The Analysis of Markets

Similar documents
Economic Efficiency, Government Price Setting, and Taxes

Demand, Supply and Elasticity

Gov t Intervention: Price Floors & Price Ceilings / Taxes & Subsidies

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

Review Question - Chapter 7. MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

Quantity Tax Incidence Subsidy Welfare Effects Case Study. Equilibrium Chapter 16

COMPETITIVE MARKETS: 10APPLICATIONS

SUPPLY AND DEMAND : HOW MARKETS WORK

Chapter 6 Supply, Demand, and Government Policies

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

a) Find the equilibrium price and quantity when the economy is closed.

CHAPTER 10 MARKET POWER: MONOPOLY AND MONOPSONY

Quantity of trips supplied (millions)

CHAPTER 2 THE BASICS OF SUPPLY AND DEMAND

Q D = (5)(5) = 75 Q S = 50 + (5)(5) = 75.

Chapter 27: Taxation. 27.1: Introduction. 27.2: The Two Prices with a Tax. 27.2: The Pre-Tax Position

PAGE 1. Econ Test 2 Fall 2003 Dr. Rupp. Multiple Choice. 1. The price elasticity of demand measures

Lab 17: Consumer and Producer Surplus

Demand, Supply, and Market Equilibrium

Final Exam 15 December 2006

Principle of Microeconomics Econ chapter 6

Supplement Unit 1. Demand, Supply, and Adjustments to Dynamic Change

MICROECONOMIC PRINCIPLES SPRING 2001 MIDTERM ONE -- Answers. February 16, Table One Labor Hours Needed to Make 1 Pounds Produced in 20 Hours

Chapter 3. The Concept of Elasticity and Consumer and Producer Surplus. Chapter Objectives. Chapter Outline

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

Econ 202 Exam 2 Practice Problems

I. Introduction to Taxation

A. a change in demand. B. a change in quantity demanded. C. a change in quantity supplied. D. unit elasticity. E. a change in average variable cost.

Chapter 03 The Concept of Elasticity and Consumer and

chapter >> Consumer and Producer Surplus Section 4: Applying Consumer and Producer Surplus: The Efficiency Costs of a Tax

Chapter. Perfect Competition CHAPTER IN PERSPECTIVE

Midterm Exam - Answers. November 3, 2005

Chapter 3 Market Demand, Supply, and Elasticity

14 : Elasticity of Supply

3) The excess supply curve of a product we (H) import from foreign countries (F) increases as B) excess demand of country F increases.

Module 49 Consumer and Producer Surplus

4. According to the graph, assume that Cliff and Paul were both producing wheat and corn, and each were dividing their time equally between the two. T

Monopoly. E. Glen Weyl. Lecture 8 Price Theory and Market Design Fall University of Chicago

MEASURING GDP AND ECONOMIC GROWTH*

Chapter 9 1. Use Exhibit 3 to answer the following questions.

Big Concepts. Measuring U.S. GDP. The Expenditure Approach. Economics 202 Principles Of Macroeconomics

Math 1526 Consumer and Producer Surplus

Principles of Economics: Micro: Exam #2: Chapters 1-10 Page 1 of 9

How to Study for Class 4: The Determinants of Demand and Supply

ECON 103, ANSWERS TO HOME WORK ASSIGNMENTS

Learning Objectives. After reading Chapter 11 and working the problems for Chapter 11 in the textbook and in this Workbook, you should be able to:

Midterm Exam #2. ECON 101, Section 2 summer 2004 Ying Gao. 1. Print your name and student ID number at the top of this cover sheet.

The formula to measure the rice elastici coefficient is Percentage change in quantity demanded E= Percentage change in price

Elasticity: The Responsiveness of Demand and Supply

Chapter 7 Monopoly, Oligopoly and Strategy

Elasticity and Its Application

Workers Total Output Average Marginal

Rutgers University Economics 102: Introductory Microeconomics Professor Altshuler Fall 2003

CLASSIFICATION OF MARKETS Perfectly competitive, various types of imperfect competition

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question on the accompanying scantron.

Chapter 8 Application: The Costs of Taxation

Economics 181: International Trade Homework # 4 Solutions

4. Answer c. The index of nominal wages for 1996 is the nominal wage in 1996 expressed as a percentage of the nominal wage in the base year.

