ECO364 - International Trade



Similar documents
Chapter 4. Specific Factors and Income Distribution

ECO 352 Spring 2010 No. 7 Feb. 23 SECTOR-SPECIFIC CAPITAL (RICARDO-VINER) MODEL

Chapter 3. Labor Productivity and Comparative Advantage: The Ricardian Model

KOÇ UNIVERSITY ECON INTERNATIONAL TRADE

Chapter 4 Specific Factors and Income Distribution

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

Natural Resources and International Trade

Chapter 4 Specific Factors and Income Distribution

TRADE WITH SCALE ECONOMIES AND IMPERFECT COMPETITION (CONT'D)

CONSUMER PREFERENCES THE THEORY OF THE CONSUMER

Homework #5: Answers. b. How can land rents as well as total wages be shown in such a diagram?

Production Possibilities Frontier, Economic Growth, and Gains from Trade

Knowledge Enrichment Seminar for Senior Secondary Economics Curriculum. Macroeconomics Series (3): Extension of trade theory

International Trade Policy ECON 4633 Prof. Javier Reyes. Test #1

Trade and Resources: The Heckscher-Ohlin Model. Professor Ralph Ossa International Commercial Policy

Professor H.J. Schuetze Economics 370

The Specific-Factors Model: HO Model in the Short Run

Problem Set #5-Key. Economics 305-Intermediate Microeconomic Theory

How To Find Out How To Balance The Two-Country Economy

Long Run Economic Growth Agenda. Long-run Economic Growth. Long-run Growth Model. Long-run Economic Growth. Determinants of Long-run Growth

PPF's of Germany and France

Protection and Real Wages

The Economic Problem: Scarcity and Choice. What is Production?

The level of price and inflation Real GDP: the values of goods and services measured using a constant set of prices

Table of Contents MICRO ECONOMICS

REVIEW OF MICROECONOMICS

Notes on indifference curve analysis of the choice between leisure and labor, and the deadweight loss of taxation. Jon Bakija

(First 6 problems from Caves, Frankel and Jones, 1990)

The Standard Trade Model

EC2105, Professor Laury EXAM 2, FORM A (3/13/02)

Market for cream: P 1 P 2 D 1 D 2 Q 2 Q 1. Individual firm: W Market for labor: W, S MRP w 1 w 2 D 1 D 1 D 2 D 2

MICROECONOMICS AND POLICY ANALYSIS - U8213 Professor Rajeev H. Dehejia Class Notes - Spring 2001

Answers to Text Questions and Problems. Chapter 22. Answers to Review Questions

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

Managerial Economics Prof. Trupti Mishra S.J.M. School of Management Indian Institute of Technology, Bombay. Lecture - 13 Consumer Behaviour (Contd )

Chapter 21: The Discounted Utility Model

University of Lethbridge Department of Economics ECON 1012 Introduction to Macroeconomics Instructor: Michael G. Lanyi

Theoretical Tools of Public Economics. Part-2

Chapter 6 Economic Growth

Chapter 7. External Economies of Scale and the International Location of Production. Copyright 2012 Pearson Education. All rights reserved.

Solution to Individual homework 2 Revised: November 22, 2011

Problem Set #3 Answer Key

Problems: Table 1: Quilt Dress Quilts Dresses Helen Carolyn

ANSWERS TO END-OF-CHAPTER QUESTIONS

TRADE AND INVESTMENT IN THE NATIONAL ACCOUNTS This text accompanies the material covered in class.

Where are we? To do today: finish the derivation of the demand curve using indifference curves. Go on then to chapter Production and Cost

INTRODUCTORY MICROECONOMICS

Lectures, 2 ECONOMIES OF SCALE

8. Average product reaches a maximum when labor equals A) 100 B) 200 C) 300 D) 400

The Central Idea CHAPTER 1 CHAPTER OVERVIEW CHAPTER REVIEW

Indifference Curves: An Example (pp ) 2005 Pearson Education, Inc.

Chapter 3 Consumer Behavior

13. If Y = AK 0.5 L 0.5 and A, K, and L are all 100, the marginal product of capital is: A) 50. B) 100. C) 200. D) 1,000.

These are some practice questions for CHAPTER 23. Each question should have a single answer. But be careful. There may be errors in the answer key!

