, The Myth that Insulating Boards Serves Long-Term Value, 113 COLUM. L. Rev. (forthcoming) (2013). 11 See Wachtell, Lipton, Rosen & Katz Memorandum, Bite the Apple; Poison the Apple; Paralyze the Company; Wreck the Economy, REPROD. THE HARVARD LAW SCHOOL FORUM ON CORPORATE GOVERNANCE AND FINANCIAL REGULATION (Feb. 26, 2013) (Martin Lipton stating that his belief in the long-term costs imposes by activist campaigns is grounded in the decades of experience that he and his colleagues have accumulated while advising companies). 12 For a review of this literature, see Alon Brav, Wei Jiang and Hyunseob Kim, Hedge Fund Activism: A Review, 4(3) FOUNDATIONS AND TRENDS IN FINANCE 185 (2009). 2

supporters of the myopic activist claims dismiss this evidence, taking the view that losses to shareholders and companies from activist interventions take place later on. On their view, improved performance following activist interventions comes at the expense of sacrificing performance later on, and short-term positive stock reactions merely reflect inefficient market prices that are moved by the short-term changes and fail to reflect their long-term costs. Thus, one prominent supporter of the myopic activism claim has recently argued that the important question is [f]or companies that are the subject of hedge fund activism and remain independent, what is the impact on their operational performance and stock price performance relative to the benchmark, not just in the short period after announcement of the activist interest, but after a 24-month period. 13 Data about companies operating performance and stock returns years following activist intervention is publicly available and easily accessible. Nonetheless, supporters of the myopic activists view have failed to back their view with empirical evidence or even to test empirically the validity of their view. In this paper, we seek to fill this void by providing the first comprehensive empirical investigation of the myopic activists claim. We find no support for this claim in the data. Our study uses a dataset consisting of the full universe of approximately 2,000 interventions by activist hedge funds during the period 1994 2007. We identify for each activist effort the month (the intervention month) in which the activist initiative was first publicly disclosed (usually through the filing of a Schedule 13D). Using the data on operating performance and stock returns of public companies during the period 1991-2012, we track the operating performance and stock returns for companies during a long period five years following the intervention month. We also examine the three-year period that precedes activist interventions and that follows activists departure. Starting with operating performance, we find that operating performance improves following activist interventions and there is no evidence that the improved performance comes at the expense of performance later on. During the third, fourth, and fifth year following the start of an activist intervention, operating performance tends to be better, not worse, than during the preintervention period. Thus, during the long, five-year time window that we examine, the declines in operating performance asserted by supporters of the myopic activism claim is not found in the data. We also find that activists tend to target companies that are underperforming relative to industry peers at the time of the intervention, not well-performing ones. We then turn to stock returns following the initial stock price spike that is well-known to accompany activist interventions. We first find that, consistent with the results obtained with respect to pre-intervention operating performance, targets of activists have negative abnormal returns during the three years preceding the intervention. We then proceed to examine whether, as supporters of the myopic activism claim believe, the initial stock price reflects inefficient 13 See Wachtell, Lipton, Rosen & Katz Memorandum, Bite the Apple; Poison the Apple; Paralyze the Company; Wreck the Economy, REPROD. THE HARVARD LAW SCHOOL FORUM ON CORPORATE GOVERNANCE AND FINANCIAL REGULATION (Feb. 26, 2013). 3

