Who Benefited From North American Slavery?

Similar documents
Economic Efficiency, Government Price Setting, and Taxes

Chapter 12 The South Section Notes Video Maps History Close-up Images Quick Facts

Review Question - Chapter 7. MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

THIRD EDITION. ECONOMICS and. MICROECONOMICS Paul Krugman Robin Wells. Chapter 19. Factor Markets and Distribution of Income

Demand, Supply, and Market Equilibrium

chapter >> Consumer and Producer Surplus Section 3: Consumer Surplus, Producer Surplus, and the Gains from Trade

Chapter 6 Supply, Demand, and Government Policies

Chapter 3. The Concept of Elasticity and Consumer and Producer Surplus. Chapter Objectives. Chapter Outline

Demand, Supply and Elasticity

Learning Objectives. After reading Chapter 11 and working the problems for Chapter 11 in the textbook and in this Workbook, you should be able to:

4 THE MARKET FORCES OF SUPPLY AND DEMAND

chapter >> Consumer and Producer Surplus Section 1: Consumer Surplus and the Demand Curve

SUPPLY AND DEMAND : HOW MARKETS WORK

OVERVIEW. 2. If demand is vertical, demand is perfectly inelastic. Every change in price brings no change in quantity.

I. Introduction to Taxation

Managerial Economics Prof. Trupti Mishra S.J.M. School of Management Indian Institute of Technology, Bombay. Lecture - 13 Consumer Behaviour (Contd )

Chapter 27: Taxation. 27.1: Introduction. 27.2: The Two Prices with a Tax. 27.2: The Pre-Tax Position

Microeconomics Topic 3: Understand how various factors shift supply or demand and understand the consequences for equilibrium price and quantity.

The Mathematics 11 Competency Test Percent Increase or Decrease

7 AGGREGATE SUPPLY AND AGGREGATE DEMAND* Chapter. Key Concepts

MICROECONOMIC PRINCIPLES SPRING 2001 MIDTERM ONE -- Answers. February 16, Table One Labor Hours Needed to Make 1 Pounds Produced in 20 Hours

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

Module 49 Consumer and Producer Surplus

Profit Maximization. 2. product homogeneity

How to Study for Class 4: The Determinants of Demand and Supply

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

Reference: Gregory Mankiw s Principles of Macroeconomics, 2 nd edition, Chapters 10 and 11. Gross Domestic Product

Quantity of trips supplied (millions)

Knowledge Enrichment Seminar for Senior Secondary Economics Curriculum. Macroeconomics Series (3): Extension of trade theory

TRADE WITH SCALE ECONOMIES AND IMPERFECT COMPETITION (CONT'D)

Douglas, Spring 2008 February 21, 2008 PLEDGE: I have neither given nor received unauthorized help on this exam.

WHAT IS ECONOMICS. MODULE - 1 Understanding Economics OBJECTIVES 1.1 MEANING OF ECONOMICS. Notes

Supply and Demand. A market is a group of buyers and sellers of a particular good or service.

Chapter. Perfect Competition CHAPTER IN PERSPECTIVE

Finance 581: Arbitrage and Purchasing Power Parity Conditions Module 5: Lecture 1 [Speaker: Sheen Liu] [On Screen]

Lab 17: Consumer and Producer Surplus

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

PAGE 1. Econ Test 2 Fall 2003 Dr. Rupp. Multiple Choice. 1. The price elasticity of demand measures

Selected Homework Answers from Chapter 3

Maximising Consumer Surplus and Producer Surplus: How do airlines and mobile companies do it?

For centuries, people of the world have traded. From the ancient silk routes and spice trade to modern

Chapter 8. Competitive Firms and Markets

LECTURE NOTES ON MACROECONOMIC PRINCIPLES

Market Supply in the Short Run

Principle of Microeconomics Econ chapter 6

Employment and Pricing of Inputs

Chapter 3 Market Demand, Supply, and Elasticity

Chapter 3. Labor Productivity and Comparative Advantage: The Ricardian Model

Gov t Intervention: Price Floors & Price Ceilings / Taxes & Subsidies

Chapter 4 Supply and Demand Macroeconomics In Context (Goodwin, et al.)

Forward exchange rates

Chapter 7: Market Structures Section 1

Math 1526 Consumer and Producer Surplus

Homework #5: Answers. b. How can land rents as well as total wages be shown in such a diagram?