ECO 745: Theory of International Economics. Jack Rossbach August 26, Week 1

MONEY, INTEREST, REAL GDP, AND THE PRICE LEVEL*

Advanced International Economics Prof. Yamin Ahmad ECON 758

Midterm Exam - Answers. November 3, 2005

MERSİN UNIVERSITY FACULTY OF ECONOMICS AND ADMINISTRATIVE SCİENCES DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS MICROECONOMICS MIDTERM EXAM DATE

Chapter 7: The Costs of Production QUESTIONS FOR REVIEW

Model Building and Gains from Trade

1. Briefly explain what an indifference curve is and how it can be graphically derived.

Sample Midterm Solutions

ECON 103, ANSWERS TO HOME WORK ASSIGNMENTS

Lecture 2. Marginal Functions, Average Functions, Elasticity, the Marginal Principle, and Constrained Optimization

Chapter 13 International Trade: Does it Jeopardize American Jobs

Q D = (5)(5) = 75 Q S = 50 + (5)(5) = 75.

Study Questions for Chapter 9 (Answer Sheet)

In following this handout, sketch appropriate graphs in the space provided.

Principles of Economics

CHAPTER 4 Consumer Choice

Economics 181: International Trade Homework # 4 Solutions

CHAPTER 7: AGGREGATE DEMAND AND AGGREGATE SUPPLY

13 EXPENDITURE MULTIPLIERS: THE KEYNESIAN MODEL* Chapter. Key Concepts

Lecture 1: The intertemporal approach to the current account

The Point-Slope Form

How To Calculate Profit Maximization In A Competitive Dairy Firm

Practice Problems on Current Account

The Short-Run Macro Model. The Short-Run Macro Model. The Short-Run Macro Model

PART A: For each worker, determine that worker's marginal product of labor.

ECON 3312 Macroeconomics Exam 3 Fall Name MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

4. Answer c. The index of nominal wages for 1996 is the nominal wage in 1996 expressed as a percentage of the nominal wage in the base year.

Why is Insurance Good? An Example Jon Bakija, Williams College (Revised October 2013)

ECON 312: Oligopolisitic Competition 1. Industrial Organization Oligopolistic Competition

Who gains and who loses from an import tariff? An export tax? (Assume world prices are fixed).

Chapter 04 Firm Production, Cost, and Revenue

. In this case the leakage effect of tax increases is mitigated because some of the reduction in disposable income would have otherwise been saved.

Final. 1. (2 pts) What is the expected effect on the real demand for money of an increase in the nominal interest rate? How to explain this effect?

Agenda. Productivity, Output, and Employment, Part 1. The Production Function. The Production Function. The Production Function. The Demand for Labor

An increase in the number of students attending college. shifts to the left. An increase in the wage rate of refinery workers.

Chapter 6 Supply of Labor to the Economy: The Decision to Work

Chapter 6: Pure Exchange

19 : Theory of Production

Midterm Exam #1 - Answers

Economics. Interdependence and the Gains from Trade CHAPTER. N. Gregory Mankiw. Principles of. Seventh Edition. Wojciech Gerson ( )

11 PERFECT COMPETITION. Chapter. Competition

Practiced Questions. Chapter 20

Answers to Text Questions and Problems in Chapter 8

Transcription:

ECO364 - International Trade Chapter 2 - Ricardo Christian Dippel University of Toronto Summer 2009 Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 1 / 73

: The Ricardian Model Why do countries specialize in different commodities/goods? Is trade a good thing? Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 2 / 73

The Ricardian Model: Definitions start with: Unit Labor Requirement: the amount of labor required to increase output by one unit. aj is the amount of labor needed to produce one unit of good j. With one factor (labor), 1/a j is the marginal product of labor. Arithmetically, if Y = F (L), then the unit labor requirement is 1 MPL = 1 Y L = L Y Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 3 / 73

The Ricardian Model: Motivating Example Suppose that Canada and China each have 100 workers and technology manifested by the following unit labor requirements: Table: Unit Labor Requirements Country Textiles Computers Canada 10 5 China 5 10 Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 4 / 73

The Ricardian Model: Motivating Example Suppose that each country divides its labor force in half so that there are 50 workers in each sector... Table: Output Country Textiles Computers Canada 5 10 China 10 5 World 15 15 Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 5 / 73