MICROECONOMICS II PROBLEM SET III: MONOPOLY

Market Failure. EC4004 Lecture 9

Chapter 14 Monopoly Monopoly and How It Arises

Chapter 5 Efficiency and Equity Test Bank MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

Macroeconomics: GDP, GDP Deflator, CPI, & Inflation

Chapter 6 Competitive Markets

6. In general, over longer periods, demand tends to become (A) More elastic (B) Perfectly elastic (C) Perfectly inelastic (D) Less elastic

LECTURE NOTES ON MACROECONOMIC PRINCIPLES

Recitation #4 Week 02/02/2009 to 02/08/2009 Chapter 5: The Market Strikes Back

Topic 4: Different approaches to GDP

Chapter 14 Monopoly Monopoly and How It Arises

Maximising Consumer Surplus and Producer Surplus: How do airlines and mobile companies do it?

Selected Homework Answers from Chapter 3

How To Calculate Profit Maximization In A Competitive Dairy Firm

Name Eco200: Practice Test 2 Covering Chapters 10 through 15

We will study the extreme case of perfect competition, where firms are price takers.

CEVAPLAR. Solution: a. Given the competitive nature of the industry, Conigan should equate P to MC.

Reference: Gregory Mankiw s Principles of Macroeconomics, 2 nd edition, Chapters 10 and 11. Gross Domestic Product

Pre-Test Chapter 18 ed17

Chapter 3 Market Demand, Supply and Elasticity

DEMAND AND SUPPLY CURVES: CONSUMER & PRODUCER SURPLUS by Kenneth Matziorinis

Learning Objectives. Chapter 6. Market Structures. Market Structures (cont.) The Two Extremes: Perfect Competition and Pure Monopoly

ECON 1100 Global Economics (Fall 2013) Surplus, Efficiency, and Deadweight Loss

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

Econ 201 Exam 1 F2002 Professor Phil Miller Name: Student Number:

Elasticity. Ratio of Percentage Changes. Elasticity and Its Application. Price Elasticity of Demand. Price Elasticity of Demand. Elasticity...

CHAPTER 4 Elasticity, Consumer Surplus, and Producer Surplus

Final Exam Microeconomics Fall 2009 Key

Equilibrium of a firm under perfect competition in the short-run. A firm is under equilibrium at that point where it maximizes its profits.

Monopolistic Competition

4 THE MARKET FORCES OF SUPPLY AND DEMAND

Econ 201 Final Exam. Douglas, Fall 2007 Version A Special Codes PLEDGE: I have neither given nor received unauthorized help on this exam.

N. Gregory Mankiw Principles of Economics. Chapter 15. MONOPOLY

THE UNIVERSITY OF AUCKLAND

Web Supplement to Chapter 2

Topic 2: Fossil Fuel Supply and Demand: Effect of Subsidies and Taxation. () Global Energy Issues, Industries and Markets 1 / 53

Supply and Demand Fundamental tool of economic analysis Used to discuss unemployment, value of $, protection of the environment, etc.

EC2105, Professor Laury EXAM 2, FORM A (3/13/02)

Chapter 6: Measuring the Price Level and Inflation. The Price Level and Inflation. Connection between money and prices. Index Numbers in General

Households Wages, profit, interest, rent = $750. Factor markets. Wages, profit, interest, rent = $750

DEMAND AND SUPPLY. Chapter. Markets and Prices. Demand. C) the price of a hot dog minus the price of a hamburger.

The Mathematics 11 Competency Test Percent Increase or Decrease

Transcription:

The Analysis of Markets

Evaluating the Gains and Losses from Government Policies Consumer and Producer Surplus In this chapter, we return to supply demand analysis and show how it can be applied to a wide variety of economic problems problems that might concern a consumer faced with a purchasing decision, a firm faced with a long-range planning problem, or a government agency that has to design a policy and evaluate its likely impact. We begin by showing how consumer and producer surplus can be used to study the welfare effects of a government policy in other words, who gains and who loses from the policy, and by how much. We also use consumer and producer surplus to demonstrate the efficiency of a competitive market. You will see how to calculate the response of markets to changing economic conditions or government policies and to evaluate the resulting gains and losses to consumers and producers.

Review of Consumer and Producer Surplus CONSUMER AND PRODUCER SURPLUS Consumer A would pay $10 for a good whose market price is $5 and therefore enjoys a benefit of $5. Consumer B enjoys a benefit of $2, and Consumer C, who values the good at exactly the market price, enjoys no benefit. Consumer surplus, which measures the total benefit to all consumers, is the yellow-shaded area between the demand curve and the market price.

CONSUMER AND PRODUCER SURPLUS Producer surplus measures the total profits of producers, plus rents to factor inputs. It is the benefit that lower-cost producers enjoy by selling at the market price, shown by the greenshaded area between the supply curve and the market price. Together, consumer and producer surplus measure the welfare benefit of a competitive market.

