Using survey data on informal firms in Myanmar, a number of issues related to firm-size,

Similar documents
Central African Republic Country Profile 2011

How To Calculate How Much Money A Business Makes From Its Customers

New data from Enterprise Surveys indicate that firms in Turkey operate at least as well as

DEFINITION OF THE CHILD: THE INTERNATIONAL/REGIONAL LEGAL FRAMEWORK. The African Charter on the Rights and Welfare of the Child, 1990

Obtaining Finance in Latin America and the Caribbean 1

country profiles WHO regions

Mexico Country Profile Region: Latin America & Caribbean Income Group: Upper middle income Population: 105,280,515 GNI per capita: US$8,340.

Flat vs Declining Balance Interest Rates What is the Difference?

Research Report May Which Countries in Europe Have the Best Gender Equality in the Workplace?

Running a Business in Georgia

Women, Business and the Law: Sarah Iqbal Program Manager Global Indicators Group, Development Economics

Who wants to be an entrepreneur?

Doing Business 2015 Fact Sheet: Sub-Saharan Africa

Country tables. Reform making it easier to do business Reform making it more difficult to do business

DEMOGRAPHIC AND SOCIOECONOMIC DETERMINANTS OF SCHOOL ATTENDANCE: AN ANALYSIS OF HOUSEHOLD SURVEY DATA

FINDINGS FROM AFROBAROMETER ROUND 5 SURVEY DEMOCRATIC ATTITUDES/BELIEFS, CITIZENSHIP & CIVIC RESPONSIBILITIES

Gender and ICT issues in Africa

Paid and Unpaid Labor in Developing Countries: an inequalities in time use approach

Comment on From Search to Match: When Loan Contracts are Too Long by Christophe Chamley and Céline Rochon

Financing Education for All in Sub Saharan Africa: Progress and Prospects

HIV/AIDS IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA: THE GROWING EPIDEMIC?

Towards Improving the Performance of Women Entrepreneurs in Small and Medium Enterprises in Nairobi County, Kenya: Policy Recommendations

Entrepreneurship in Egypt

IV. DEMOGRAPHIC PROFILE OF THE OLDER POPULATION

Entrepreneurship in Greece: Main trends & characteristics

Africa Business Forum December 2014

AIO Life Seminar Abidjan - Côte d Ivoire

Do Commodity Price Spikes Cause Long-Term Inflation?

Regional Profile Sub-Saharan Africa (SSA)

Executive summary. Global Wage Report 2014 / 15 Wages and income inequality

I. DEMOGRAPHIC DETERMINANTS OF POPULATION AGEING

Countries Ranked by Per Capita Income A. IBRD Only 1 Category iv (over $7,185)

The Development of Self-Employment in Russia

Social protection and poverty reduction

Entrepreneurship is attractive to many youth in the abstract. Key Messages. Data and methodology

Primary School Net and Gross Attendance Rates, Kenya. Over-Age, Under-Age, and On-Time Students in Primary School, Kenya

Sub-Saharan Africa Universal Service Fund study

Financial capability and saving: Evidence from the British Household Panel Survey

Avoiding Crime in Latin America and the Caribbean 1

Striving for Good Governance in Africa

WOMEN S PARTICIPATION IN AGRICULTURAL RESEARCH AND HIGHER EDUCATION

32 DOING BUSINESS 2011

YOUTH UNEMPLOYMENT ANALYSIS

HIV/AIDS: AWARENESS AND BEHAVIOUR

Financial Crisis. How Firms in Eastern and Central Europe Fared through the Global Financial Crisis: Evidence from

Workforce Training Results Report December 2008

Step 5. Facilitating labor mobility and job matching. Problem: None of the first four steps matter if people can t find jobs that match their skills

African Elephant (Loxondonta africana)

People and Demography

Progress and prospects

A Sloan Work & Family Research Network Fact Sheet

The Africa Infrastructure

COUNTRY NOTE GERMANY

It is important to understand child poverty as multidimensional. Income poverty in South Africa. Annie Leatt (Children s Institute)