Examine two other possibilities. 1. Canada specializes in computers and China in textiles. 2. Canada specializes in textiles and China in computers. Canada: C, China: T Canada: T, China: C Country C T C T Canada 20 0 0 10 China 0 20 10 0 World 20 20 10 10 Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 6 / 73

If countries specialize in the right sector, world output can increase. But how do we know what the right sector is? Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 7 / 73

The Ricardian Model: Definitions Constant Returns to Scale (CRS): If one increases all inputs by some proportion, output increases by the same proportion. y=ouput and l= labor. y = f (l) is CRS if y = f (γl) = γf (l) where γ > 0. y = l is a CRS production function. y = l 0.4, y = l 1.1, and y = l + 5 are all not CRS production functions. Homothetic Preferences: The form of the utility function does not depend on income (linear Engels Curves). Autarky: When economies are closed and do not trade at all. Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 8 / 73

The Ricardian Model: Assumptions Two countries, two goods, one factor (labor), Labor is immobile across countries and mobile across sectors, Constant returns to scale (CRS) production, Identical and homothetic preferences, Perfect Competition (all agents are price takers). Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 9 / 73

The Ricardian Model: Opportunity Costs Opportunity costs (OC) formalize the tradeoffs implicit in the unit labor requirements. Recall that an opportunity cost is the cost associated with forgoing one s next best option. The OC of production turns out to be the ratio of unit labor requirements. Table: Unit Labor Requirements Country Textiles Computers Canada 10 5 China 5 10 Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 10 / 73

10 Canadian workers needed to produce 1 unit of textile and 5 needed to produce a computer. Consequently, the opportunity cost of producing a computer in Canada is the 0.5 of a textile that is forgone. 5 Chinese workers needed to produce one unit of textiles and 10 needed to produce a computer. Consequently, the opportunity cost of producing a computer in China is the 2 textiles that are forgone. Because the opportunity cost of producing a computer is lower in Canada than China, Canada has a comparative advantage in computers and China possesses a comparative advantage in textiles. Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 11 / 73

An absolute advantage is when a country has a lower unit labor requirement than another country for a given good. Absolute advantage involves comparing unit labor requirements for a good across countries. Comparative advantage involves comparing unit labor requirements across countries and goods. This distinction is at the heart of Ricardian Theory. Do not confuse the two. Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 12 / 73

More generally, rename Canada and China to be N(orth) and S(outh), With the same two goods, C(omputers) and T(extiles), the North will possess a comparative advantage in computers if and only if: ac N at N < as C a S T The South will possess a comparative advantage in computers if and only if: ac N at N > as C a S T Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 13 / 73

Is this confirmed in the earlier data? Country a T a C Canada 10 5 China 5 10 a Can. C a Can. T = 1 2 a China C a China T = 2 acan. C a Can. T < achina C at China and Canada has a comparative advantage in computers! Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 14 / 73

With only two goods, if a country possesses a comparative advantage in one good, the other country will possess the comparative advantage in the other good. With only two goods, a country cannot have a comparative advantage in both goods!! In the above example, suppose one country has a set of a j s that are lower for both goods. Are there still gains from specialization, if one country has an absolute advantage in which it possesses lower unit labor requirements in both sectors? Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 15 / 73

Suppose that North possesses an absolute advantage in both sectors such that the structure of unit labor requirements is as follows: Table: Unit Labor Requirements Country Textiles Computers North 10 5 South 20 40 For each good, the North has a lower unit labor requirement but which good is it more better at? Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 16 / 73

Opportunity costs. (a N C /a N T )=0.5 (a S C /a S T )=2. Opportunity costs are the same as before even though Canada is 4 times as productive as before in both goods! Comparative advantage is not necessarily affected by shifts in Absolute Advantage. Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 17 / 73

Are their gains from specialization? Suppose that the South wants an additional computer. The South can: 1. Forgo 2 textiles and produce the computer at home. Or, 2. Produce 0.5 textiles and then trade them to the North for, for example, 1 computer. (the North is willing to do this because 1 is less than its own opportunity costs of producing textiles). Clearly, the South prefers producing the good they have a comparative advantage in and the trading it relative to producing an additional unit of the good at which they are at a comparative disadvantage. Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 18 / 73