market pricing that fails to reflect the long-term costs of the activist intervention and is thus followed by stock return underperformance in the long term. In investigating the presence of negative abnormal returns during this period, we employ three standard methods used by financial economists for detecting stock return underperformance. In particular, the study examines: first, whether the returns to targeted companies were systematically lower than what would be expected given standard asset pricing models; second, whether the returns to targeted companies were lower than those of matched firms that are similar in terms of size and book to market; and, third, whether a portfolio based on taking positions in activism targets and holding them for five years underperforms relative to its risk characteristics. Using each of these methods, we find no evidence of the asserted reversal of fortune during the five-year period following the intervention. The long-term underperformance asserted by supporters of the myopic activism claim, and the resulting losses to long-term shareholders resulting from activist interventions, are not found in the data. We also analyze whether activists cash out their stakes before negative stock returns occur and impose losses on remaining long-term shareholders. Because activist hedge funds have been documented to deliver adequate returns to their own investors, such a pattern is a necessary condition for long-term shareholders being made worse off by activist interventions. We therefore examine whether targets of activist hedge funds experience negative abnormal returns in the three years after an activist discloses that its holdings fell below the 5% threshold that subjects investors to significant disclosure requirements. Again using the three standard methods for detecting the existence of abnormal stock returns, we find no evidence that long-term shareholders experience negative stock returns during the three years following the partial or full cashing out of an activist s stake. We next turn to examine the two subsets of activist interventions that are most resisted and criticized first, interventions that lower or constrain long-term investments by enhancing leverage, beefing up shareholder payouts, or reducing investments and, second, adversarial interventions employing hostile tactics. In both cases, interventions are followed by improvements in operating performance during the five-year period following the intervention, and no evidence is found for the adverse long-term effects asserted by opponents. Finally, we examine whether activist interventions render targeted companies more vulnerable to economic shocks. In particular, we examine whether companies targeted by activist interventions during the years preceding the financial crisis were hit more in the subsequent crisis. We find no evidence that pre-crisis interventions by activists were associated with greater declines in operating performance or higher incidence of financial distress during the crisis. Our findings that the data does not support the claims and empirical predictions of those holding the myopic activism view have significant implications for ongoing policy debates. Going forward, policymakers and institutional investors should not accept the validity of assertions that interventions by hedge funds are followed by long-term adverse consequences for companies and their long-term shareholders. The use of such claims as a basis for limiting shareholder rights and involvement should be rejected. 4

The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. Part II describes our dataset and the universe of 2,000 activist interventions that we study. Part III analyzes operating performance. Part IV analyzes long-term stock returns. Part V focuses on the two subsets of activist interventions that are especially resisted and criticized by critics. Part VI investigates whether activist interventions during the years preceding the financial crisis were followed by increased vulnerability to the subsequent crisis. Part VII concludes. II. THE UNIVERSE OF HEDGE FUND ACTIVISM We build in this paper on the dataset, covering the period from 2001 to 2006, used in the first comprehensive study of hedge-fund activism published by two of us along with Frank Partnoy and Randall Thomas. 14 This dataset was also used by the same authors in subsequent work. 15 Two of us, with Hyunseob Kim, extended the data to include 2007 in a subsequent study, 16 and presented an updated sample covering the period from 1994 through 2007 in a more recent article focusing on the effects of activism on plant productivity and capital reallocation. 17 The three of us, working with Robert Jackson, have recently used this dataset to study predisclosure accumulations of stock by hedge fund activists. 18 Thus, this database has proven fruitful for previous analysis of several issues, and in this paper we extend it to study the longterm effects of hedge fund activism. The dataset includes information drawn from disclosures required to be filed under Section 13(d), which are typically made on the SEC s Schedule 13D. 19 To begin, the dataset was constructed by first identifying all of the investors that filed Schedule 13Ds between 1994 and 2007. Then, based on the names and descriptions of the filers required to be disclosed under Item 2 of Schedule 13D, 20 filer types such as banks, insurance companies, mutual funds, and other non-activist investors were excluded from our sample. In addition, based on the description of 14 Alon Brav, Wei Jiang, Frank Partnoy and Randall Thomas, Hedge Fund Activism, Corporate Governance, and Firm Performance, 63 J. FIN. 1729 (2008). 15 Alon Brav, Wei Jiang, Frank Partnoy and Randall Thomas, The Returns to Hedge Fund Activism, 64 FIN. ANALY. J. 45 (2008). 16 Alon Brav, Wei Jiang & Hyunseob Kim, Hedge Fund Activism: A Review, 4(3) FOUNDATIONS AND TRENDS IN FINANCE 185 (2009). 17 Alon Brav, Wei Jiang & Hyunseob Kim, The Real Effects of Hedge Fund Activism: Productivity, Asset Allocation, and Product Market Concentration (May 23, 2013), available at http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=2022904. 18 Lucian Bebchuk, Alon Brav, Robert Jackson and Wei Jiang, Pre-Disclosure Accumulations by Activist Investors: Evidence and Policy, 39 J. CORP. L. (forthcoming) (2013). 19 See SECURITIES AND EXCHANGE COMMISSION, FORM OF SCHEDULE 13D, 17 C.F.R. 240.13d (2010). 20 See id. at Item 2 (requiring a description of the name[,] principal business[, and] address of [the] principal office of the filer). 5