Financing Profiles SMALL BUSINESS. Women Entrepreneurs. SME Financing Data Initiative October highlights

Association Between Variables

Regional Profile: Sub-Saharan Africa (SSA)

The Ariel Mutual Funds/Charles Schwab & Co., Inc. Black Investor Survey. Saving and Investing Among High Income African-American and White Americans

European Startup Monitor Country Report Germany. Introduction

Market Conditions for Housing Loans in Uganda

TALKING TRADE: ENTREPRENEURS IN AFRICA TRANSLATLANTIC BUSINESS STRATEGY. World Trade Week 13 May 2014 Michael Sudarkasa, CEO, ABG

WOMEN IN THE INFORMAL SECTOR: A GLOBAL PICTURE, THE GLOBAL MOVEMENT By Martha Alter Chen

Bachelor s graduates who pursue further postsecondary education

January PwC Research Services Survey on Retrenchment and Redundancy Practices

NQTs THEIR REASONS FOR JOINING, OR NOT, A TEACHERS ORGANISATION

Gender Dynamics in Crowdfunding: Evidence on Entrepreneurs, Investors, and Deals from Kickstarter

Matti Kyrö. International comparisons of some features of

UNAIDS 2013 AIDS by the numbers

ITC Survey: Small business exporters report improvements in business environment, expect exports to rise

West Bank and Gaza: Labor Market Trends, Growth and Unemployment 1

WHO Global Health Expenditure Atlas

REMARKS BY H.E. MARTHA POBEE ON WOMEN AND YOUTH ENTREPRENEURSHIP IN AFRICA: THE IMPACT OF ENTREPRENEURIAL EDUCATION ON DEVELOPMENT

Over-Age, Under-Age, and On-Time Students in Primary School, Tanzania

A TEACHER FOR EVERY CHILD: Projecting Global Teacher Needs from 2015 to 2030

Briefing note for countries on the 2015 Human Development Report. Burkina Faso

The Effects of the Current Economic Conditions on Sport Participation. Chris Gratton and Themis Kokolakakis

How Not to Count the Poor? A Reply to Reddy and Pogge

Secondary Analysis of the Gender Pay Gap. Changes in the gender pay gap over time

The Gender Global Entrepreneurship and Development Index (GEDI)

F. MORTALITY IN DEVELOPING COUNTRIES

Madagascar. Country coverage and the methodology of the Statistical Annex of the 2015 HDR

Briefing note for countries on the 2015 Human Development Report. Niger

Who Goes to Graduate School in Taiwan? Evidence from the 2005 College Graduate Survey and Follow- Up Surveys in 2006 and 2008

Knowing Your School. A series of briefing notes for school governors from the National Governors Association produced in association with partners

Can Entrepreneurship Programs Transform the Economic Lives of the Poor?

ijcrb.webs.com INTERDISCIPLINARY JOURNAL OF CONTEMPORARY RESEARCH IN BUSINESS APRIL 2013 VOL 4, NO 12 MARKET, KISUMU COUNTY, KENYA.

EARLY MARRIAGE A HARMFUL TRADITIONAL PRACTICE A STATISTICAL EXPLORATION

SECTOR ASSESSMENT (SUMMARY): MICRO, SMALL, AND MEDIUM-SIZED ENTERPRISE DEVELOPMENT

Graduate Entrepreneurial Intention in Turkey: Motivators and Obstacles. Nurdan Özarallı Marmara University, Istanbul, Turkey

Women Entrepreneurs in the Middle East and North Africa:

UPDATE UNAIDS 2016 DATE 2016

Congo (Democratic Republic of the)

The global economy in 2007

2016 Edenred-Ipsos Barometer Understand and improve Wellbeing At Work. May 2016

1 The total values reported in the tables and

Communications Networks and Foreign Direct Investment in Developing Countries

WELFARE STATES AND PUBLIC HEALTH: AN INTERNATIONAL COMPARISON. Peter Abrahamson University of Copenhagen

The Role of Small and Medium Size Enterprises in Economic Development

The earnings expectations of EU business school students

Getting credit WHO REFORMED IN GETTING CREDIT IN 2011/12?

