What Caused the Build-Up of Canada s Public Debt?

Similar documents
Politics, Surpluses, Deficits, and Debt

FISCAL POLICY* Chapter. Key Concepts

Answers to Text Questions and Problems in Chapter 11

University of Lethbridge Department of Economics ECON 1012 Introduction to Microeconomics Instructor: Michael G. Lanyi. Chapter 29 Fiscal Policy

I. Introduction to Aggregate Demand/Aggregate Supply Model

MONETARY AND FISCAL POLICY IN THE VERY SHORT RUN

The labour market, I: real wages, productivity and unemployment 7.1 INTRODUCTION

The Aggregate Demand- Aggregate Supply (AD-AS) Model

CHAPTER 7: AGGREGATE DEMAND AND AGGREGATE SUPPLY

Problem Set #4: Aggregate Supply and Aggregate Demand Econ 100B: Intermediate Macroeconomics

Econ 303: Intermediate Macroeconomics I Dr. Sauer Sample Questions for Exam #3

FISCAL POLICY* Chapter. Key Concepts

4. Answer c. The index of nominal wages for 1996 is the nominal wage in 1996 expressed as a percentage of the nominal wage in the base year.

12.1 Introduction The MP Curve: Monetary Policy and the Interest Rates 1/24/2013. Monetary Policy and the Phillips Curve

Chapter 12: Gross Domestic Product and Growth Section 1

MEASURING THE UK FISCAL STANCE

Study Questions for Chapter 9 (Answer Sheet)

Professor Christina Romer. LECTURE 17 MACROECONOMIC VARIABLES AND ISSUES March 17, 2016

Chapter 27: Taxation. 27.1: Introduction. 27.2: The Two Prices with a Tax. 27.2: The Pre-Tax Position

7 AGGREGATE SUPPLY AND AGGREGATE DEMAND* Chapter. Key Concepts

Fiscal Unruliness: Checking the Usual Suspects for Jamaica's Debt Buildup

SRAS. is less than Y P

Pre-Test Chapter 11 ed17

Strategy Document 1/03

A BRIEF HISTORY OF BRAZIL S GROWTH

Macroeconomics Machine-graded Assessment Items Module: Fiscal Policy

chapter: Aggregate Demand and Aggregate Supply Krugman/Wells 2009 Worth Publishers 1 of 58

Measuring GDP and Economic Growth

THE U.S. FISCAL GAP AND RETIREMENT SAVING

Does My State Have a Structural Deficit?

United States Government Required Supplementary Information (Unaudited) For the Years Ended September 30, 2014, and 2013

The Fiscal Policy and The Monetary Policy. Ing. Mansoor Maitah Ph.D.

Macroeconomics Instructor Miller Fiscal Policy Practice Problems

S.Y.B.COM. (SEM-III) ECONOMICS

a) Aggregate Demand (AD) and Aggregate Supply (AS) analysis

ANSWERS TO END-OF-CHAPTER QUESTIONS

PROJECTION OF THE FISCAL BALANCE AND PUBLIC DEBT ( ) - SUMMARY

Demand, Supply and Elasticity

The long-term projections of federal revenues and

Chapter 13. Aggregate Demand and Aggregate Supply Analysis

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

CHAPTER 5: MEASURING GDP AND ECONOMIC GROWTH

Chapter 10 Fiscal Policy Macroeconomics In Context (Goodwin, et al.)

Volume URL: Chapter Title: Liquidity Ratios and Cash Balances. Chapter URL:

Projections for the Portuguese economy:

Current account deficit -10. Private sector Other public* Official reserve assets

The current economic situation in Germany. Deutsche Bundesbank Monthly Report February

Government Budget and Fiscal Policy CHAPTER

A Beginner s Guide to the Stock Market

6. Economic Outlook. The International Economy. Graph 6.2 Terms of Trade Log scale, 2012/13 average = 100

002236/EU XXV.GP Eingelangt am 15/11/13

1. Explain what causes the liquidity preference money (LM) curve to shift and why.

West Bank and Gaza: Labor Market Trends, Growth and Unemployment 1

Chapter 30 Fiscal Policy, Deficits, and Debt QUESTIONS

Aggregate Demand and Aggregate Supply Ing. Mansoor Maitah Ph.D. et Ph.D.

With lectures 1-8 behind us, we now have the tools to support the discussion and implementation of economic policy.

Fiscal Policy and the National Debt

Real income (Y)

Agenda. Business Cycles. What Is a Business Cycle? What Is a Business Cycle? What is a Business Cycle? Business Cycle Facts.