Application of Consumer and Producer Surplus welfare effects Gains and losses to consumers and producers. deadweight loss Net loss of total (consumer plus producer) surplus. CHANGE IN CONSUMER AND PRODUCER SURPLUS FROM PRICE CONTROLS The price of a good has been regulated to be no higher than P max, which is below the market-clearing price P 0. The gain to consumers is the difference between rectangle A and triangle B. The loss to producers is the sum of rectangle A and triangle C. Triangles B and C together measure the deadweight loss from price controls.

Application of Consumer and Producer Surplus EFFECT OF PRICE CONTROLS WHEN DEMAND IS INELASTIC If demand is sufficiently inelastic, triangle B can be larger than rectangle A. In this case, consumers suffer a net loss from price controls.

PRICE CONTROLS AND NATURAL GAS SHORTAGES Supply: Q S = 15.90 + 0.72PG + 0.05P O Demand: Q D = 0.02 1.8PG + 0.69P O EFFECTS OF NATURAL GAS PRICE CONTROLS The market-clearing price of natural gas was $6.40 per mcf, and the (hypothetical) maximum allowable price is $3.00. A shortage of 29.1 20.6 = 8.5 Tcf results. The gain to consumers is rectangle A minus triangle B, and the loss to producers is rectangle A plus triangle C. The deadweight loss is the sum of triangles B plus C.

PRICE CONTROLS AND NATURAL GAS SHORTAGES EFFECTS OF NATURAL GAS PRICE CONTROLS A = (20.6 billion mcf ) ($3.40/mcf) = $70.04 billion B = (1/2) x (2.4 billion mcf) ($1.33/mcf ) = $1.60 billion C = (1/2) x (2.4 billion mcf ) ($3.40/mcf ) = $4.08 billion The annual change in consumer surplus that would result from these hypothetical price controls would therefore be A B = 70.04 1.60 = $68.44 billion. The change in producer surplus would be A C = 70.04 4.08 = $74.12 billion. And finally, the annual deadweight loss. would be B C = 1.60 4.08 = $5.68 billion.

Review of Consumer and Producer Surplus WELFARE LOSS WHEN PRICE IS HELD ABOVE MARKET-CLEARING LEVEL When price is regulated to be no lower than P 2, only Q 3 will be demanded. If Q 3 is produced, the deadweight loss is given by triangles B and C. At price P 2, producers would like to produce more than Q 3. If they do, the deadweight loss will be even larger.

THE MARKET FOR HUMAN KIDNEYS Even at a price of zero (the effective price under the law), donors supply about 16,000 kidneys per year. It has been estimated that 8000 more kidneys would be supplied if the price were $20,000. We can fit a linear supply curve to this data i.e., a supply curve of the form Q = a + bp. When P = 0, Q = 16,000, so a = 16,000. If P = $20,000, Q = 24,000, so b = (24,000 16,000)/20,000 = 0.4. Thus the supply curve is Supply: Q S = 16,000 + 0.4P Note that at a price of $20,000, the elasticity of supply is 0.33. It is expected that at a price of $20,000, the number of kidneys demanded would be 24,000 per year. Like supply, demand is relatively price inelastic; a reasonable estimate for the price elasticity of demand at the $20,000 price is 0.33. This implies the following linear demand curve: Demand: Q D = 32,000 0.4P

THE MARKET FOR HUMAN KIDNEYS THE MARKET FOR KIDNEYS AND THE EFFECT OF THE NATIONAL ORGAN TRANSPLANTATION ACT The market-clearing price is $20,000; at this price, about 24,000 kidneys per year would be supplied. The law effectively makes the price zero. About 16,000 kidneys per year are still donated; this constrained supply is shown as S. The loss to suppliers is given by rectangle A and triangle C. If consumers received kidneys at no cost, their gain would be given by rectangle A less triangle B. Economics, the dismal science, shows us that human organs have economic value that cannot be ignored, and prohibiting their sale imposes a cost on society that must be weighed against the benefits.

Minimum Prices PRICE MINIMUM Price is regulated to be no lower than P min. Producers would like to supply Q 2, but consumers will buy only Q 3. If producers indeed produce Q 2, the amount Q 2 Q 3 will go unsold and the change in producer surplus will be A C D. In this case, producers as a group may be worse off. The total change in consumer surplus is: The total change in producer surplus is: CS = A B PS = A C D

THE MINIMUM WAGE Although the market-clearing wage is w 0, firms are not allowed to pay less than w min. This results in unemployment of an amount L 2 L 1 and a deadweight loss given by triangles B and C.