Transcription:

Enterprise Surveys Enterprise Note Series Informality Informal Firms in World Bank Group Enterprise Note No. 33 216 Mohammad Amin Using survey data on informal firms in, a number of issues related to firm-size, productivity, business environment, gender disparity and registration costs and benefits are discussed. The findings suggest that informal firms in are less productive than formal sector firms but compare favorably with informal firms elsewhere. The education level of the manager is positively correlated with firm productivity but firm-size is not. Access to finance is the most commonly chosen top obstacle, especially by the relatively smaller firms. Few firms find any benefits from registration and particularly so in the relatively smaller cities outside Yangon. Introduction Informal or unregistered firms and workers exist in every country. According to some studies, while 17 percent of the work force in OECD countries is in the informal sector, in developing countries, the corresponding figure is about 6 percent (Ihrig and Moe, 24; Dessy and Pallage, 23). La Porta and Shliefer (214) suggest that about 3 to 4 percent of economic activity occurs in the informal sector in poor countries. Schneider et al. (21) estimate the informal economy to be about 34 percent on average for 88 developing countries in 25. Despite the large size of the informal economy, a number of issues remain unexplored. For example, low productivity of informal firms is worrisome but it is not clear if factors such as firm-size and manager s education level matter for productivity as has been found for the formal sector firms. Similarly, it is widely believed that informal firms face a poor business environment. However, it is not immediately clear what the top constraint is for example, limited access to finance or corruption? This note attempts to shed light on some of the issues mentioned above for informal firms in. Available estimates suggest that the informal economy in is large even by developing country standards. For example, according to Schneider et al. (21), in a sample of 88 developing countries, the share of the informal economy in is smaller than only 6 other countries. The data we use is a pure random sample of 3 informal (unregistered) firms in the large cities of and collected by the World Bank's Enterprise Surveys Unit (Enterprise Surveys). Due to lack of a proper sampling frame, the data are not necessarily representative of the informal sector in the cities covered. Hence, the results presented below should be treated with due caution as pertaining to the sample of informal firms rather than the broader informal sector in the country. For benchmarking purposes, we use similar Informal Surveys for 16 other developing countries. Further, we also use two other nationally representative surveys for non-agricultural and private sector firms in (Enterprise Surveys). These surveys cover the microenterprise firms (less than 5 employees), small firms (5 to 19 employees), medium firms (2 to 99 employees) and large firms (1 or more employees). 1 Informal firms in compare favorably in labor productivity and turnover with informal firms elsewhere It is well-known that compared with the formal sector firms, informal sector firms are much less productive and inefficiently small. This could be due to excessive government regulations that inhibit the sector (De Soto 1989, 2) or because of the sector s limited access to finance, low education and skills and lack of adequate motivation among the firm owners (La Porta et al. 214). In fact, one view is that productivity levels in the informal sector are so low that the sector can hardly be expected to contribute to overall growth and development (La Porta et al. 214). The Enterprise Surveys (ES) data confirm that informal