the purpose of the investment required to be included in Item 4, 21 events where the purpose of the investor is to be involved in a bankruptcy or reorganization due to financial distress, the purpose of the filer is to engage in merger or acquisition-related risk arbitrage, or the security in which the investment is made is not a common share were also excluded. In addition, extensive news searches were conducted using the hedge fund and company names drawn from Schedule 13D. These searches allow for the inclusion in the dataset of additional information not available in the Schedule 13Ds, such as the hedge fund s motive and the target company s response. Due to these searches, the dataset includes instances in which hedge funds maintained an activist position in a large public company but owned less than 5% of the company s stock (and, thus, were not required to file a Schedule 13D). 22 In this paper, we use this dataset to provide the first systematic evidence on the long-term effects of hedge fund activism. To this end, we supplement the dataset of activist filings with data on operating performance and stock returns of the companies targeted by activist interventions. We use standard sources COMPUSTAT for operating performance data and CRSP for stock return data. This enables us to study the long-term effects of activist interventions on both operating performance and shareholder wealth. In particular, we seek to study long-term results during the five years following the activist intervention. We have data on the operating performance and stock returns of public companies through the end of 2012. Thus, because 2007 is the last year for which we have data on interventions, we have data on the stock return and operating performance of public companies during the five years following each of the activist events in our dataset. In the analysis below, we track each company for up to five years and for as long as it remains public within that period. 23 Table 1 below provides summary data on 1,886 Schedule 13D filings by activist hedge funds during the period 1994-2007. As Table 1 shows, there has been an increase in the frequency of activist hedge funds filings over time. Furthermore, the dataset includes a 21 See id. at Item 4 (requiring investors to disclose the [p]urpose of [the t]ransaction, including, inter alia, any plans relating to the acquisition of additional stock or a corporate event such as a merger or acquisition). 22 Because of the significant amount of capital required to own 5% or more of the stock of a large public company, relying exclusively on Schedule 13D filings might exclude cases in which outside investors maintained significant holdings of stock. Thus, our sample includes 42 events in which the activist hedge fund did not file a Schedule 13D because it held less than 5% of the stock of the target company. For further discussion, see Alon Brav, Wei Jiang, Frank Partnoy & Randall Thomas, Hedge Fund Activism, Corporate Governance, and Firm Performance, 63 J. FIN. 1729, 1739 (2008). For a more detailed description of the procedure for assembling the dataset, see Alon Brav, Wei Jiang and Hyunseob Kim, Hedge Fund Activism: A Review, 4(3) FOUNDATIONS AND TRENDS IN FINANCE 185, 193-5 (2009). 23 As is the case for public companies in general, many of the companies that are targets of activist interventions stop being independent public companies over time. In particular, within five years, targets of activist intervention have attrition rates of about 47%, which is similar to the 44% five-year attrition rate of public companies in general. 6

significant number of filings in nearly every year, with more than 100 filings in every year except for four throughout our fourteen-year sample. Furthermore, except for the first two years, 1994 and 1995, the dataset includes more than 80 filings for each year in our study. Year Table 1: Incidence of 13D Filings by Activist Hedge Funds Number of 13D Filings by Hedge Fund Activists Year Number of 13D Filings by Hedge Fund Activists 1994 9 2001 88 1995 31 2002 126 1996 86 2003 117 1997 198 2004 139 1998 152 2005 213 1999 111 2006 248 2000 110 2007 258 Total, 1994-2000 697 Total, 2001-2007 1189 The dataset described in this Section has two features that make it especially useful for the study of our subject. First, it is comprehensive and includes all hedge fund activist interventions during a substantial period of time, thus avoiding the questions that could arise if one were to use a sample or otherwise select a subset of interventions. Second, with nearly 2,000 interventions, the dataset provides us with a large number of observations that facilitates statistical testing. III. OPERATING PERFORMANCE A. Measures of performance We pay special attention to Tobin s Q and ROA which are very commonly used measures in financial economics. Tobin s Q, named after Noble-prize-winner James Tobin, is a measure that reflects the effectiveness with which a company turns a given book value into market value accrued to investors. 24 Tobin s Q, often referred to as Q for simplicity, has been extensively used in studies that seek to measure the efficiency of governance arrangements, ownership structures, or investor protection rules. 25 24 Tobin s Q is measured as the ratio of market value of equity and book value of debt to the book value of equity and book value of debt. 25 See, e.g., Randall Morck, Andrei Shleifer, and Robert Vishny, Management Ownership and Market Valuation: An Empirical Analysis, 20 J. FINANC. ECON. 293 (1988); David Yermack, Higher Market Valuation for Firms with a Small Board of Directors, 40 J. FINANC. ECON. 185 (1996); Robert Daines, Does Delaware Law Improve Firm Value? 62 J. FINANC. ECON.. 559 (2001). 7

