How New Zealand Governments Determine Their Fiscal Strategies

Similar documents
for the year ending 30 June 2016 Economic Development and Infrastructure Sector

Note: This feature provides supplementary analysis for the material in Part 3 of Common Sense Economics.

THE FINANCIAL CRISIS: Is This a REPEAT OF THE 80 S FOR AGRICULTURE? Mike Boehlje and Chris Hurt, Department of Agricultural Economics

Introducing expanded external lending and debt statistics

A layperson s guide to monetary policy

12.1 Introduction The MP Curve: Monetary Policy and the Interest Rates 1/24/2013. Monetary Policy and the Phillips Curve

Investing in our future the role of the New Zealand Superannuation Fund

Chapter 12: Gross Domestic Product and Growth Section 1

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

Chapter 10 Fiscal Policy Macroeconomics In Context (Goodwin, et al.)

The Treasury Loan-to-Value Ratios/Macroprudential Policy Information Release. Release Document. June 2015

Jarle Bergo: Monetary policy and the outlook for the Norwegian economy

a) Aggregate Demand (AD) and Aggregate Supply (AS) analysis

MACROECONOMIC AND INDUSTRY ANALYSIS VALUATION PROCESS

THE POTENTIAL MACROECONOMIC EFFECT OF DEBT CEILING BRINKMANSHIP

U.S. Fixed Income: Potential Interest Rate Shock Scenario

DEBT FUNDING GUIDELINES FOR LOCAL GOVERNMENT

Project LINK Meeting New York, October Country Report: Australia

GOVERNMENT OF SAINT LUCIA DEBT MANAGEMENT STRATEGY

Chapter 18. MODERN PRINCIPLES OF ECONOMICS Third Edition

With lectures 1-8 behind us, we now have the tools to support the discussion and implementation of economic policy.

Switzerland 2013 Article for Consultation Preliminary Conclusions Bern, March 18, 2013

3. a. If all money is held as currency, then the money supply is equal to the monetary base. The money supply will be $1,000.

FISCAL POLICY* Chapter. Key Concepts

Economic Policy After the 1979 Oil Shock

MACROECONOMIC AND FISCAL ASSESSMENT

Politics, Surpluses, Deficits, and Debt

OFFICE OF THE STATE COMPTROLLER Thomas P. DiNapoli, State Comptroller. New York State s Cash Flow Crunch

Reading the balance of payments accounts

THE RETURN OF CAPITAL EXPENDITURE OR CAPEX CYCLE IN MALAYSIA

ZIMELE PERSONAL PENSION PLAN

Impact of Global Financial Crisis on South Asia

Should banks be allowed to go into bankruptcy

Sweden 2013 Article IV Consultation: Concluding Statement of the Mission Stockholm May 31, 2013

The Fiscal Policy and The Monetary Policy. Ing. Mansoor Maitah Ph.D.

In recent years, fiscal policy in China has been prudent. Fiscal deficits

Quarterly Employment Survey: September 2011 quarter

South African Trade-Offs among Depreciation, Inflation, and Unemployment. Alex Diamond Stephanie Manning Jose Vasquez Erin Whitaker

Why Has Japan Been Hit So Hard by the Global Recession?

HOW BAD IS THE CURRENT RECESSION? LABOUR MARKET DOWNTURNS SINCE THE 1960s

Best Essay from a First Year Student

7 AGGREGATE SUPPLY AND AGGREGATE DEMAND* Chapter. Key Concepts

Scotland s Balance Sheet. April 2013

Greece. 1. Economic situation

Financial Market Outlook

IMF Country Report No. 11/365

Government Budget and Fiscal Policy CHAPTER

United States General Accounting Office GAO. High-Risk Series. February Farm Loan Programs GAO/HR-95-9

Globalization, IMF and Bulgaria

A PLAN FOR A DEBT-FREE ALBERTA

Economics 101 Multiple Choice Questions for Final Examination Miller

FISCAL POLICY* Chapter. Key Concepts

EQUITY MARKET RISK PREMIUMS IN THE U.S. AND CANADA

Chapter 4 Consumption, Saving, and Investment

International Money and Banking: 8. How Central Banks Set Interest Rates

What Drives the Economy? Key Economic Variables

The U.S. and Midwest Economy in 2016: Implications for Supply Chain Firms

Effects on pensioners from leaving the EU

Guide to cash flow management

Working together: Racial discrimination in New Zealand

BANK INTEREST RATE MARGINS

A Model of Housing Prices and Residential Investment

Net debt as a fiscal anchor - balance sheet management

Introduction to Small Business Administration Lending

Why a Floating Exchange Rate Regime Makes Sense for Canada

Development of the government bond market and public debt management in Singapore

Study Questions for Chapter 9 (Answer Sheet)

Econ 202 Section 4 Final Exam

Session 12. Aggregate Supply: The Phillips curve. Credibility

Gross sovereign-issued debt (GSID) was broadly in line with forecast at $35.7 billion (23.1% of GDP).