firms in are much smaller and have lower sales per worker (labor productivity) compared to formal sector firms in the country (figure 1). For example, median labor productivity of informal firms is about 65 percent of the level for micro firms in the country. Similarly, total monthly sales (turnover) for informal firms is about 75 percent of the level for micro firms and less than 5 percent of the level for medium and large firms. However, informal firms in do reasonably well when compared with informal firms elsewhere (figure 2). That is, median labor productivity in is higher than in 12 out of 16 other countries and monthly sales higher than in 13 other countries. Thus, the experience of could help improve productivity levels of informal firms in other countries. Do firm-size and owner s education matter for the productivity level of informal firms? Formalization and improving the business environment are often suggested as solutions to raising informal sector productivity. But what about other factors such as firmsize and education levels of the manager/owner which have been found to be important for firm productivity in the formal sector? Amin and Islam (215) look at the relationship between firm-size and labor productivity of informal firms in a crosssection of 13 developing countries. The issue is important since the small size of informal firms is often viewed as a reason for their low productivity. The authors argue that larger firm-size is likely to increase productivity due to increasing returns to scale but it may also lower it due to Figure 1 Monthly sales (USD. median) $25, $2, $15, $1, $5, $ Informal firms are smaller and have lower productivity than firms in the formal sector $289 $1,16 $1,355 $452 $3,48 $427 $21,166 $517 Informal Micro Small Medium & Large Sales (USD, monthly, median) Labor productivity (USD, monthly, median) $6 $5 $4 $3 $2 $1 $ Sales per worker (monthly, USD, median) Figure 2 Monthly sales (USD median $) 4,5 4, 3,5 3, 2,5 2, 1,5 1, 5 Madagascar Rwanda Cote d Ivoire Burkina Faso ranks high in turnover and labor productivity of informal firms Kenya Mali Congo, Dem. Rep. Ghana Guatemala Cameroon Botswana Argentina Mauritius Peru Angola Cabo Verde Sales (USD, monthly, median $) Labor productivity(usd, monthly, median $) increased costs of evading government regulations. They find that the latter effect dominates. For informal firms in, there is no relationship between firm-size and labor productivity (figure 3A). In contrast, for the comparator countries, the results confirm the findings in Amin and Islam. Thus, improvements in firm-size of the informal firms in are unlikely to add much to labor productivity levels. The role of education in improving labor productivity has been discussed in the literature, although much of this literature focuses on the formal sector (Echevin and Murtin 29, Bertrand and Schoar 23). La Porta and Shleifer (214) argue that higher levels of education of managers in the formal sector than the informal sector is what makes formal firms far more productive. However, the authors do not provide any evidence on how education affects labor productivity within the informal sector. As figure 3B shows, labor productivity level is significantly higher for informal firms in that have managers with higher education (secondary education, university degree or vocational training) vs. the rest (no education or primary education). This holds even after accounting for differences in firm characteristics including firm-size (number of employees), age of the firm, sector of activity (manufacturing vs. services), gender of the largest owner, years of manager experience in the field, region (city) fixed effects, dummy variables indicating whether or not the firm uses machinery, uses electricity, experienced losses due to crime, and reports access to finance as a major obstacle for its business. In short, providing better education to entrepreneurs in the informal sector could be a panacea for the low levels of productivity in the sector. 6 5 4 3 2 1 Sales per worker (monthly, USD median $) 2

Figure 3A Labor productivity and firm size are uncorrleated Figure 3B Labor productivty Labor productivity (USD, monthly, logs) 1 8 6 4 2 1 2 3 4 5 Number of workers (logs) (USD, monthly, median) 4 2 $35 Largest owner has secondary or higher education $169 Largest owner has primary or no education Female owned/run firms have lower labor productivity but only in the manufacturing sector A number of studies have shown that firms owned or run by women tend to under-perform firms owned or run by men in terms of firm productivity and turnover (Brush et al. 26; Sabarwal and Terrel 28). Difficulties that women face relative to men due to limited access to finance, discriminatory laws and social and cultural attitudes could explain the lower performance. However, the existing literature is entirely focused on formal sector firms and it is not clear if the findings apply to informal firms. The ES data reveal that on average, labor productivity level does not vary significantly between women vs. men owned/run 2 informal firms in. If anything, women perform better than men (figure 4). However, the firm s sector of activity matters. In the manufacturing Figure 4 Labor productivity (monthly, USD, median) 5 4 3 2 1 $322 $265 Female owned/run firms lag behind male owned/run firms in terms of labor productivity in the manufacturing sector in $178 $35 Full sample Manufacturing $416 $298 Female owned firms $145 $164 $114 $124 $37 $274 Services Full sample Manufacturing Services Other countries Male owned firms 19 sector, labor productivity is much lower for women and the opposite holds in the services sector. As figure 4 shows, the above findings are unique to. That is, for informal firms in other countries, on average, labor productivity is lower for female than male owned/run firms in the full sample, manufacturing sector, and especially services sector. The data confirm that the results for here are not due to differences in firm-size, age of the firm or the level of education of the owner/manager. Limited access to finance is the most commonly cited top obstacle, and more so by the smaller firms From a list of 8 obstacles (access to finance, access to land, corruption, crime, electricity supply, water supply, access to technology, and lack of skilled workers), access to finance was the most commonly chosen top obstacle (by 36 percent of the firms) followed by access to land (2 percent). On the absolute level, about a quarter of the informal firms in report limited access to finance as a severe obstacle for their business. As in the broader literature, firm-size matters here with the smaller firms (employment and sales wise) much more likely to report access to finance as the top obstacle and a severe obstacle than the larger firms (figure 5). Thus, policy measures aimed at relaxing financial constraints in the informal sector are likely to be more effective if targeted towards the relatively smaller firms. Smaller informal firms are more likely to be credit-constrained than larger informal firms Less than 5 percent of the informal firms in have a bank account for business purposes, much lower than in Guatemala (21 percent), Argentina (31 percent), Peru (33 percent) and Rwanda (78 percent) for which information is available. Micro firms with a bank account in are also few (1 percent). However, informal firms in 3