Response on the financing of Employment Insurance and recent measures. Ottawa, Canada October 9,

Overview of the Norwegian Asset Accounts for Oil and Gas,

MACROECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF VARIOUS PROPOSALS TO PROVIDE $500 BILLION IN TAX RELIEF

Chapter 12 Unemployment and Inflation

The UK in 2011 is not Canada in 1996

Acceleration Introduction: Objectives: Methods:

The Legacy of Austerity in the Eurozone

Note: This feature provides supplementary analysis for the material in Part 3 of Common Sense Economics.

Answers to Text Questions and Problems. Chapter 22. Answers to Review Questions

3. a. If all money is held as currency, then the money supply is equal to the monetary base. The money supply will be $1,000.

SHORT-RUN FLUCTUATIONS. David Romer. University of California, Berkeley. First version: August 1999 This revision: January 2012

A. GDP, Economic Growth, and Business Cycles

Why is the Greek economy collapsing?

Monetary Policy Bank of Canada

HAS THE PRODUCTIVITY BOOM FINALLY ARRIVED?

U.S. Fixed Income: Potential Interest Rate Shock Scenario

Managerial Economics Prof. Trupti Mishra S.J.M. School of Management Indian Institute of Technology, Bombay. Lecture - 13 Consumer Behaviour (Contd )

7 AGGREGATE SUPPLY AND AGGREGATE DEMAND* * Chapter Key Ideas. Outline

The Keynesian Cross. A Fixed Price Level. The Simplest Keynesian-Cross Model: Autonomous Consumption Only

International Conference of Social Security Actuaries and Statisticians

CH 10 - REVIEW QUESTIONS

CHAPTER 9 Building the Aggregate Expenditures Model

Solutions to Problem Set #2 Spring, a) Units of Price of Nominal GDP Real Year Stuff Produced Stuff GDP Deflator GDP

2015 ASSESSMENT RATES

Trends in U.S. Military Spending

The IS-LM Model Ing. Mansoor Maitah Ph.D.

Analyzing the Elements of Real GDP in FRED Using Stacking

does the debt matter? comments

South African Reserve Bank. Statement of the Monetary Policy Committee. Issued by Lesetja Kganyago, Governor of the South African Reserve Bank

Macroeconomics 2301 Potential questions and study guide for exam 2. Any 6 of these questions could be on your exam!

In the news. The Global Economy Aggregate Supply & Demand. Roadmap. In the news. In the news. In the news

FRED Data Practice: U.S. deficit and debt Objectives

Domestic Activity. Graph 6.2 Terms of Trade Log scale, 2013/14 average = 100

Economic Research Division

In recent years, fiscal policy in China has been prudent. Fiscal deficits

Measured in terms of either output or employment, the United States

As the monetary aggregates have become

COMMISSION STAFF WORKING DOCUMENT. Analysis of the draft budgetary plan of ITALY. Accompanying the document COMMISSION OPINION

ECO209 MACROECONOMIC THEORY. Chapter 11

ANNEX 1 - MACROECONOMIC IMPLICATIONS FOR ITALY OF ACHIEVING COMPLIANCE WITH THE DEBT RULE UNDER TWO DIFFERENT SCENARIOS

Fiscal policy and pension expenditure in Portugal

Transcription:

What caused the Build-Up of canada s Public Debt? 1 What Caused the Build-Up of Canada s Public Debt? In Chapter 32 we discuss government debt and deficits and why these matter, not only for the conduct of macroeconomic policy but also how they affect the long-run living standards of consumers and taxpayers. In a box on page 818 we use simple algebra to derive an equation showing how the debt-to-gdp ratio changes over time. In this web-based section, we use a slightly modified version of this equation to explain the various components in the build-up of Canada s federal public debt over the past three decades. The Evolution of the Debt-to-GDP Ratio As we show in the textbook, the change in the debt-to-gdp ratio can be shown with a simple equation: d = x + (r g)d (1) where d is the debt-to-gdp ratio at the end of the previous period (usually the year), x is the primary deficit as a share of GDP during the period, r is the real interest rate, g is the growth rate of real GDP, and d is the change in the debt-to-gdp ratio during the current period. As we explain at length in Chapter 32, the primary budget deficit is the excess of program expenditures (discretionary spending) over tax revenues, and this can change for two quite different reasons. First, it can change because of a change in the government s fiscal policy a decision to change the level of program spending or the level of tax revenues. Second, it can change because the level of real GDP changes, thus influencing the government s level of tax collection or transfer payments, even in the absence of a change in fiscal policy. To separate these two distinct effects on the size of the debt-to- GDP ratio, we modify the right-hand-side of equation (1) slightly by adding and subtracting x*, the primary budget deficit when the economy is operating at its capacity level of output potential output. d = x* + (x x*) + (r g)d (2) This modified equation shows three distinct forces acting on the debt-to-gdp ratio. First, the structural component (x*) is the primary deficit when the economy is operating at potential output. Other things being equal, an increase in x* leads to an increase in the rate of debt accumulation. Second, the cyclical component is the difference between the actual primary budget deficit (x) and x*. Other things being equal, a reduction in real GDP created by a slowdown in growth will lead to an increase of x above x* and thus to an increase in the rate of debt accumulation. Third, the rate component is the difference in the real interest rate and the GDP growth rate, all multiplied by the current debt-to-gdp ratio. Other things being equal, an increase in the real interest rate or a decline in the GDP growth rate will lead to an increase in the rate of debt accumulation. To see how this decomposition is useful in the analysis of real-world government debt, we apply this equation to the Canadian federal debt beginning in 1970. These data and analysis are based on that by Ronald Kneebone and Jennifer Chung from the University of Calgary and is found in their excellent paper Where Did the Debt Come From? 1 1 See Is the Debt War Over?, edited by Christopher Ragan and William Watson, published by the Institute for Research on Public Policy, 2004.