I. Introduction to Aggregate Demand/Aggregate Supply Model

Research. What Impact Will Ballooning Government Debt Levels Have on Government Bond Yields?

Econ Spring 2007 Homework 5

STABILITY PROGRAMME

Volume Author/Editor: Universities-National Bureau. Volume URL: Chapter URL:

Adjusting to a Changing Economic World. Good afternoon, ladies and gentlemen. It s a pleasure to be with you here in Montréal today.

Lecture 2. Output, interest rates and exchange rates: the Mundell Fleming model.

Strategy Document 1/03

Lecture 4: The Aftermath of the Crisis

27Forecasting cash flows 27Activity 27.1 open-ended question.

Yukon Wealth Management, Inc.

Urban Community Energy Fund Getting your project investment ready

New Monetary Policy Challenges

WHY STUDY PUBLIC FINANCE?

CHAPTER 7: AGGREGATE DEMAND AND AGGREGATE SUPPLY

INFLATION REPORT PRESS CONFERENCE. Thursday 4 th February Opening remarks by the Governor

Fiscal policy and pension expenditure in Portugal

ECON 3312 Macroeconomics Exam 3 Fall Name MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

SHORT-RUN FLUCTUATIONS. David Romer. University of California, Berkeley. First version: August 1999 This revision: January 2012


E D I T I O N CLEP O F F I C I A L S T U D Y G U I D E. The College Board. College Level Examination Program

European Monetary Union Chapter 20

Why Invest in a Non-Traded Business Development Company?

The Euro and the Stability Pact. Martin Feldstein *

The Return of Saving

World Economic Outlook

MEASURING THE UK FISCAL STANCE

LECTURE NOTES ON MACROECONOMIC PRINCIPLES

THE IMPACT OF MACROECONOMIC FACTORS ON NON-PERFORMING LOANS IN THE REPUBLIC OF MOLDOVA

Decomposition of External Capital Inflows and Outflows in the Small Open Transition Economy (The Case Analysis of the Slovak Republic)

Transcription:

How New Zealand Governments Determine Their Fiscal Strategies A Layman s Guide

This pamphlet is based on the 2014 Fiscal Strategy Report. If you are reading it at a later date it is possible that some of the details of the fiscal strategy will have changed, but the general considerations will most likely be similar. Crown Copyright ISBN (Online): 978-0-478-43631-0 This work is licensed under the Creative Commons Attribution 3.0 New Zealand licence. In essence, you are free to copy, distribute and adapt the work, as long as you attribute the work to the Crown and abide by the other licence terms. To view a copy of this licence, visit http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/3.0/nz/. Please note that no departmental or governmental emblem, logo or Coat of Arms may be used in any way which infringes any provision of the Flags, Emblems, and Names Protection Act 1981. Attribution to the Crown should be in written form and not by reproduction of any such emblem, logo or Coat of Arms. The Treasury URL at March 2015 for this document is http://www.treasury.govt.nz/government/fiscalstrategy/laymansguide The PURL for this document is http://purl.oclc.org/nzt/g-nzgdfs

Contents INTRO What is a fiscal strategy?...2 PART 1 Why is a fiscal strategy important?...3 PART 2 What factors do governments take into...5 account when setting fiscal strategies? 2.1 How much Crown debt is prudent?... 5 2.2 What is happening in the broader economy,... 10 and how might the fiscal strategy affect it? 2.3 What about building up other assets in 12 preparation for a rainy day PART 3 Further reading...14 1

INTRODUCTION: What is a fiscal strategy? A government s fiscal strategy is a plan for managing its finances, which includes spending, revenue and the portfolio of assets and liabilities on the Crown balance sheet. New Zealand governments frequently express their fiscal strategies using goals for public debt and the gap between spending and revenue (that is, whether the annual budget is in surplus or deficit). It is a requirement under the Public Finance Act 1989 (PFA) for governments to produce a fiscal strategy every year and to set it out in a transparent way. Part 1 of this pamphlet explains why a government s fiscal strategy is important for New Zealanders. Part 2 explains the factors that are generally taken into account when developing a robust fiscal strategy. A Fiscal Strategy is a plan for managing its finances A key part of the current Government s fiscal strategy is to reduce net core Crown debt to no higher than 20% of national income (GDP) by 2020 and, after that, to keep net debt in the 10-20% range over the economic cycle. In the short term, the current Government s focus is on returning to surplus by 2014/15 and increasing surpluses thereafter. 2

