Two broad cases are noteworthy: Monopolistic Competition

Similar documents
Managerial Economics & Business Strategy Chapter 9. Basic Oligopoly Models

Chapter 9 Basic Oligopoly Models

Oligopoly: How do firms behave when there are only a few competitors? These firms produce all or most of their industry s output.

Learning Objectives. Chapter 6. Market Structures. Market Structures (cont.) The Two Extremes: Perfect Competition and Pure Monopoly

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

Chapter 7: The Costs of Production QUESTIONS FOR REVIEW

Oligopoly and Strategic Pricing

CHAPTER 8 PROFIT MAXIMIZATION AND COMPETITIVE SUPPLY

Chapter 15: Monopoly WHY MONOPOLIES ARISE HOW MONOPOLIES MAKE PRODUCTION AND PRICING DECISIONS

ECON 312: Oligopolisitic Competition 1. Industrial Organization Oligopolistic Competition

Models of Imperfect Competition

All these models were characterized by constant returns to scale technologies and perfectly competitive markets.

CHAPTER 12 MARKETS WITH MARKET POWER Microeconomics in Context (Goodwin, et al.), 2 nd Edition

Price competition with homogenous products: The Bertrand duopoly model [Simultaneous move price setting duopoly]

Chapter 05 Perfect Competition, Monopoly, and Economic

Monopoly WHY MONOPOLIES ARISE

Pricing and Output Decisions: i Perfect. Managerial Economics: Economic Tools for Today s Decision Makers, 4/e By Paul Keat and Philip Young

Chapter 7: Market Structures Section 1

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

Managerial Economics & Business Strategy Chapter 8. Managing in Competitive, Monopolistic, and Monopolistically Competitive Markets

Chapter 7 Monopoly, Oligopoly and Strategy


Chapter 12 Monopolistic Competition and Oligopoly

Figure: Computing Monopoly Profit

INDUSTRIAL ECONOMICS COMPONENT: THE INTERACTIVE TEXTBOOK

A Detailed Price Discrimination Example

KEELE UNIVERSITY MID-TERM TEST, 2007 BA BUSINESS ECONOMICS BA FINANCE AND ECONOMICS BA MANAGEMENT SCIENCE ECO MANAGERIAL ECONOMICS II

Chapter 7: Market Structures Section 3

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

Market Structure: Perfect Competition and Monopoly

Chapter 6 MULTIPLE-CHOICE QUESTIONS

Chapter 6 Competitive Markets

Economics II: Micro Fall 2009 Exercise session 5. Market with a sole supplier is Monopolistic.

Monopolistic Competition

Economics Chapter 7 Market Structures. Perfect competition is a in which a large number of all produce.

Equilibrium of a firm under perfect competition in the short-run. A firm is under equilibrium at that point where it maximizes its profits.

Economics 201 Fall 2010 Introduction to Economic Analysis Problem Set #6 Due: Wednesday, November 3

Introduction to microeconomics

11 PERFECT COMPETITION. Chapter. Competition

Week 7 - Game Theory and Industrial Organisation

The Basics of Game Theory

Monopolistic Competition

Chapter 11. T he economy that we. The World of Oligopoly: Preliminaries to Successful Entry Production in a Nonnatural Monopoly Situation

Chapter 11 Pricing Strategies for Firms with Market Power

Econ 101: Principles of Microeconomics

Econ 101: Principles of Microeconomics

Lecture 28 Economics 181 International Trade

CHAPTER 6 MARKET STRUCTURE

A2 Micro Business Economics Diagrams

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

CHAPTER 18 MARKETS WITH MARKET POWER Principles of Economics in Context (Goodwin et al.)

MONOPOLIES HOW ARE MONOPOLIES ACHIEVED?

Managerial Economics. 1 is the application of Economic theory to managerial practice.

Chapter 16 Monopolistic Competition and Oligopoly

4. Market Structures. Learning Objectives Market Structures

Pure Competition urely competitive markets are used as the benchmark to evaluate market

Mikroekonomia B by Mikolaj Czajkowski. MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

Monopoly: static and dynamic efficiency M.Motta, Competition Policy: Theory and Practice, Cambridge University Press, 2004; ch. 2

Chapter 13 Oligopoly 1

9.1 Cournot and Bertrand Models with Homogeneous Products

Economics Chapter 7 Review

INTRODUCTORY MICROECONOMICS

Pre-Test Chapter 23 ed17

Chapter 8. Competitive Firms and Markets

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

Market Structure: Duopoly and Oligopoly

Midterm Exam #1 - Answers

OLIGOPOLY. Nature of Oligopoly. What Causes Oligopoly?

Maximising Consumer Surplus and Producer Surplus: How do airlines and mobile companies do it?

Revenue Structure, Objectives of a Firm and. Break-Even Analysis.

Practice Multiple Choice Questions Answers are bolded. Explanations to come soon!!