2 What caused the Build-Up of canada s Public Debt? The Evolution of Canadian Federal Debt, 1970 2001 The application of equation (2) to actual data requires some assumptions in order to construct a measure of x*. Two different sets of assumptions or estimates are needed. First, the potential level of GDP is not directly observed and must therefore be estimated. The federal Department of Finance, the Bank of Canada, and several private forecasters provide different estimates. The various estimates are not identical, and there is some disagreement over the path of potential output during specific intervals, but there is broad agreement over the general path of potential output. Second, some assumption must be made regarding the sensitivity of the primary budget deficit to changes in the value of real GDP in other words, it is necessary to estimate the slope of the (primary) budget deficit function (recall the discussion in the textbook on pages 815 and 816). Kneebone and Chung estimate that a one-percentage-point increase in real GDP reduces the primary deficit by 0.23 percentage points of GDP. With these estimates in hand, Kneebone and Chung are able to construct a time series for x* for the Canadian federal government. Figure 1 shows the annual contributions to the change in the debt-to-gdp ratio coming from the three distinct components, each component represented by the vertical bars of different shading. The continuous line simply connects the cyclical contributions and thus gives a quick impression of the business cycle during this 30-year period. (Periods when the cyclical contributions to the debt ratio are negative are periods when real GDP exceeds potential GDP; periods when the cyclical components are positive are periods when real GDP is less than potential GDP.) FIGURE 1 Annual Contributions to the Federal Debt-to-GDP Ratio 5 4 3 Percentage Points of GDP 2 1 0 1 2 3 4 Structural Component Cyclical Component Rate Component 5 1971 1973 1975 1977 1979 1981 1983 1985 1987 1989 1991 1993 1995 1997 1999 2001

What caused the Build-Up of canada s Public Debt? 3 We begin with the cyclical component, the green vertical bars. We see that in times when the economy is operating above potential output, such as the mid-to-late 1970s and the late 1980s, the cyclical component is negative, acting to reduce the debt ratio. This is sensible since during such boom periods tax revenues tend to be high and government transfers tend to be low. In contrast, in periods when the economy is operating below potential output, such as immediately after the recessions in the early 1980s and 1990s, the cyclical component is positive, acting to increase the debt ratio. Not surprisingly, however, the cyclical component tends to cancel itself out over a period of many years; the debt-reducing years of economic booms are offset by the debtincreasing years of economic slumps. Next consider the rate component, as shown by the blue vertical bars. During the 1970s real interest rates were low (negative in the mid 1970s!) and GDP growth rates were relatively high; the result was that the rate component was negative, acting to reduce the debt-to-gdp ratio. Indeed, the magnitude of this separate component was significant, especially in the early 1970s and early 1980s. From the mid 1980s to the mid 1990s, however, real interest rates had increased and GDP growth rates had declined (both partly because of the disinflation policies in place at the beginning of each decade). The result was that the rate component turned positive, and sharply so in the early 1990s. Only by the late 1990s had the rate component fallen from its very high levels at the beginning of that decade. Now consider the structural component, clearly the largest contributor to changes in the debt-to-gdp ratio over the three decades shown in the figure. The vertical red bars show the annual contributions to the debt ratio due to the structural component the decisions by the federal government to change program spending or total tax revenues. As is clear in the figure, the structural contribution to the debt ratio rises from below 1 percentage point in the early 1970s to between 3 and 4 percentage points from the mid 1970s to the mid 1980s. Only in the mid 1980s, under the Conservative government of Brian Mulroney, does the structural component begin to fall. Only under the subsequent Liberal government of Jean Chrétien is there success in turning this component around into significant negative values indicating that the structural component is then reducing the debt-to-gdp ratio. Figure 1 shows the annual contributions to the debt-to-gdp ratio but does not add them up to show the cumulative effect over time. This cumulative effect is shown in Figure 2, where the three continuous lines show the cumulative effect of the three separate components, whereas the vertical bars show the path of the overall federal debt-to- GDP ratio. In other words, the height of the vertical bar in any period (the debt ratio in that year) is given by the sum of the three values as shown by the three lines. Note that in 1970 the federal debt-to-gdp ratio was very close to 20 percent. It is important to keep in mind that the values shown in Figure 2 are relative to that base of 20 percent. Thus, in 1988, for example, the height of the vertical bar is 30 percent, indicating that the cumulative effect of the three components since 1970 has been to increase the debt ratio by 30 percentage points to a total of 50 percent of GDP. The structural component begins a substantial increase in the mid 1970s, as government tax revenues fall further and further behind growing program spending. But during this same period, the effect on the overall debt is muted because the rate component is negative (real interest rates below the growth rate of real GDP). Thus the structural increases in the government s debt ratio were largely hidden by the favourable rate component at the time. The problem, however, is that the rate component can change quickly, whereas the structural component, being much more entrenched in established policies, is harder to change. The early 1980s witnessed precisely this kind of turnaround in the rate component. As real growth rates dropped and real interest rates increased, the negative contribu-