Despite the fact that the North has an absolute advantage in both goods, the North has a comparative advantage in Computers and the South has a comparative advantage in Textiles. Why is it inefficient for the North to produce everything? Suppose they did... Both countries could always be better of by specializing and trading at a price that lies in between the two opportunity costs. The South should produce what it is good at and the North should produce what it is good at. Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 19 / 73

What will the relative price of computers and textiles be? Remember that there is no money in this model. All prices are relative prices of goods. Assume that trade occurs. Assertion: In equilibrium, the world price of computers will be between 0.5 and 2 textiles per computer. Start with the result that Canada produces computers and China produces textiles. i.e. assume each country produces its comparative advantage good. Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 20 / 73

Suppose that the world price of computers is less than 0.5 textiles per computer. Computers are cheap for China relative to autarky. China is happy but textiles are expensive for Canada relative to autarky. Canada is better off producing its own textiles the relative price cannot be less than 0.5 textiles per computer. Suppose that the world price of computers is more than 2 textiles per computer. Textiles are cheap for Canada relative to autarky. Canada is happy but computers are now expensive relative to autarky. China is better off producing its own computers the relative price cannot be more than 2. Consequently, the the relative price will be between 0.5 and 2. Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 21 / 73

Can 1 (textile per of computer) be the equilibrium relative price? Canada produces computers. The one textile per computer it can obtain through trade is better than the 1/2 of a textile it could get if it produced its own textiles. China produces textiles. The one computer per textile it can obtain through trade is better than the 1/2 of a computer it could get if it produced its own computers. For yourself: verify that 0.75 and 1.5 are also both possible equilibrium relative prices. Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 22 / 73

More generally, an equilibrium relative price must satisfy the following restriction where the North has a comparative advantage in good x and the South has a comparative advantage in good y. a North x a North y p x asouth x p y ay South This only pins down a possible range of equilibrium factor prices. To narrow this range, we introduce demand. First, let s think more deeply about the gains from trade in this Ricardian model. Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 23 / 73

Conjecture: Suppose that the North has a comparative advantage in good x: If If a N x a N y = px p y < as x a S y trade and the South gains. a N x a N y < px p y = as x a S y South neither gains nor loses. then the North neither gains nor loses from then the North gains from trade and the Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 24 / 73

Can we illustrate this graphically? The North s Production Possibility Frontier (PPF) is as follows where L N is the amount of labor that the North possesses: a N C QN C + an T QN T LN Assuming full employment of all factors, simple arithmetic gives: Q N T = LN a N T an C a N T Q N C Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 25 / 73

Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 26 / 73

Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 27 / 73

A key insight is that in autarky, the PPF and the budget constraint will be the same line. In autarky, what you consume/purchase must be what you produce. With trade, you need not consume what you produce. Therefore, in a trading equilibrium, the budget constraint and PPF need not be the same line. Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 28 / 73

Autarky Relative Prices w = P k MPL k = P k a k for k = {C, T } Because the same wage w is paid in both sectors, this implies P C P T = a C a T Autarky relative prices will be equal to the ratio of unit labor requirements in that country. Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 29 / 73

Now introduce Trade a The PPF will look the same as before and will have a slope of N C. at N The budget constraint will now be based on the equation P C Q C + P T Q T Y and will have the slope P C P T. Let s examine the case where P C P T > an C. at N Does the North gain from trade if it specializes in computers? Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 30 / 73

Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 31 / 73

Now let s examine the Southern case. Let s examine the case where P C P T < as C. at S Does the South gain from trade if it specializes in textiles? Starting from autarky... Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 32 / 73

Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 33 / 73

Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 34 / 73

Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 35 / 73

Suppose that (for either country) world relative prices more closely resemble autarky relative prices. The gains from trade will diminish until ( ) PC P T 0 = an C a N T At this point, utility will be the same as in autarky.. Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 36 / 73

Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 37 / 73

If world relative prices equal autarky relative prices for one country, that country does not gain from trade. The other country does gain from trade. If world relative prices are in between autarky relative prices, both countries gain from trade. The more different a country s ratio of unit labor requirements are from world relative prices, the more a country gains from trade. If both countries have the same opportunity costs there is no comparative advantage Then there is no gains from trade for either country. Even though there might still be absolute advantage. Large differences mean larger gains from specialization. Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 38 / 73

Let s introduce demand... Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 39 / 73

We are going to use the following graph to solve for equilibrium (relative) output and prices (note the axes labels!!). Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 40 / 73