Sanna-Randaccio LECTURE 22 : NON TARIFF BARRIERS

Monopoly and Monopsony Labor Market Behavior

1. Supply and demand are the most important concepts in economics.

12 Monopolistic Competition and Oligopoly

5. Suppose demand is perfectly elastic, and the supply of the good in question

Chapter 14 Monopoly Monopoly and How It Arises

Chapter. Perfect Competition CHAPTER IN PERSPECTIVE

Practice Questions Week 8 Day 1

Common in European countries government runs telephone, water, electric companies.

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question on the accompanying scantron.

Lecture 3: The Theory of the Banking Firm and Banking Competition

Chapter 27: Taxation. 27.1: Introduction. 27.2: The Two Prices with a Tax. 27.2: The Pre-Tax Position

Figure 1, A Monopolistically Competitive Firm

UNIVERSITY OF CALICUT MICRO ECONOMICS - II

Microeconomics. Lecture Outline. Claudia Vogel. Winter Term 2009/2010. Part III Market Structure and Competitive Strategy

Solution to Homework Set 7

N. Gregory Mankiw Principles of Economics. Chapter 15. MONOPOLY

Chapter 13 Market Structure and Competition

Profit maximization in different market structures

Final Exam (Version 1) Answers

At the end of Chapter 18, you should be able to answer the following:

ECON101 STUDY GUIDE 7 CHAPTER 14

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

TRADE WITH SCALE ECONOMIES AND IMPERFECT COMPETITION (CONT'D)

Microeconomics Topic 7: Contrast market outcomes under monopoly and competition.

ECON 600 Lecture 5: Market Structure - Monopoly. Monopoly: a firm that is the only seller of a good or service with no close substitutes.

Economics 203: Intermediate Microeconomics I Lab Exercise #11. Buy Building Lease F1 = 500 F1 = 750 Firm 2 F2 = 500 F2 = 400

EXAM TWO REVIEW: A. Explicit Cost vs. Implicit Cost and Accounting Costs vs. Economic Costs:

This hand-out gives an overview of the main market structures including perfect competition, monopoly, monopolistic competition, and oligopoly.

Transcription:

Monopolistic Competition Until now, we have studied two extreme cases of competition: perfect competition and monopoly. Yet, reality is often in between: often, a firm s residual demand curve is downward sloping. This is the case when fixed costs in an industry are large compared to market demand, but not as big as to create a natural monopoly. Two broad cases are noteworthy: Oligopoly: The good in uestion is relatively homogenous, but entry is limited because of (uasi-)fixed costs (or possibly regulation). Monopolistic competition: The good of one supplier is uniue, but there exist close substitutes for the good. In practice, the distinction between these two market forms is sometimes difficult to draw precisely. Monopolistic competition is characterized by the following features:. A firm produces a specific variety of a good, which consumers perceive as different from that offered by competitors ( = product differentiation, e.g. geographic location, uality, taste, ) Monopolistically competitive firm has market power; firm s residual demand curve is downward sloping, because consumers only gradually shift away when firm raises its price.. The firm must pay high uasi-fixed costs to maintain its brand name (remember: uasifixed costs are paid independently of the uantity sold, if the uantity is positive). ACs decline over a large range, and the industry s minimum efficient scale is large. 3. Entry is possible in principle. firms in a monopolistically competitive industry make (approximately) zero profits. Firm s MR curve is downward sloping. 3 4

These features together imply that firm behaviour in monopolistic competition is given by two simple rules:. Marginal revenue euals marginal cost p, $ per unit p p = AC MC AC. Price euals average cost. In particular, the firm s residual demand curve and its average cost curve are tangent at the firm s optimal operating decision. MRr =MC MR r D r 5, Units per year 6 Three points to note: Monopolistically competitive euilibrium is inefficient: price is above marginal cost. In monopolistically competitive industries, there is excess capacity: if there were fewer firms, each firm could slide down its average cost curve by expanding output (but careful: less variety). Firms profits are driven to zero because of potential entry. But because uasi-fixed costs are large, not all profits need to be eroded. Hence, profits are only approximately zero. 7 p 300 75 83 47 0 Example: The wiss coated cornflakes market (hypothetical numbers). firms with uasi-fixed cost of Fr..3 million: π = $.8 million 64 MR r for firms D r for firms AC MC 37.5 75, Thousand tons per year 8

p 300 43 95 47 With 3 firms, the individual firm s residual demand curve shifts inward. All 3 firms make zero profits. Note: if fixed cost is larger than Fr..3 million, the third firm does not enter, and both firms make positive profits (smaller than Fr..8 million). AC MC An example of product differentiation: geographic location (Hotelling) Imagine the beach of a sea-side resort. uppose the beach is one kilometer long, and families are distributed eually along the beach. D r for 3 firms 0 48 MR r for 3 firms.5, Thousand tons per year 43 9 If there is one vendor who sells ice-cream, where should the vendor be located? 0 The average walking distance of all the people on the beach is minimized if the vendor sets up his shop at: Answer: At x = 0.5 and x = 0.75. The vendors have a clientele of [0, 0.5) and (0.5, ], respectively. x = 0.5 (where x = 0 represents the left end-point and x = the right end-point of the beach). Now assume that there are two ice-cream vendors. Where should the two optimally But if the two vendors are acting competitively, where do they locate? (To simplify assume that they charge the same price.) The vendor at x = 0.5 has an incentive to move to the right: by doing this, she keeps all her old customers, but captures some new customers in the middle. locate? 3