ROA refers to return on assets as the ratio of earnings before interest, taxes, depreciation and amortization to the book value of assets. ROA reflects the earning power of a business and thus the effectiveness with which the firm uses assets of a given book value to generate earnings for investors. Like Q, ROA has been significantly used by financial economists as a metric for operating performance. 26 Industries differ significantly in their levels of Q and ROA. For example, old economy firms have lower Q levels, and higher ROA levels, than new economy firms. In examining the quality of a firm s governance or management, it is natural to compare it to its industry peers. Accordingly, it is common to look at a firm s industry-adjusted level of Q or ROA that is, the difference between the firm s level and the industry s mean or median level. A positive level of industry-adjusted Q or ROA indicates that the firm outperforms its industry peers on this dimension, and, conversely, a negative level indicates under-performance. B. Operating Performance Following Activist Interventions We begin by looking at the operating performance of firms that experienced activist intervention at different points in time relative to the time of the intervention. In particular, we examine operating performance in the five-year period following the intervention. Table 2 below reports the levels of Q and ROA at such different points in time. The column labeled t refers to performance in the year of the intervention. Columns labeled t+1, t+2, and so forth represent years after the intervention. We initially report just raw figures that are not adjusted for the industry. For each year, we report the average and the median level of the metric across our sample. 27,28 Table 2: Operating Performance Pre- and Post-Intervention No Industry Adjustment Panel A: ROA t: Event Year t+1 t+2 t+3 t+4 t+5 Average 0.022 0.034 0.038 0.048 0.049 0.046 std. err. 0.006 0.005 0.006 0.006 0.007 0.010 Median 0.069 0.075 0.073 0.083 0.091 0.089 Observations 1584 1363 1187 1055 926 694 Panel B: Q t: Event Year t+1 t+2 t+3 t+4 t+5 Average 2.074 2.010 2.033 2.086 2.128 2.190 std. err. 0.057 0.059 0.066 0.071 0.077 0.092 Median 1.373 1.332 1.316 1.363 1.347 1.412 Observations 1611 1384 1206 1076 942 710 26 See, e.g., Paul Gompers, Joy Ishii, and Andrew Metrick, Corporate Governance and Equity Prices, 118 QUART. J. ECON. 107 (2003); Lucian Bebchuk, Alma Cohen and Charles C.Y. Wang, Learning and the Disappearing Association between Governance and Returns, 108 J. FINANC. ECON. 323 (2013). 27 As is standard, when calculating averages, we pre-winsorize the sample at the 1% and 99% extremes. 28 The number of hedge fund activism observations in table 2 is lower than in Table 1, since some target firms are not covered by COMPUSTAT for certain years. 8

Table 2 indicates that, on average, ROA is higher in each of the five years following the intervention year than in the year of the intervention. Furthermore, we do not see the patterns feared by those advancing the myopic activists claim that is, an initial spike in operating performance followed by a decline to below intervention-year levels. Indeed, while average ROA is higher in each of the two years following the intervention than in the intervention year, it is higher still in each of the subsequent three years. The average ROA is more than double the average ROA in the year of intervention in each of the years t+3, t+4, and t+5. Table 2 also shows that, focusing on average Q as a metric of operating performance, the operating performance at t+3, t+4, and t+5 is better, on average, than at the intervention year. While average Q declines somewhat in the first two years following the intervention year, average Q exceeds its event year level at t+3, t+4, and t+5 and reaches its highest level at t+5. As noted earlier, researchers commonly base their analysis not on raw levels of Q and ROA but rather on industry-adjusted levels. Performance is best assessed in comparison to the company s industry peers. Accordingly, we present in Table 3 below an analysis based on industry-adjusted levels. We identify for each company the firms with the same SIC three-digit industry classification. We define the industry-adjusted level of Q and ROA as equal to the difference between the raw Q or raw ROA level and the industry average Q or ROA. 29,30 Table 3 below presents the evolution of average industry-adjusted ROA and Q over time among the targets of hedge fund activists. As before, we report levels for the intervention year and each of the five years following the intervention year. Table 3: Industry-Adjusted Operating Performance Pre- and Post-Intervention Panel A: Industry-adjusted ROA, with benchmark = industry average t: Event year t+1 t+2 t+3 t+4 t+5 Average -0.028-0.013-0.010-0.004-0.005-0.009 std. err. 0.005 0.005 0.005 0.006 0.006 0.009 Median -0.005-0.002 0.001 0.000 0.005 0.002 Skew -3.394-1.660-1.553-2.701-2.790-7.144 Observations 1584 1363 1187 1055 926 694 Panel B: Industry-adjusted Q, with benchmark = industry average t: Event year t+1 t+2 t+3 t+4 t+5 Average -0.440-0.396-0.325-0.311-0.192-0.097 std. err. 0.054 0.053 0.058 0.059 0.065 0.084 Median -0.643-0.497-0.439-0.490-0.415-0.398 Skew 3.689 3.587 3.351 3.576 3.321 3.399 Observations 1611 1384 1206 1076 942 710 29 Industry average levels differ somewhat from industry median levels because both ROA and Q are skewed. ROA is significantly skewed to the left and, as a result, the average is lower than the median. Q is significantly skewed to the right and, as a result, the benchmark average is higher than the median. 30 The Industry averages are calculated after pre-winsorizing the firm Q and ROA. In an earlier version of this paper, we calculated the industry averages Q and ROA before pre-winsorization. The two results are qualitatively similar. 9