The vertical axis gives the price of good X relative to Y. The horizontal axis gives the relative World quantities where the World is simply to aggregation of the North and South. Recall that the equilibrium relative price of goods X and Y must lie between the autarky relative prices/unit labor requirements of the two countries. Assume that the North has a comparative advantage in good x, therefore the South possesses a comparative advantage in good y. Arithmetically, an x a < as y n x a. y s We can represent this graphically as... Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 41 / 73

Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 42 / 73

Now suppose that px p y = as x. ay S The North completely specializes in good x because it can produce x and then trade for y at better terms than if it produced its own y. Consequently X N = L N /a n x and Y N = 0. The South is indifferent between specializing in Y (and then trading for X ) and producing both X and Y. The South will produce some combination of (X S, Y S ) that satisfies Consequently, when px p y segment. 0 < X S Y S < = as x, the relative quantity supplied will be a ay S Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 43 / 73

Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 44 / 73

Suppose that px p y = an x. ay N The South completely specializes in good y because it can produce y and then trade for x at better terms than if it produced its own x. Consequently X S = 0 and Y S = L S /a s y. However, we cannot say how much the North will specialize because the North is indiffernt indifferent between specializing in X (and then trading for Y ) and producing both X and Y. Consequently, when px p y segment... = an x, the relative quantity supplied will be a ay N Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 45 / 73

Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 46 / 73

Now suppose that an x a N y < px p y < as x. ay S Complete specialization where the North specializes in X and the South specializes in X. Note that any set of relative prices between the two autarky price ratios will support this outcome. The relative supply curve will be vertical at this point. Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 47 / 73

Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 48 / 73

At this point... The North prefers specializing in X and trading for Y to producing both. Consequently, X N = L N /a N X and Y N = 0. The South prefers specializing in Y and trading for X to producing both. X S = 0 and Y S = L S /a S Y. Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 49 / 73

Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 50 / 73

The structure of demand determines the equilibrium. This is done by introducing a relative demand curve As the relative price of a good rises, relative demand increases. Reflects substitution effects. Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 51 / 73

Figure: Demand for X is high relative to Y Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 52 / 73

The North specializes in X and the South produces both X and Y. Why? World demand for X is sufficiently high that the North cannot produce enough X to satisfy high World demand for X. The South satisfies for the remaining demand for X. Because relative prices for the South are the same as in autarky, the South does not gain from trade but the North does. In sum, the World gains. Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 53 / 73

Figure: Demand for Y is high relative to X Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 54 / 73

The South specializes in Y and the North produces both X and Y. Why? World demand for Y is sufficiently high that the South cannot produce enough Y to satisfy high World demand for Y. The North must provide for the remaining demand for Y. Because prices for the North are the same as in autarky, the North does not gain from trade but the South does. In sum, the World gains. Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 55 / 73

Figure: Demand for X and Y is Relatively Even. Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 56 / 73

The North specializes in X and the South specializes in Y. Because relative world prices are between autarky unit labor requirements, both countries gain from trade General Rule in this model: a country that does not specialize does not gain from trade! Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 57 / 73

This analysis suggests that a country will produce more of its comparative advantage good than its comparative disadvantage good (specialization). One country produces a lot of one good, the other country produces a lot of the other. If preferences are sufficiently similar (which we have assumed), they will demand the same goods. A country will export its comparative advantage good and import its comparative disadvantage good. See an upcoming problem set for concrete examples. Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 58 / 73

Relative Wages Some commentators argue that high relative wages in the North relative to the south are evidence of Northern exploitation of Southern workers. Does the Ricardian model have anything to say about this? Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 59 / 73

Relative Wages Start with the profit maximizing condition that nominal wages equal the marginal revenue product of labor. w = p MPL Now suppose that Northern workers specialize in computers and Southern workers specialize in textiles. This gives us two equilibrium conditions: w N = p C a N C w S = p T a S T Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 60 / 73

Relative Wages These conditions can be combined to give the following expression w N w S = as T p C ac N p T = MPLN C p C MPL S p T T Northern relative wages are determined by labor productivity and the relative prices of the two goods. If the two goods have the same price, labor productivity alone determines relative wages. If the two goods do not have the same price, the relative wage is higher in the country that produces the relatively valuable good, holding labor productivity constant. But wages in both North and South are always higher under Trade than under Autarky. Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 61 / 73