Figure 5 6 45 3 15 52 Lowest sales As perceived by the firms, limited access to finance affects smaller firms more than larger firms 39 37 2nd sales Access to finance is the top obstacle Figure 6 that are credit-constrained Figure 7 1 8 6 4 2 8 6 4 2 98 99 99 Own funds 32 31 21 3rd sales 23 19 Highest sales Access to finance is a severe obstacle Use of own funds is almost universal among informal firms in 9 Informal Small informal firms in are much more likely to be credit-constrained than the larger informal firms 47 Below median monthly sales 56 Lower limit 2 7 7 2 Credit/advance from suppliers/customers 36 Above median monthly sales Upper limit 4.7.3 4.7 4.5 Banks Micro Regular ES Other informal are less likely to be credit-constrained than informal firms elsewhere. Firms that did not apply for a loan during the last year because of complex application procedures, high interest rates, high collateral requirement, insufficient loan amount or maturity, and because the firm did not think it would be approved are classified as credit-constrained firms; firms that did not apply for the loan because of no need for a loan are credit-unconstrained firms; the remaining firms are the ones that applied for the loan but it is not clear if they got what they wanted. Classifying these remaining firms as credit-constrained gives an upper limit for creditconstrained firms and a lower limit by assuming that these firms are credit-unconstrained. Between 42 and 49 percent of the informal firms in are credit-constrained. This is only somewhat higher than the same for micro firms in the country (42 to 43 percent are credit- constrained) but lower than for informal firms on average in other countries (49 to 62 percent). As above, firm-size matters with small informal firms in much more likely to be credit-constrained than the larger informal firms (figure 6). Use of own funds by informal firms is almost universal in, and more common than elsewhere About 98 percent of the informal firms in use their own funds to finance working capital. As figure 7 shows, the figure is roughly same for the formal sector firms in the country but noticeably higher than for informal firms on average in other countries. Use of bank finance is almost non-existent among informal firms in as is the case for informal firms elsewhere. In contrast, use of credit/advances from suppliers/customers is more common among informal compared with micro firms in. Few firms have a favorable opinion of the benefits from formalization, especially in the smaller cities Policies encouraging formalization require an understanding of the potential benefits to firms from registering and the reasons for not registering. The ES asked firms about various reasons for not registering and potential benefits as perceived by them from registering. Findings from these questions are provided in figure 8. Two results stand out. First, the proportion of firms that believe there are benefits from registering is low: it ranges between 11 percent (better access to raw materials and public services) to 23 percent (less bribes to pay). Thus, it is not surprising that 62 percent of the firms report no benefit as a reason for not registering. In short, greater effort is required in making formalization more beneficial to the firms. Second, firms are much more likely to report 4