Table 3 indicates that targets of activist interventions tend to under-perform at the time of the intervention. In the year of intervention, both the average industry-adjusted ROA and the industry-adjusted Q are negative. 31 Furthermore, and most importantly for the purposes of our inquiry in this paper, Table 3 displays clear patterns of improved operating performance relative to industry peers during the five years following activist interventions. As Panel A shows, the average industry-adjusted ROA increases over time during the five-year period following the intervention year. Indeed, average industry-adjusted ROA is higher in each of the five years following the intervention than in the year of intervention. Furthermore, the increase is of significant magnitude and closes most of the under-performance relative to industry peers at the time of the intervention. Panel B displays a similar pattern with respect to average industry-adjusted Q. The average industry-adjusted Q increases over time during the five-year period following the intervention year. Furthermore, average industry-adjusted Q is higher in each of the five years following the intervention than in the year of intervention, and the increase during the five years is of significant magnitude relative to the under-performance at the time of the intervention. Last, as with the change in ROA, the increase in Q closes most of the under-performance relative to industry peers at the time of the intervention. Finally, Figure 1 displays graphically the results presented in Table 3. In particular, the Figure plots the evolution of industry-adjusted ROA and industry-adjusted Q. The graphs vividly display the increasing patterns of Q and ROA during the years following the intervention. Figure 1: The Evolution of ROA and Q Over Time 0.0% Industry Adjusted ROA (in %) 0.0 Industry Adjusted Q -0.5% -1.0% -1.5% -2.0% -2.5% -0.1-0.2-0.3-0.4-3.0% t t+1 t+2 t+3 t+4 t+5-0.5 t t+1 t+2 t+3 t+4 t+5 31 In addition, note that the median industry-adjusted Q and the median industry-adjusted Q are also both negative. 10

C. Regression Analysis We now turn to a regression analysis of the evolution of ROA and Q over time. This analysis enables us to control for other factors that might be relevant and to assess the statistical significance of our results. Table 4 below displays the results of four regressions. In column (1) and (2), we run a regression in which the dependent variable is ROA. The adjustment for industry performance is made by including industry (or firm) fixed effects. In both regressions we include as explanatory variables dummy variables representing the year of intervention as well as each of the subsequent five years. As controls, we use in both regressions the company s market value and age, year fixed effects to account for time trends in the values of ROA and Q and the impact of macroeconomic factors, and dummy variables for each of the three years preceding the intervention year. In regression (1) we include industry fixed effects. As a result, the coefficients on the key variables t, t+1,, t+5, should be interpreted as a difference-in-difference. It is as if we first take a difference of each firm-year ROA against the average level of all firms in the same year and the sample average of all firms in the same industry. We then estimate the difference between the industry-and-year-adjusted ROA of firms targeted in the current and next five years and that of the non-target firms while holding constant company size and age. In regression (2) we include a dummy for each firm, running a firm fixed effect regression, to account for time-invariant factors unique to each firm. Under such a specification, the coefficients on the key variables, t, t+1,, t+5, should be interpreted as the excess performance of a target firm, during years t to t+5, over its own all-time average and adjusted for market-wide conditions (due to the year fixed effects). Firm fixed effects automatically subsume industry fixed effects. In columns (3) and (4) we run regressions that are identical to those in (1) and (2) respectively except that the dependent variable is now Q rather than ROA. Thus, regression (3) includes industry fixed effects and regression (4) includes firm fixed effects. 11