Chapter 6 Competitive Markets

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

Chapter 9 1. Use Exhibit 3 to answer the following questions.

Southern Culture and Slavery

Chapter 7. Comparative Advantage and the Gains from International Trade

III. INTERNATIONAL TRADE

Midterm Exam - Answers. November 3, 2005

Trade and Resources: The Heckscher-Ohlin Model. Professor Ralph Ossa International Commercial Policy

Elasticity and Its Application

ANSWERS TO END-OF-CHAPTER QUESTIONS

For instance between 1960 and 2000 the average hourly output produced by US workers rose by 140 percent.

Bailouts and Stimulus Plans. Eugene F. Fama

Candy Companies Flee U.S. Workers, Not U.S. Sugar Prices

The Election of 1860 Role Play

CHAPTER 1: LIMITS, ALTERNATIVES, AND CHOICES

Advanced International Economics Prof. Yamin Ahmad ECON 758

chapter >> First Principles Section 1: Individual Choice: The Core of Economics

MEASURING A NATION S INCOME

One Period Binomial Model

4. According to the graph, assume that Cliff and Paul were both producing wheat and corn, and each were dividing their time equally between the two. T

THE THEORY OF ECONOMIC VALUE

FISCAL POLICY* Chapter. Key Concepts

CHAPTER 9: PURE COMPETITION

Econ 202 Exam 2 Practice Problems

Economics 340: International Economics Andrew T. Hill Heckscher-Ohlin Theory

Massachusetts Institute of Technology Department of Economics Principles of Microeconomics Exam 2 Tuesday, November 6th, 2007

Peasant Welfare in England

The Business Cycle and The Great Depression of the 1930 s

Name Eco200: Practice Test 1 Covering Chapters 10 through 15

Agribusiness Management, its meaning, nature and scope, types Of management tasks and responsibilities

Study Questions for Chapter 9 (Answer Sheet)

A version of this essay was published as "Reduziert die Globalisierung die Kinderarbeit?" in Neue Zürcher Zeitung, February 23/24, 2002 p29.

Chapter 2 The Measurement and Structure of the National Economy

Econ 202 Section 4 Final Exam

At the end of Chapter 14, you will be able to answer the following:

Elasticity. Ratio of Percentage Changes. Elasticity and Its Application. Price Elasticity of Demand. Price Elasticity of Demand. Elasticity...

Problem Set #5-Key. Economics 305-Intermediate Microeconomic Theory

Economics 101 Multiple Choice Questions for Final Examination Miller

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

Topic 4: Different approaches to GDP

Test 1 10 October Assume that tea and lemons are complements and that coffee and tea are substitutes.

What did you have for breakfast this morning? Do you know where the things you ate and drank were produced or grown?

Chapter 1 Lecture Notes: Economics for MBAs and Masters of Finance

Final Exam 15 December 2006

Chapter 11. International Economics II: International Finance

Transcription:

Who Benefited From North American Slavery? Economics 113, Spring 2005 U.C. Berkeley Introduction Ask a historian, or a political scientist, or a politician the question, Who benefited from North American slavery? and the answer you will probably get is, The slaveholders, of course. The slaveholders got to work their slaves hard, pay them little, sell what they made for healthy prices, and get rich. We economists have a different view. Consider North American slaves growing cotton in the nineteenth century. Those slaveholders who owned slaves when it became clear that Cotton would be King that the British industrial revolution was producing an extraordinary demand for this stuff and that Eli Whitney s cotton gin meant that it could be produced cheaply profited immensely as the prices of the slaves they owned rose. But slaveholders who bought their slaves later on and entered the cotton-growing business probably profited little if any more than they would have had they invested their money in transatlantic commerce or New England factories or Midwestern land speculation: with the supply of slaves fixed, the excess profits produced I won t say earned by driving your slaves hard were already incorporated in the prices you paid for slaves. And there is another group who benefited mightily from North American slavery: consumers of machine-made cotton textiles, from peasants in Belgium able for the first time to buy a rug to London carters to Midwestern pioneers who found basic clothing the only cheap part of equipping a covered wagon. Slave-grown 1