PART 1: Why is a fiscal strategy important? Fiscal policy is not an end in itself. It is a means to help achieve important social and economic objectives. The choices governments make about their finances affect people s living standards both directly and indirectly. The taxes we pay and the services we get in return have implications for equity and economic performance. Decisions about public spending, tax and the balance between them is one of the most direct levers a government has to influence economic and social outcomes. Decisions about public spending, tax and the balance between them is one of the most direct levers a government has to influence economic and social outcomes For example, how much a government borrows can affect the wider economy with social implications. If the government is borrowing a lot, that debt may be perceived as riskier. This could mean that investors demand a higher interest rate to compensate for the higher risk. The consequence would be higher interest rates across the whole economy, putting upward pressure on the exchange rate and potentially discouraging investment by the private sector. It is not only government borrowing that affects the economy. Governments impact the level and composition of activity in the economy by spending more or less than they receive in revenue. For example, looser fiscal policy where governments increase spending or reduce taxes stimulates consumer demand. In a downturn, this may be appropriate. However, when the economy is already operating at or near capacity, stimulating demand tends to push up inflation, which can prompt the Reserve Bank to put up interest rates, leading to higher exchange rates than would otherwise be the case. In other words, in an upturn, looser fiscal settings could do more economic and social harm than good. 3

At the extreme, a government that runs an imprudent fiscal strategy exposes its people to serious risks. For example, New Zealand s public debt rose to high levels during the 1980s and early 1990s, with net core Crown debt reaching over 55% of GDP in 1992, exposing New Zealand to considerable risks. Over this period New Zealand s sovereign credit rating was downgraded twice. Governments eventually had to take abrupt measures to live within their means, involving socially disruptive policy adjustments. Since then, successive New Zealand governments have been committed to keeping government debt at more prudent levels. SHOCK! More recently, in Greece, decades of allowing expenses to exceed revenue contributed to a debt crisis which forced the government to make drastic cuts to various public services. The unplanned nature of these cuts was detrimental to living standards. Unemployment rose steeply with accompanying negative impacts on well-being arising not only from the immediate loss of income but also the increased level of uncertainty for those remaining in employment. 4

PART 2: What factors do governments take into account when setting fiscal strategies? When setting its fiscal strategy, a government needs to ensure that it complies with the principles of responsible fiscal management as set out in the PFA. For more detail on the fiscal policy framework, you can read the companion pamphlet An Introduction to New Zealand s Fiscal Policy Framework on this topic. 2.1 How much Crown debt is prudent? The PFA requires governments to maintain debt at prudent levels, but the law does not define what a prudent level is this is for the government of the day to determine and explain. The law does not define what a prudent level is The PFA also requires that governments aim, on average over time, to ensure that they fund current expenses such as of the health, welfare and justice systems out of current revenue without needing to borrow. If current expenses cannot be funded by current revenue, these expenses need to be funded by borrowing, at least in part. Debt-funding pushes the costs of repayment onto future generations, even if it is people today who are getting most of the benefits. However, borrowing for capital investments in assets, such as on bridges, roads and buildings, can be desirable. This is because it allows governments to spread the costs of that capital spending across the generations that will benefit from it. This cost-sharing could be considered fair. It also tends to create better incentives for current generations to spend an appropriate amount, as people who 5

must fund the whole cost of an investment yet will only see some of the benefits might be tempted to under-invest. Regardless of what the borrowing is used for, when public debt levels get too high it exposes a country to higher risks. For example, economic shocks will often lead to higher spending (eg, on unemployment benefits) and lower tax revenue and, thus, often result in the government needing to borrow more. But, an already high level of debt might restrict its ability to borrow more. Even in the absence of shocks, a high level of public debt might make lenders start to doubt a country s ability to repay its debt, leading to higher interest rates. And higher interest rates, coupled with the higher principal to which those rates are applied, means that interest payments form a higher share of current expenses, potentially crowding out more valuable spending or requiring higher taxes. There is no precise science to identifying the point at which public debt is too high, or to determine a level that is prudent. A number of factors affect this judgement, so we might expect different governments to come to different conclusions based on the specific circumstances they face: New Zealand is unusually vulnerable to natural disasters Vulnerability to shocks:»» New Zealand is unusually vulnerable to natural disasters (particularly earthquakes). As a small, open economy with a significant agricultural base we are also vulnerable to a range of other domestic and international shocks. For example, droughts or lower demand for our exports 6