Price Supports and Production Quotas Price Supports price support Price set by government above free-market level and maintained by governmental purchases of excess supply. PRICE SUPPORTS To maintain a price P s above the market-clearing price P 0, the government buys a quantity Q g. The gain to producers is A + B + D. The loss to consumers is A + B. The cost to the government is the speckled rectangle, the area of which is P s (Q 2 Q 1 ).

Let s examine the resulting gains and losses to consumers, producers, and the government CONSUMERS Some consumers pay a higher price, while others no longer buy the good. PRODUCERS CS = A B Producers are now selling a larger quantity Q 2 instead of Q 0, and at a higher price P s. THE GOVERNMENT PS = +A + B + D The cost to the government (which is ultimately a cost to consumers) is The total change in welfare is (Q 2 Q 1 )P S CS + PS Cost to Govt. = D (Q 2 Q 1 )P S

Production Quotas SUPPLY RESTRICTIONS To maintain a price P s above the market-clearing price P 0, the government can restrict supply to Q 1, either by imposing production quotas (as with taxicab medallions) or by giving producers a financial incentive to reduce output (as with acreage limitations in agriculture). For an incentive to work, it must be at least as large as B + C + D, which would be the additional profit earned by planting, given the higher price P s. The cost to the government is therefore at least B + C + D. Q 1

INCENTIVE PROGRAMS In U.S. agricultural policy, output is reduced by incentives rather than by outright quotas. Acreage limitation programs give farmers financial incentives to leave some of their acreage idle. Figure 9.11 also shows the welfare effects of reducing supply in this way. As with direct production quotas, the change in consumer surplus is CS = A B Farmers receive a higher price, produce less, and receive an incentive to reduce production. Thus, the change in producer surplus is now PS = A C + Payments for not producing The cost to the government is at least B + C + D, and the total change in producer surplus is PS = A C + B + C + D = A + B + D An acreage-limitation program is more costly to society than simply handing the farmers money. The total change in welfare Welfare = A B + A + B + D B C D = B C

SUPPORTING THE PRICE OF WHEAT 1981 Supply: Q S = 1800 + 240P 1981 Demand: Q D = 3550 266P THE WHEAT MARKET IN 1981 To increase the price to $3.70, the government must buy a quantity of wheat Q g. By buying 122 million bushels of wheat, the government increased the market-clearing price from $3.46 per bushel to $3.70. 1981 Total demand: Q D = 3550 266P + Q g Q g = 506P 1750 Q g = (506)(3.70) 1750 = 122 million bushels Loss to consumers = A B = $624 million Cost to the government = $3.70 122 million = $451.4 million Total cost of the program = $624 million + $451.4 million = $1075 million Gain to producers = A + B + C = $638 million

WHY CAN T I FIND A TAXI? The city of New York limits the number of taxis by requiring each taxi to have a medallion (essentially a permit), and then limiting the number of medallions. In 2011 there were 13,150 medallions in New York roughly the same number as in 1937. Why not just issue more medallions? The reason is simple. Doing so would incur the wrath of the current owners of medallions. Medallions can be bought and sold by the companies that own them. In 1937, there were plenty of medallions to go around, so they had little value. By 1947, the value of a medallion had increased to $2,500, by 1980 to $55,000, and by 2011 to $880,000. That s right because New York City won t issue more medallions, the value of a taxi medallion is approaching $1 million! But of course that value would drop sharply if the city starting issuing more medallions. So the New York taxi companies that collectively own the 13,150 available medallions have done everything possible to prevent the city from issuing any more and have succeeded in their efforts. If the city were to issue another 7,000 medallions for a total of about 20,000, demand and supply would equilibrate at a price of about $350,000 per medallion still a lot, but just enough to lease cabs, run a taxi business, and still make a profit.

FIGURE 9.13 TAXI MEDALLIONS IN NEW YORK CITY The demand curve D shows the quantity of medallions demanded by taxi companies as a function of the price of a medallion. The supply curve S shows the number of medallions that would be sold by current owners as a function of price. New York limits the quantity to 13,150, so the supply curve becomes vertical and intersects demand at $880,000, the market price of a medallion in 2011. WHY CAN T I FIND A TAXI?

Import Quotas and Tariffs import quota Limit on the quantity of a good that can be imported. tariff Tax on an imported good. IMPORT TARIFF OR QUOTA THAT ELIMINATES IMPORTS In a free market, the domestic price equals the world price P w. A total Q d is consumed, of which Q s is supplied domestically and the rest imported. When imports are eliminated, the price is increased to P 0. The gain to producers is trapezoid A. The loss to consumers is A + B + C, so the deadweight loss is B + C.