Table 4: Evolution of ROA and Q over Time (1) (2) (3) (4) Dependent Variable ROA ROA Q Q t: Event year -0.007-0.013*** -0.346*** -0.016 (-1.363) (-3.036) (-6.357) (-0.341) t+1 0.010** 0.002-0.271*** 0.066 (2.075) (0.543) (-4.996) (1.296) t+2 0.016*** 0.007-0.175*** 0.178*** (3.223) (1.510) (-2.951) (3.342) t+3 0.020*** 0.010* -0.065 0.255*** (3.678) (1.886) (-1.014) (4.444) t+4 0.013** 0.007 0.029 0.304*** (2.112) (1.415) (0.433) (5.083) t+5 0.008 0.002 0.118 0.338*** (0.954) (0.348) (1.385) (4.520) ln(mv) 0.036*** 0.043*** 0.242*** 0.840*** (90.124) (39.843) (65.065) (76.917) Ln(Age) 0.021*** 0.009*** -0.275*** -0.345*** (28.254) (5.653) (-40.435) (-22.375) Year FE Y Y Y Y SIC 3 FE Y Y Firm FE Y Y Pre-event dummies (t-1,t-2,t-3) Y Y Y Y Observations 126,742 126,742 129,966 129,966 R-squared 0.202 0.702 0.191 0.626 F-Tests: F Tests: [t+3] t 12.9 13.8 [t+3] - t 11.1 15.4 p-val 0.0% 0.0% p-val 0.0% 0.0% [t+4] t 6.2 10.78 [t+4] - t 18.5 20.2 p-val 1.3% 0.1% p-val 0.0% 0.0% [t+5] t 2.3 3.9 [t+5] - t 20.9 17.7 p-val 12.6% 5.0% p-val 0.0% 0.0% The results of the regressions are consistent with the view that targets of activist interventions tend to under-perform at the time of the intervention. The coefficient of the event year is negative in both of the ROA regressions (1) and (2), and is statistically significant at the 99% confidence in regression (2), indicating that target firms were performing significantly below their own normal levels at the time of intervention. Similarly, the coefficient of the event year t is negative in both of the Q regressions (3) and (4) and is statistically significant at the 99% level in regression (3), indicating that target firms command valuations (relative to their book values) that were considerably below their industry peers at the time of intervention Most importantly for the purposes of our inquiry in this paper, there is no evidence for the post-intervention decline in operating performance feared by those making the myopic activist claims. Indeed, the results are consistent with the view that operating performance 12

improves steadily during the years following the intervention relative to the intervention time. Indeed, in each of the four regressions, each of the coefficients for the dummy variables representing the years t+1, t+2. t+3, t+4, and t+5 is higher than the coefficient for the event year. Because holders of the myopic activists focus on declines in operating performance, we pay special attention to the coefficients for t+3, t+4, and t+5. In particular, for each of the four regressions, we conduct F-tests for the difference between each of these coefficients and the event year coefficient. In each of the tests, each of the t+3, t+4, and t+5 coefficients is higher than the event year coefficient and the difference is statistically significant at the 90% confidence level in eleven of the twelve F-tests we conduct and, indeed, significant at the 99% confidence level in nine of these tests. Finally, looking at the coefficients for the pre-intervention years used as controls (not tabulated), we note that, in three of the four regressions, these coefficients decline from t-3 to the event year t. Indeed, F-tests conducted for these three regressions indicate that the difference between the event year coefficient and the t-3 coefficient is negative and significant at a confidence level of 95% or higher. This suggests that the operating performance of the target of activist intervention was trending in a negative direction during the period preceding the intervention and that the intervention was followed by a reversal of this trend. 1. A Clear Pattern D. Summary The analysis above establishes a clear pattern. To begin, activists do not generally target well-performing companies. Targets of activism tend to be companies whose operating performance was below industry peers or their own historical levels at the time of intervention. Indeed, at the time of the intervention the targets seem to be in a negative trend with operating performance declining during the three years preceding the intervention. Furthermore, during the five years following the intervention, we find no evidence for the concerns that activists push companies to increase short-term earnings at the expense of operating performance in subsequent years. To the contrary, we find that the activist intervention is followed by systematic improvement in operating performance relative to industry peers during this five-year period. Indeed, operating performance exceeds the intervention year level in each of the years three, four, and five following the intervention; these improvements are both statistically significant and economically meaningful. Thus, the evidence is inconsistent with the view that activists push for and produce shortterm increases in earnings at the expense of worse operating performance later on. Activist interventions are followed in the long-term by improved, not worse, operating performance. 2. Causality vs. Stock Picking 13