cotton could be produced cheaply, yes, but the cotton-growers did not collude and so sold their cotton at prices that incorporated only a normal rate of profit. Cotton could be spun and woven by machines at amazingly low prices, yes, but British factories did not collude and sold their garments at prices that incorporated only a normal rate of profit. And there is yet a third group that benefited: northern and western Americans whose taxes are lower because of the tariffs collected on imports of goods financed by cotton exports. A lot of surplus was extracted from North American slaves. And the bulk of the surplus went to three places: to the pockets of those who owned slaves when slave prices boomed as the extent to which Cotton was King became clear, to those who could because of slavery buy machine-made cotton textiles much cheaper than would otherwise be the case, and to those in the north and west of the United States whose taxes were lower than would otherwise have been the case. That s the verbal preview of the economic argument. Now let s turn to the argument itself. It will proceed in three stages. First, it will sketch out a picture of what the world in the first half of the nineteenth century would have been like in the absence of North American slavery. Second, it will sketch out a picture of what the world actually looked at. Third, it will compare the two. The World in the Absence of Slavery Suppose that there were no North American slavery in the first half of the nineteenth century. Britain (and American) textile factories would still have gotten the bulk of their cotton from the American south: India was far and transport costs were high, and while Egypt was closer its cotton-growing capacity was limited. The big difference would have been that cotton would have had to have 2

been grown by free American farmers rather than by slaves, and that the price of cotton would have to be high enough to offer those who grew it earnings high enough to attract them out of northern wheat farming. Let s roll all the costs of growing cotton (including any labor engaged in supervision, storage, transportation, plus normal profits, et cetera) into one variable: the (high) wage of American labor growing cotton: w A. And let s make the constant returns to scale assumption: American land is free and American labor is abundant so that as long as free cotton-growers in America can earn w A more and more will enter the cotton-growing business, and America can grow as much cotton at the price corresponding to that wage as the world demands. Now let s move across the ocean, and make the same argument for the factories in Britain that spin and weave the cotton into cloth. British capital and labor are abundant, so we can once again assume constant returns to scale. British costs of production can be rolled into one variable, w B, the wage of British cottonprocessing labor ((including labor engaged in management, construction of factories, machine-making, machine fixing, storage, transportation, plus normal profits, et cetera). The assumptions we have made tell us that the world supply of cotton textiles takes a very simple form. It is, with P being the price and Q being the quantity of cotton textiles produced in the world: P = w A + w B If the price of cotton textiles were higher, American cottongrowers would earn more than w A and British cotton-processors would earn more than w B, more would enter the cotton-growing and cotton-processing businesses, and production would expand. If the price of cotton textiles were lower, American cotton-growers would earn less than w A and British cotton-processors would earn 3

less than w B, some would exit the cotton-growing and cottonprocessing businesses, and production would contract. The world supply of cotton textiles is perfectly elastic at the price P = wa+wb. The industry will supply whatever quantity Q is demanded at that price. The supply curve is a flat, horizontal line. Figure 1 World Supply of Textiles (No-Slavery World) In a world without slavery and with constant returns to scle in growing and processing cotton, the world supply of cotton textiles is a perfectly elastic horizontal line, with the price of cotton textiles equal to the sum of the American cottongrowing wage w A and the British cotton-processing wage w B. Let s also assume a particularly simple form for world demand for machine-made cotton textiles. Let the demand curve be: P = P 0 - βq 4

If production of machine-made cotton textiles were very small, then the (few) purchasers would be willing to pay some maximum price P 0 : that s the value of machine-made cotton textiles to those who want them the most. As production expands, in order to sell all the textiles produced they need to be sold to those who value them less and less, with each unit increase in quantity produced reducing the market price by the demand parameter β. Figure 2 World Demand and Supply of Textiles (No-Slavery World) The equilibrium quantity the amount of machine-made cotton textiles produced will be that which makes the price along the demand curve equal to the supply price: P 0 βq = P = w A + w B And so the quantity Q F of cotton textiles produced in the noslavery world in which cotton is grown by free labor is: 5

Q F = (P 0 w A w B )/β Now let s calculate who gets the surplus from the cotton-growing and cotton-textile industry in this no-slavery world. American cotton growers earn the wage w A but they could earn that same wage working in New York or growing wheat in the Midwest: they aren t made better off by the fact that the cotton-textile exists. (This is surely too strong a conclusion: their wage w A is probably a small premium above the wage they would earn elsewhere. But the major point is that they gain little, and that is surely true.) British cotton processors earn the wage w B but they could earn the same wage elsewhere: the British economy is full of opportunities and has a very flexible labor market. (Once again, the conclusion is too strong, but the message that British workers had ample other opportunities and would have done almost as well without the option of working in spinning mills is almost surely true.) Figure 3 Consumer Surplus in Textiles (No-Slavery World) 6