IMPORT TARIFF OR QUOTA (GENERAL CASE) When imports are reduced, the domestic price is increased from P w to P*. This can be achieved by a quota, or by a tariff T = P* P w. Trapezoid A is again the gain to domestic producers. The loss to consumers is A + B + C + D. If a tariff is used, the government gains D, the revenue from the tariff. The net domestic loss is B + C. If a quota is used instead, rectangle D becomes part of the profits of foreign producers, and the net domestic loss is B + C + D.

THE SUGAR QUOTA In recent years, the world price of sugar has been between 10 and 28 cents per pound, while the U.S. price has been 30 to 40 cents per pound. Why? By restricting imports, the U.S. government protects the $4 billion domestic sugar industry, which would virtually be put out of business if it had to compete with low-cost foreign producers. This policy has been good for U.S. sugar producers, but bad for consumers. U.S. production: U.S. consumption: U.S. price: World price 15.9 billion pounds 22.8 billion pounds 36 cents per pound 24 cents per pound U.S. supply: Q S = 7.95 + 0.66P U.S. demand: Q D = 29.73 0.19P At the 24-cent world price, U.S. production would have been only about 7.9 billion pounds and U.S. consumption about 25.2 billion pounds, of which 25.2 7.9 = 17.3 billion pounds would have been imported. But fortunately for U.S. producers, imports were limited to only 6.9 billion pounds.

THE SUGAR QUOTA SUGAR QUOTA IN 2010 At the world price of 24 cents per pound, about 25.2 billion pounds of sugar would have been consumed of which all but 7.9 billion pounds would have been imported. Restricting imports to 6.9 billion pounds caused the U.S. price to go up by 12 cents. The cost to consumers, A + B + C + D, was about $2.9 billion. The gain to domestic producers was trapezoid A, about $1.4 billion. Rectangle D, $836 million, was a gain to those foreign producers who obtained quota allotments. Triangles B and C represent the deadweight loss of about $614 million.

The Impact of a Tax or Subsidy THE EFFECTS OF A SPECIFIC TAX specific tax Tax of a certain amount of money per unit sold. INCIDENCE OF A TAX P b is the price (including the tax) paid by buyers. P s is the price that sellers receive, less the tax. Here the burden of the tax is split evenly between buyers and sellers. Buyers lose A + B. Sellers lose D + C. The government earns A + D in revenue. The deadweight loss is B + C. Market clearing requires four conditions to be satisfied after the tax is in place: Q D = Q D (P b ) Q S = Q S (P s ) Q D = Q S P b P s = t (9.1a) (9.1b) (9.1c) (9.1d)

IMPACT OF A TAX DEPENDS ON ELASTICITIES OF SUPPLY AND DEMAND (a) If demand is very inelastic relative to supply, the burden of the tax falls mostly on buyers. (b) If demand is very elastic relative to supply, it falls mostly on sellers. By using the following pass-through formula, we can calculate the percentage of the tax that is passed through to consumers: Pass-through fraction = E s /(E s E d )

The Effects of a Subsidy subsidy Payment reducing the buyer s price below the seller s price; i.e., a negative tax. SUBSIDY A subsidy can be thought of as a negative tax. Like a tax, the benefit of a subsidy is split between buyers and sellers, depending on the relative elasticities of supply and demand. Conditions needed for the market to clear with a subsidy: Q D = Q D (P b ) Q S = Q S (P s ) Q D = Q S P s P b = s (9.2a) (9.2b) (9.3c) (9.4d)

A TAX ON GASOLINE Q D = 150 25P b Q S = 60 + 20P s Q D = Q S P b P s = 1.00 (Demand) (Supply) (Supply must equal demand) (Government must receive $1.00/gallon) 150 25P b = 60 + 20Ps P b = P s + 1.00 150 25P b = 60 + 20P s 20P s + 25P s = 150 25 60 45P s = 65, or P s = 1.44 Q D = 150 (25)(2.44) = 150 61, or Q = 89 bg/yr Annual revenue from the tax tq = (1.00)(89) = $89 billion per year Deadweight loss: (1/2) ($1.00/gallon) (11 billion gallons/year = $5.5 billion per year

A TAX ON GASOLINE IMPACT OF $1 GASOLINE TAX The price of gasoline at the pump increases from $2.00 per gallon to $2.44, and the quantity sold falls from 100 to 89 bg/yr. Annual revenue from the tax is (1.00)(89) = $89 billion (areas A + D). The two triangles show the deadweight loss of $5.5 billion per year.