4 What caused the Build-Up of canada s Public Debt? FIGURE 2 Cumulative Contributions to the Federal Debt-to-GDP Ratio 50 40 30 Net Debt Structural Component Cyclical Component Rate Component Percentage Points of GDP 20 10 0 10 20 1970 1972 1974 1976 1978 1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 tions from the rate components turned into large positive contributions (see Figure 1). In Figure 2 we therefore see the cumulative rate component start to increase. But there is no significant change in the structural component during this period, so the overall debt ratio continues climbing, reaching 30 percentage points by 1989 (above the base of 20 percent from 1970). And then, in the early 1990s, the rate component rises very sharply and, even though the structural component is roughly stable, the overall debt ratio climbs even higher, to about 48 percent in 1996 (above the 20 percent base from 1970). At this point, many economic observers viewed Canada as being against the debt wall. Following the dramatic deficit-reduction policies instituted by the Liberal government of Jean Chrétien, especially following the 1995 federal budget, the structural component continued its sharp downward trajectory (which had begun under the Conservatives in the late 1980s). Despite the tendency of the rate component to remain at significant levels throughout the 1990s, the combined effect was to sharply reduce the overall debt ratio, from its high of 68 percent in 1996 to about 49 percent in 2001, and it continued to fall to about 44 percent by the time of the 2004 federal budget. Some Simple Lessons? The first lesson that can be drawn from this exercise is that the three distinct components all influence the overall debt ratio but their changes are caused by different things. A full

What caused the Build-Up of canada s Public Debt? 5 understanding of where the debt comes from must therefore recognize this distinction and understand the movements of the three separate components. The government has the most direct influence on the structural component its spending and taxing policies determine whether the primary budget will be in deficit or surplus when the economy is operating at potential output. In contrast, the government only has an indirect influence on the cyclical and rate components. Changes in the government s fiscal (and monetary) policies will lead to changes in the growth rate of real GDP and thus to changes in the cyclical component, but these effects may be small relative to the other, non-policy sources of economic fluctuation. In addition, the government s policies will surely have an influence on real interest rates and GDP growth rates, at least in the short run, but other factors are also very important in driving changes in the rate component. Nonetheless, governments must recognize that their policies will have some effect on both the cyclical and rate components. The second lesson that should be drawn from this exercise is for policy analysis; the rate component is prone to sudden and significant swings, whereas the structural component, being based on policies that tend to be entrenched and with considerable political inertia, is difficult to change over short periods of time. As Figure 2 shows so clearly, the increase in the overall debt ratio was very modest until 1983, and until then there was no clear debt problem. But in fact the structural component at that time had increased markedly from a decade earlier but was being hidden by a favourable rate component. When the rate component turned around suddenly in the early 1980s, and then sharply increased again in the early 1990s, the effect on the overall debt ratio was dramatic. But it took considerable time and effort and political consensus to reduce the structural component, which did not begin its significant fall until the late 1980s. By that time the overall federal debt was well on its way to its high of 68 percent of GDP. If this exercise in debt decomposition had been done in the late 1970s or 1980s, the government of the day may have seen the truth that the un-alarming overall debt picture of the mid 1970s or even early 1980s was based largely on a very favourable rate component hiding an unfavourable structural component. Reasoning that the rate component might change quickly, a strong case could have been made at that time to reduce the large and growing structural component. There would naturally have been some political opposition to such a change (as there usually is to spending cuts and/or tax increases), but at least it would be clear from the overall decomposition exercise that the structural component was adding significantly to overall debt.