In response to the above findings, critics of hedge fund activism might argue that the identified association between activist intervention and subsequent improvements in operating performance does not by itself demonstrate a causal link. It could merely reflect the activists tendency to choose targets whose operating performance is expected to increase in any event. Under such a scenario, the improvement in long-term performance experienced by targets reflect the activist s stock picking ability rather than the activist s impact on the company s operating performance. We would like to stress at the outset that accepting that activist interventions are followed by improvements in operating performance, and merely questioning whether activists should get credit for these improvement, would already concede that the long-term consequence of activism provide no basis for calls to limit the influence of activism and to insulate boards form such influence. Such calls have been premised on the claim that activist interventions are followed by (and bring about) declines in long-term operating performance. To the extent that interventions are followed by improvements in operating performance, there is no reason to seek to limit the influence of the activists regardless of how much credit they should be getting for the improvements. Stock pickers who successful bet on future improvements might not deserve a medal, but certainly do not warrant criticism and opposition. However, there are reasons to believe that the identified improvements in operating performance are at least partly due to the activist interventions. To begin, the activist themselves clearly believe that their activities contribute to the subsequent improvements in operating performance. Activist activities involve significant costs, and activists would thus have strong incentive to avoid bearing them if they believed that the improvements in performance would ensue even without them engaging in such activities. They would just buy a stake, avoid intervening in how the company is run, and passively capture the benefits of the improved performance expected to take place. Furthermore, the view that the interventions contribute to the subsequent improvements is consistent with the finding in earlier work co-authored by the two of us that such improvements do not take place after outside blockholders pursuing a passive strategy announce the purchase of a block of shares, but occur after a subset of the blockholders switch from passive to activist stance. 32 This finding is also consistent with the view that the patterns we identify above are at least partly a product of the activists work and not merely a reflection of their foresight in choosing targets. In any event, causality issues in corporate governance and finance are notoriously difficult to resolve confidently and are not a main focus of this paper. Our chief interest is in investigating empirically whether the long-standing claim that activist interventions are followed by declines in long-term operating performance are backed by the evidence. Because this claim has been the basis for calls to limit the rights and involvement of activist investors, determining 32 See Alon Brav, Wei Jiang and Hyunseob Kim, The Real Effects of Hedge Fund Activism: Productivity, Asset Allocation, and Industry Concentration, NBER WORKING PAPER No. w17517 (2011). 14

its validity is important for the ongoing policy debate. Our results provide a clear answer: this long-standing claim is not supported by the data. IV. STOCK RETURNS We now turn to examine the long-term returns to the shareholders of companies targeted by hedge fund activists. Opponents of activism believe that the initially positive stock market reaction to activist interventions represent inefficient, myopic market pricing that fails to reflect the subsequent negative returns that are experienced by long-term shareholders and make such shareholders worse off. Such opponents also hold the view that, while activists might benefit from capturing positive stock price returns prior to their departure, negative long-term stock returns follow this exit, leaving long-term shareholders holding the bag. In this Part, we subject these claims to an empirical test. Section A begins by confirming the short-term pattern conceded by opponents of activism, i.e., the positive abnormal stock returns that such shareholders enjoy during the 40-day period surrounding the filing of Schedule 13D by an activist hedge fund. Section B investigates empirically the claim that these initial gains are wiped out by significant negative returns in subsequent years. Section C examines empirically the claims that negative long-term returns follow the departure of activists. Finally, Section D concludes. A. Short-Term Returns We begin by examining in our sample the stock price movements that accompany the announcement of the activist campaign. That is, we document the initial stock price spike that activism opponents argue to be reversed in the long term. The initial spike we confirm below has been extensively documented by prior work. This pattern was first documented in an empirical study co-authored by two of us, 33 as well as in a study conducted by April Klein and Emanuel Zur. 34 These initial findings were corroborated by three subsequent studies by Nicole Boyson and Robert Mooradian, 35 Christopher P. Clifford, 36 and Robin Greenwood and Michael Schor. 37 Each of these studies found that 13D filings by activists were accompanied by positive stock market reactions. 38 33 See Alon Brav, Wei Jiang, Frank Partnoy, and Randall Thomas, Hedge Fund Activism, Corporate Governance, and Firm Performance, 63(4) J. FIN. 1729, 1741 45 (2008). 34 April Klein and Emanuel Zur, Entrepreneurial Shareholder Activism: Hedge Funds and Other Private Investors, 64 J. FIN., 187 (2009). 35 Nicole M. Boyson and Robert M. Mooradian, Intense Hedge Fund Activists, WORKING PAPER (2009), available at ssrn.com/paper=1492641. 36 Christopher P. Clifford, Value Creation or Destruction? Hedge Funds as Shareholder Activists, 14 J. CORP. FIN. (2008). 37 Robin Greenwood and Michael Schor, Investor Activism and Takeovers, 92 J. FINANC. ECON., 362 75 (2009). 15