imilarly, the vendor at Another application: Circular City (alop) x = 0.75 has an incentive to move to the left. Result: - Both vendors locate at x = 0.5. - The monopolistically competitive euilibrium is inefficient (too little variety). 3 4 Oligopoly We now turn to markets in which the good in uestion is relatively homogenous, but there are only few suppliers in the market because of high fixed costs or other entry barriers. In such markets (oligopolies), the production choice of each producer has a strategic impact on all other producers. Reminder: The distinction between oligopoly and monopolistic competition is not always clear cut. On the one hand, homogenous goods offered by different firms are rarely exactly identical, on the other hand, even if a producer sells a differentiated product that protects her somewhat from market pressure, the other producers strategic choices will matter for her. 5 6 4

We study the simplest form of oligopoly: duopoly ( two sellers ) Assumptions: Market with one homogenous product, market demand D(p) Two firms in the market, no entry Firm i has cost function. C i () The strategic interaction in such a market can and does take many forms. In particular, one should ask: Is the relevant choice variable price or uantity? Is one firm dominant (leads in the decision making)? (Both these uestions are irrelevant in monopoly or in perfect competition) 7 8 The Cournot model In this model (Augustin Cournot, 838), neither firm is dominant (in the sense that it can directly influence the other s decision making), and both firms choose uantities. The important point: Each firm s optimal behaviour depends on what the other firm does. If, for example, firm chooses uantity, firm faces a residual demand curve of D r ( p) = D( p). Firm will, therefore, maximise its returns from pricing on this residual demand curve. If p( Q) = D ( Q) is the inverse market demand curve, this means that firm chooses to maximize p( + ) C ( ) 9 0 5

Assuming constant marginal cost: p This argument gives an optimal uantity = R ( ) for firm as a function of what firm produces. MC imilarly, we can derive the optimal uantity of firm as a function of what firm does: = R ( ). i The R are called best-response functions or reaction functions. MR r D r D 0 The Cournot euilibrium is defined as the pair (, ) such that = R ( ) and = R ( ). In words: firm s behaviour is the best response to firm s behaviour, and firm s behaviour is the best response to firm s behaviour. In other words: each firm chooses an output based on a belief about the other firm s choice, and no firm has an incentive to change its behaviour, once it learns the competitor s choice. 3 The Cournot euilibrium is the intersection point of the two best-response curves: Firm s best-response curve 0 M Cournot euilibrium Firm s best-response curve 4 6

Application: Competition in the airline market On many air-traffic routes, there are very few direct flights. In Europe these flights are often limited to the national carriers. Example: Geneva Berlin, where only wiss and ufthansa offer direct flights. The production function of air travel is characterized by constant and relatively low marginal costs high fixed costs We study competition between wiss and ufthansa on the Geneva - Berlin route by using a simple Cournot model, using rough estimates of cost and demand. Variables (expressed as one-way flight): price p (in Fr) uantity Q = + (000 passengers/year) Demand: D(p) = 300 0.3 p Cost: VC() = 300 (identical for both carriers) and F = 3,000,000; F = 8,000,000) 5 6 The wiss perspective: maximize p 300 = ( 000 3.33( + )) 300 The optimum is at = 05 0. 5. The ufthansa perspective: maximize ( 000 3.33( + )) 300 which yields =05 0. 5 7 The Cournot euilibrium is given by the intersection of these two reaction functions: = 05 0.5 = 05 0.5(05 0.5 ) = 70 By symmetry, also = 70. This gives a total uantity of Q = 40 and a price of p = 533.33. At this price, each airline makes a profit of H: (533.33 300)70,000 8,000,000 = 8.33 million/year) WI: (533.33 300)70,000 3,000,000 = 3.33 million/year 8 7

Remark: The model is simplified in several respects. One is the lack of price discrimination: airlines charge at least two prices for the same flight in the same class, one discounted for weekend travels and one marked up for within-week travel. 9 Generalisation of Cournot model Consider n firms, all with identical cost structures, C() = c. inear market demand: p = a - bq (for Q < a/b). The individual firm maximizes profits: ( n a b( +... ) c) which gives the reaction function: i = ( a c b b j i j ) i 30 The n reaction functions form a system of n euations in n variables: a c b( M a c b( j umming all these euations, using = Q, yields j= which means +... + +... + n ) b ) b n n = 0 = 0 n ( a c) nbq = bq n Q = n + a c n This simple formula is very useful and reasonable: For n =, this is just the monopoly output (determined by a- bq = c). As n increases, Q increases. As n becomes large, Q tends to (a c)/b. But this is just the competitive output (given by c = a bq) b 3 3 8

Hence, the Cournot model provides a model that fits in between the monopoly outcome and the competitive outcome, and the number of firms indicates a degree of competitiveness. ummary Table 33 34 9