can have significant impacts. Increased vulnerability to shocks implies that a lower level of public debt is prudent as a fiscal buffer. SHOCKS ARE PART OF LIFE IN NEW ZEALAND Here is a brief sample of some shocks that had significant negative economic or fiscal impacts for us over the past 40 years: Oil price shocks in 1973, 1979, 1990, and 2002. Decline in commodity prices in 1974. Global sharemarket crash of 1987. Asian Financial Crisis 1997/98. Droughts in 1973, 1992, 1998, 2008 and 2013. Global Financial Crisis in 2008/09. Canterbury earthquakes in 2010 and 2011. Private debt: The level of private borrowing and how it is held can also affect how much debt it is prudent for a government to hold. In New Zealand, the private sector s saving rate as a whole is not sufficient to fund all its investment, so firms and households borrow from foreigners (via the banks) to close the gap. These capital inflows mirror our large current account deficit, and imply an overall vulnerability for New Zealand. This is because, in a crisis situation, there is the risk that foreigners could start to lose confidence in lending to us, forcing a sudden contraction in economic 7

output. In addition, the Crown can also end up taking responsibility for debts that are not strictly speaking its own (see the box on page 9 for an example). Of course, to reduce this risk, the Reserve Bank and the Treasury promote policies to ensure a sound financial system. Lenders take into account all these factors when deciding whether to lend to governments, meaning that even a country with apparently low levels of public debt can seem like a risky proposition, potentially limiting that country s ability to borrow when it needs to. CASE STUDY Ireland: private debt public debt In 2008, following the onset of the global financial crisis, some of Ireland s major banks found themselves about to fail. To avoid a financial meltdown, the Irish Government stepped in and recapitalised its major banks. Even that was not quite enough, and one bank, the Anglo Irish Bank, was nationalised in 2009. The impact on the Irish Government s books was dramatic. From a slightly positive fiscal balance in 2007, Ireland moved into deficit in 2008, with the deficit peaking at 30.5% of GDP in 2010 (IMF). The debt story was similar: gross government debt was just under 25% of GDP in 2007, but rose quickly following the bank recapitalisations. In 2013 gross government debt reached around 116% of GDP. While not all of this debt increase is attributable to the government taking on private debt, a substantial proportion of it was. 8

Track record: The Global Financial Crisis put government and private debt into the spotlight. The prospect that governments might default on loans looms larger in lenders minds than it did prior to the global financial crisis. Most New Zealand government debt is held by non-residents. Debt held by non-residents is generally thought to be riskier to refinance than debt held by residents. However, as a country with a history of repaying its debt on time and successive governments that seem to take fiscal prudence seriously, the government is likely to be able to carry a higher level of public debt if the need arises, at least in the short-term. This is because lenders will trust us more. Maintaining a low level of public debt, in general, is part of that equation. The unique combination of being very vulnerable to shocks (economic and natural disasters) and high private debt has led successive New Zealand governments to hold a lower level of debt than foreign governments. This helps to ensure New Zealand maintains a reputation for repaying debt on time and provides a buffer against future shocks. In spite of the broad consensus to maintain prudent debt levels, over time different New Zealand governments have come to different conclusions about what level of debt is prudent. For instance:»» In 1994, the first year that the government was required by legislation to express a long-term debt objective, the government had a goal to reduce net debt from over 40% of GDP to between 20% and 30% of GDP (measured on a slightly different basis from the net core Crown debt measure we use now). 9

This goal was amended to below 20% of GDP in 1995 and to 15% of GDP in 1998. In 2000, a net debt objective of 20% of GDP was reintroduced, although in fact debt continued to decline below that level. From 2002-2008 the government used a gross debt objective of 20% of GDP essentially a stricter target. After the Global Financial Crisis hit and debt began to rise, the government stated that net debt would be reduced back towards 20% of GDP. By 2012 this goal was refined to no higher than 20% of GDP by 2020. In 2014, the government further clarified that after the 20% of GDP target is reached, it would maintain net debt within the range of 10-20% of GDP over the economic cycle. New Zealand s prudent levels of public debt in the lead up to the Global Financial Crisis helped New Zealand cope with the shock much better than comparator countries, despite the further shock of the Canterbury earthquakes. 2.2 What is happening in the broader economy, and how might the fiscal strategy affect it? Determining a prudent level of government debt is part of deciding a fiscal strategy, but it is only a starting point. Governments also need to consider the economic cycle and the implications for how fiscal policy should operate. On average over time, current expenses should not exceed current revenue. But we would not expect exact balancing each year. 10