Although our focus is on long-term results, we begin by confirming this effect in our extended sample. Figure 2 below describes the average abnormal buy-and-hold returns in a 40- day window surrounding the filing of a Schedule 13D. This period begins twenty days before an activist hedge fund files a schedule through twenty days afterwards. Figure 2: short-term stock returns around 13d filings As the Figure shows, the average abnormal returns observed during the 20-day period before and after an investor files a Schedule 13D are approximately 6%, a magnitude consistent with the findings in prior work. The initial market reaction to the announcement of an activist stake views this development as good news. And this market reaction is consistent with the view that hedge fund activists provide benefits to, rather than impose costs on, the targets of their campaigns. 39 Opponents of activism do not contest the evidence that activist interventions are accompanied by positive short-term stock returns but rather dismiss its significance. Lipton, for example, argues that the important question is, [f]or companies that are the subject of hedge fund activism and remain independent, what is the impact on stock price performance relative to the benchmark, not just in the short period after announcement of the activist interest, but after a 24-month period. 40 38 Similarly, Marco Becht, Julian Franks, Colin Mayer, and Stefano Rossi studied activist engagement by the Hermes U.K. Focus Fund and found that positive and significant abnormal short-term returns (about 5% in the seven-day event window) accompanied the announcement of changes produced by such engagement. See Marco Becht, Julian R. Franks, Colin Mayer, and Stefano Rossi, Returns to Shareholder Activism: Evidence from a Clinical Study of the Hermes U.K. Focus Fund, 23(3) REV. FIN. ST., 3093 (2009). 39 See, e.g., Alon Brav, Wei Jiang and Hyunseob Kim, Hedge Fund Activism: A Review, 4(3) FOUNDATIONS AND TRENDS IN FINANCE 185 (2009). 40 Id. 16

Opponents of activism believe that (i) the elevated stock price levels following 13D filings represent inefficient market pricing that fails to perceive the expected long-term costs of the intervention, (ii) as a result, the initial spike is expected to be followed in the long term by negative abnormal stock returns, and (iii) these negative returns are so large that they wipe out the initial spike and make long-term shareholders worse off. To the assessment of this claim we will now turn. B. Subsequent Reversal? Clearly, the above proposition has empirical implications that make it testable using publicly available data. Surprisingly, however, opponents of activism have not tried to test this key proposition empirically or to commission or encourage such testing by others. Nor have those holding this view provided any empirical support for the reversal and long-term underperformance they assert. Although opponents of activism holding this view have failed to provide empirical evidence backing it, some have stressed that it is strongly confirmed by their experiences. Martin Lipton, for example, recently wrote that his short-termism concerns are based on the decades of [his and his] firm s experience in advising corporations. 41 In our view, however, arguments and policy decisions should not be based on reported individual experience and felt intuitions concerning long-term returns. Data on stock returns is generally publicly available and accessible and it makes it possible to subject claims about returns to a rigorous and objective test. Below we engage in such testing. We examine returns to the shareholders of targets of activist interventions in the five years following the initial stock price spike accompanying the intervention. We look for evidence of the asserted long-term reversal that is believed to make long-term shareholders worse off. In investigating the presence of negative abnormal long-term returns, we employ three standard approaches used by financial economists for detecting underperformance relative to the risks involved. First, in Subsection 1, we examine whether the returns to targeted companies were systematically lower during the considered five-year period than what would be expected given standard asset pricing models. Second, in Subsection 2, we examine whether the long-term returns to targeted companies were lower than those of matched firms that is, firms that are similar in terms of size and book to market. Third, in Subsection 3, using a portfolio approach, we examine whether a portfolio that took a position in each targeted company after the 13D announcement window and retained this position for the subsequent five years underperformed relative to its risk characteristics. Using each of these methods, we look for evidence of the asserted long-term underperformance of companies that were the targets of activist interventions. As we discuss 41 See Wachtell, Lipton Memorandum, Bite the Apple; Poison the Apple; Paralyze the Company; Wreck the Economy, REPROD. THE HARVARD LAW SCHOOL FORUM ON CORPORATE GOVERNANCE AND FINANCIAL REGULATION (Feb. 26, 2013). 17