Figure 8 Perceived benefits from registering seem to be less common in the smaller cities Notes 1. Detailed information on these surveys is available at www. enterprisesurveys.org. 2. There is hardly any distinction between the largest owner and the manager of the firms in the sample used. 8 6 4 2 58 51 46 Time, fees, and paper work required to complete registration Reasons for not registering 62 55 51 Taxes that need to be paid if registered 151515 Inspections and meetings with government officials that follow registration 2 25 17 Bribes registered businesses need to pay 62 49 71 No benefit from registering Full sample Large city Small city Potential benefits from registering Better access to finance Better access Less bribes Being able to to raw materials and govt. services to pay issue receipts benefits from registering in the large city of Yangon than elsewhere in (see figure 8 for details). One reason for this could be that typically large cities have better public services, physical and financial infrastructure implying greater benefits from registering. What this suggests is that formalization efforts are likely to be more beneficial and successful where the availability of public services and infrastructure is good such as in the relatively larger cities of. As is the case in many other developing countries, the informal sector in is large and likely to persist. Understanding the sector is important both for raising incomes of those working in the sector, as well as to maximize the sector s contribution to overall growth and dynamism of the economy. Using firm-level survey data, this note highlights a number of issues concerning informal firms in covering firm productivity, gender disparity, business environment and costs and benefits of registration. While the findings are preliminary in nature, it is hoped that they will help encourage more rigorous empirical work in the future. 24 34 16 11 16 7 23 36 13 2 25 16 References Amin, Mohammed and Asif Islam (215), Are Large Informal Firms More Productive than the Small Informal Firms? Evidence from Firm-level Surveys in Africa, World Development 74(October): 374-385. Bertrand, Marianne, and Antoinette Schoar (23), Managing with Style: The Effect of Managers on Firm Policies, Quarterly Journal of Economics 118(4): 1169 128. Brush, C., N. Carter, E.J. Gatewood, P. Greene and M. Hart, (26), Growth Oriented Women Entrepreneurs and Their Businesses (New Horizons in Entrepreneurship). Cheltenham, UK and Northampton, MA: Edward Elgar. De Soto, Hernando (1989), The Other Path: The Invisible Revolution in the Third World, New York: Harper and Row. De Soto, Hernando (2), The Mystery of Capital: Why Capitalism Triumphs in the West and Fails Everywhere Else, New York: Basic Books. Dessy, Sylvain, and Stephane Pallage (23), Taxes, Inequality, and the Size of the Informal Sector, Journal of Development Economics 7(23): 225-233 Echevin, Damien and Fabrice Murtin (29), What Determines Productivity in Senegal? Sectoral Disparities and the Dual Labour Market, Journal of Development Studies 45(1): 177-173. Ihrig, Jane and Karine S. Moe (24), Lurking in the Shadows: the Informal Sector and Government Policy, Journal of Development Economics 73: 541-557. La Porta, Rafael and Andrei Shleifer (214), Informality and Development, Journal of Economic Perspectives 28(3): 19-126. Sabarwal, Shwetlana and Katherine Terrell (28), Does Gender Matter for Firm Performance? Evidence from Eastern Europe and Central Asia, World Bank Working Paper Series No. 475, World Bank, USA. Schneider, Friedrich, Andreas Buehn and Claudio E. Montenegro (21), Shadow Economies All over the World: New Estimates for 162 Countries from 1999 to 27, Working Paper 5356, World Bank, USA. The Enterprise Note Series presents short research reports to encourage the exchange of ideas on business environment issues. The notes present evidence on the relationship between government policies and the ability of businesses to create wealth. The notes carry the names of the authors and should be cited accordingly. The findings, interpretations, and conclusions expressed in this note are entirely those of the authors. They do not necessarily represent the views of the International Bank for Reconstruction and Development/World Bank and its affiliated organizations, or those of the Executive Directors of the World Bank or the governments they represent. 5