Now let s look at consumers of cotton textiles. They get lots of surplus. The first consumer gets (P 0 w A w B ) in surplus. The last purchaser gets 0. The average purchaser gets (P 0 w A w B )/2. There are (P 0 w A w B )/β purchasers. So total consumer surplus is: ( P 0 w A w B ) 2 2β Which you can also think of as the shaded green area in Figure 3 above. Now let s switch gears, and look at the world as it actually was the world with American slavery. The World as It Was, with Slavery Now consider the world as it was, with slavery. North Amerian slaves and there were, with the closing of the slave trade, a relatively fixed number of North American slaves could grow enough cotton to produce a quantity Q S of textiles. Assume that all the slaves who could be deployed to cotton were, and that the total production of cotton textiles with slavery was Q S. Then the price of cotton textiles will be the most that that quantity can be sold for: P S = P 0 - βq S That s the price at which British textile manufacturers will sell their textiles. Because they are a competitive industry on the buying side as well as the selling side, and because the quantity of cotton that slaves can grow is fixed and limited, they will pay as much as they can for scarce cotton imports. How much can they afford to pay? Well, if they pay more than P S w B they will lose money and go bankrupt. So slaveholders will earn 7

For each unit of cotton they sell. P S w B Figure 4 World Demand and Supply of Textiles (Actual, Slavery World) How is this P S w B per unit of cotton divided up? Some an amount ws goes to maintain the slaves. Some an amount t is collected as tariffs on imports of goods from Britain that slaveholders buy and goes to reduce the taxes of the United States s northern and western free-state citizens. And the rest: P S w B - w S t goes as profits to the slaveholders. Or does it? The supply of slaves is fixed. Slaves are a durable asset. If you get (P S w B - w S t) for each bale of cotton you 8

extract from a slave, people who want those profits will bid up the price of slaves. How far will they bid them up? Until the price of slaves is such that it is no longer an extraordinarily good deal to buy slaves and put them to work in the cotton fields. If r is the appropriate rate of return on capital in the American economy, the price of slaves will rise to: (P S w B - w S t )/r The capitalized value of the profits from slaveholding is thus captured by those who owned slaves when slave prices rose, and slave prices rose when people learned more about just how much surplus there was from growing cotton and shipping it to Industrial Revolution Britain. It was those who held slaves then who benefited the most, not those who bought slaves at high prices and put them to work later on. So northern and western taxpayers gained as tariffs on imports sold to slaveholders reduced their taxes. Those who owned slaves when it became clear that Cotton would be King gained. How about consumers the buyers of cotton textiles? Well, as long as P S is lower than w A + w B (and we know it isn t: if it were growing cotton with free labor would have been cheaper than growing cotton with slave labor), consumers gain because the consumer surplus triangle for the actual, slavery world is bigger than the consumer surplus triangle for the counterfactual, no slavery world. The difference is: (w A + w B P S )(Q F +Q S )/2 and can be seen to be the shaded area in Figure 5. 9

Figure 5 Gain to Consumers From Slavery Now, as I said above, all these conclusions are too strong. British wages were not completely unaffected by the existence of the cotton textile industry. British manufacturers gained, the landlords of Manchester gained, and British workers pulled into the booming textile factories gained too. But the British textile-processing industry (and the American cotton-growing industry) were nearly competitive. And competitive industries do not capture economic surplus they pass it along, forward to consumers and backward to the owners (in this case, initial slaveholders) of the factors of production they must be. So economists would say that the standard answer that slaveholders benefited from cotton-growing slavery is largely wrong. Initial slaveholders when it became clear how big a deal cotton would be gained, but world consumers gained as well, and so did those who benefited from lower American domestic taxes 10

made possible by high tariffs on imports financed by cotton exports. This is why we economists want to make every sociologist, historian, and political science at Berkeley and beyond! to take microeconomics, and then to take it again, and again. If you are going to evaluate what s going on in the economy, you need to be able to make these incidence calculations. And only microeconomic theory gives you the tools you need to do so. You may complain: I ve thrown a lot of algebra around (simple algebra) but no real numbers. How important was all this, really? Ah. You re going to have to answer that. That s what the next problem set is about JBD 20050215 11

12