In a downturn, it is reasonable for expenses to exceed revenue, in order to compensate for depressed tax revenue and to allow for some temporarily higher expenses, like spending to support people who have lost jobs. Conversely, in an upturn, we would expect revenue to exceed expenses. Excess revenue can be used to pay down public debt and build up other financial buffers. Paying down government debt when times are good means that debt can rise when times are bad; the country can manage a temporary period of expenses exceeding revenue with no lasting ill effects. There are other reasons why fiscal policy should generally be tighter in an upturn and looser in a downturn. Fiscal policy should generally be tighter in an upturn and looser in a downturn For example, looser fiscal policy during an upturn, when the economy is already operating at or near capacity, will further stimulate demand, prompting the Reserve Bank to increase interest rates further. This will put more upward pressure on the exchange rate than would otherwise be the case, and hurt the competitiveness of our exporters. Economists refer to the relative looseness and tightness of fiscal and monetary policy as the macroeconomic mix. In general, during an economic upturn, tighter fiscal policy (larger surpluses) and looser monetary policy (lower interest rates) is a better macroeconomic mix than the reverse. Even though the economic growth rate may be similar in either scenario, the composition of output will be different. Economic downturns are a better time for loosening fiscal policy (eg, by raising spending or lowering taxes) as the magnitude of interest rate and exchange rate cycles would not be exacerbated. 11

Governments often come under pressure during upturns to spend more money or cut taxes due to the appearance of large surpluses. At the time it is happening, an unusually strong period of economic growth can look permanent, making it seem harder to justify maintaining large fiscal surpluses. However, it is important that governments resist this pressure to spend surpluses during economic upturns, both for reasons of enhancing exporter competitiveness as discussed above and so that the government is better placed to respond to the next downturn, when it comes. 2.3 What about building up other assets in preparation for a rainy day? If you are going to make the argument that in the bad times such as when a big earthquake or a recession hits the Crown should borrow money to stimulate or support the economy, then logically, in the good times, you ve got to prepare for another rainy day. Reducing debt is not the only thing that governments can do to build buffers and prepare for a rainy day. Just as households may have separate saving accounts for different things, or income protection insurance to guard against accidents or a health scare, governments also do similar things. The different options for preparing for a rainy day are sometimes referred to as different jam jars into which the government can choose to save. One example of a government jam jar is the National Disaster Fund (NDF), which is financed by New Zealanders insurance EQC levies. The fund was used up in the aftermath of the Canterbury earthquakes in helping reimburse home and business-owners for damages. There are now questions about how quickly the fund should be rebuilt, and what priority rebuilding it should have, compared to other uses of 12

Crown revenue. In the meantime, in the NDF s absence, the low debt buffer becomes particularly important for helping to cope with the next natural disaster. The New Zealand Superannuation Fund (NZSF) is another jam jar on the Crown s balance sheet. Where the NDF provides insurance against a risk we cannot predict (earthquakes), the NZSF is designed to help society prepare for the known future expense associated with demographic ageing. As the population ages there will be an increase in government spending on New Zealand Superannuation entitlements. 13

PART 3: Further reading The Austerity vs Growth Debate and How NZ is Different (May 2012), Monthly Economic Indicators, Special Topic 2, The Treasury, http://www.treasury.govt.nz/economy/mei/ may12/04.htm Fiscal Indicators and the Financial Statements (2014), The Treasury, http://www.treasury.govt.nz/government/ fiscalstrategy/fiscalind-fsg.pdf Fiscal Strategy Report (2014), Hon Bill English, http://www. treasury.govt.nz/budget/2014/fsr Government and economic growth: Does size matter?, (2011), D. Cook, C. Schousboe and D. Law, New Zealand Treasury Working Paper 11/01, http://www.treasury.govt.nz/ publications/research-policy/tp/govtsize IMF Article IV Consultation Staff Reports, annual IMF reports on New Zealand. Treasury Investment Statement (2014), http://www.treasury. govt.nz/government/investmentstatements/2014 Modelling Shocks to New Zealand s Fiscal Position (2011), C. Fookes, New Zealand Treasury Working Paper 11/02, http://www.treasury.govt.nz/publications/research-policy/ wp/2011/11-02 Papers presented at New Zealand s Macroeconomic Imbalances Causes and Remedies Policy Forum, 23 and 24 June 2011, http://www.treasury.govt.nz/publications/researchpolicy/conferences-workshops/macroeconomicimbalances Recapping New Zealand s Recent Fiscal Policy (June 2013), Monthly Economic Indicators, Special Topic 2, The Treasury, http://www.treasury.govt.nz/economy/mei/jun13/04.htm 14