Relative Wages We can also offer strong rebuttals to common criticisms of free trade if the Ricardian model possesses substantial validity. 1. Free Trade is beneficial only if your country is strong enough to stand up to foreign competition. 2. Foreign competition is unfair and hurts other countries when it is based on low wages. 3. Trade exploits a country and makes it worse off if its workers receive much lower wages than workers in other nations. Krugman and Obstfeld, pp. 36-40 Krugman Ricardo s Difficult Idea. (optional). Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 62 / 73

Relative Wages Free Trade is beneficial only if your country is strong enough to stand up to foreign competition. Comparative and not absolute advantage is sufficient for gains from trade Foreign competition is unfair and hurts other countries when it is based on low wages. Low foreign wages are caused by low productivity. Trade exploits a country and makes it worse off if its workers receive much lower wages than workers in other nations. If wages are based on productivity, they will be low even if there is no trade. Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 63 / 73

Conclusions 1. Each country exports the good at which it possesses a comparative advantage. 2. Each country imports the good at which it possesses a comparative disadvantage. 3. In this setting, each country possesses a comparative advantage in some good. 4. If free trade relative prices lie between autarky unit labor requirements, both countries gain from trade. 5. If free trade relative prices equal the autarky price ratio for one country, that country is no worse off from trade and the other country is better off. 6. Increased utility comes from increased consumption possibilities that allow consumer/workers to attain a higher indifference curve. Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 64 / 73

The Multi-Good Extension Let s make the model more realistic by allowing more than one good. This will also allow us to introduce the important notion of the the intensive and extensive margin of trade. Suppose there are N goods produced, indexed by i = 1,2,N. The domestic countrys unit labor requirement for good i is a i, and that of the foreign country is a i Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 65 / 73

The Multi-Good Extension Goods will be produced wherever it is cheaper to produce them. Let w represent the wage rate in the domestic country and w* represent the wage rate in the foreign country. If wa 1 < w a1 then only the domestic country will produce good 1, since total wage payments are less there. < w w Equivalently, good i is produced in Home only if a 1 a1 technology advantage is larger than its cost disadvantage) Let s consider an example: (if Home s Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 66 / 73

The Multi-Good Extension Figure: Demand for X and Y is Relatively Even. Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 67 / 73

The Multi-Good Extension Home has high productivity in apples, bananas, and caviar. That gives Home a cost advantage. Suppose Foreign has low wages. That gives it a cost advantage, despite its low productivity. How is the equilibrium relative wage determined? the relevant equilibrium is equality of the relative supply and relative (derived) demand of labor services. Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 68 / 73

The Multi-Good Extension As domestic labor becomes more expensive relative to foreign labor, goods produced in the domestic country become more expensive, and demand of these goods and therefore derived demand for the labor to produce them falls. At certain threshold-levels, comparative advantage shifts from Home to Foreign so that fewer goods will be produced in Home, further reducing the demand of domestic labor services. The relative (derived) demand of domestic labor services therefore falls when w/w* rises. Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 69 / 73

The Multi-Good Extension The Intensive and Extensive Margin of Trade The intensive margin refers to a country exporting or importing a larger quantity of the same goods The extensive margin refers to a country exporting or importing new goods In later chapters, the intensive margin can also refer exporting firms exporting more while the extensive margin refers to non-exporting firms becoming exporters. Suppose w/w* increases from 3 to 3.99: Home produces the same goods but at higher prices so that the demand for these goods and the labor to produce them falls (intensive margin). Suppose w/w* increases from 3.99 to 4.01: The caviar industry now moves to Foreign, causing a discrete drop in the demand of domestic labor (extensive margin). Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 70 / 73

The Multi-Good Extension Figure: Demand for X and Y is Relatively Even. Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 71 / 73

Empirical Evidence What is the empirical evidence for technology-differences-based comparative advantage? Do countries export those goods in which their productivity is relatively high? The ratio of U.S. to British exports in 1951 compared to the ratio of U.S. to British labor productivity in 26 manufacturing industries suggests yes. At this time the U.S. had an absolute advantage in all 26 industries, yet the ratio of exports was low in the least productive sectors of the U.S. Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 72 / 73

Empirical Evidence Figure: Demand for X and Y is Relatively Even. Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 73 / 73