Derisking Renewable Energy Investment



Similar documents
Derisking Renewable Energy Investment

Attracting private investment through NAMAs: the role of risk, return and policy design. Part1: Why and how private investment matters

Financing of Renewable Energy in India: Implications for Policy. Gireesh Shrimali Climate Policy Initiative

The Clean Development Mechanisms (CDM) What is it? And how can it be used to promote climate protection and sustainable development?

International Solar Energy Arena January 23rd, 2009, Istanbul STEAM (Strategic Technical Economic Research Center)

Summary of Master Thesis for SAEE. Fuelling Renewable Energy Diffusion in non-oecd Countries

Financing Energy Efficiency and Renewable Energy through the India Renewable Energy Development Agency

Opportunities for a Green Bank in California

Green Power Accounting Workshop: Concept Note For discussion during Green Power Accounting Workshop in Mexico City, May 13th 2011

Sustainable and Renewable Energy Development Authority (SREDA) of Bangladesh Role and Responsibility

Preparing for Scaled-up Climate Financing: New Business Opportunities for Green Growth

FINDING YOUR CHEAPEST WAY TO A LOW CARBON FUTURE. The Danish Levelized Cost of Energy Calculator

A macro-economic viewpoint. What is the real cost of offshore wind? siemens.com / wind

Scope 2 Accounting Guidance: What it means for corporate decisions to purchase environmental instruments

CO 2 Regulation and Electricity Pricing

Energy Productivity & Pricing

The Real Cost of Electrical Energy. Outline of Presentation

PROJECT FINANCE & PPPs

Energy Finance in the Middle East: Uncertainties and Opportunities Maamari Auditorium, OSB AUB, 22 January 2016

World Economic Forum Insurance and Asset Management Council. Joachim Faber. Low Carbon Economy Finance Paper Q4 2011

EU energy and climate policies beyond 2020

Expanding the Investor Base and Lowering the Cost of Capital for Renewable Energy through Master Limited Partnerships

The Levy Control Framework

Portfolio Manager and Green Power Tracking

FINANCE FOR CLEAN ENERGY

Introduction to Project Finance Analytic Methods

Winning Entry - Fernando Rezende Ayres. M.S. in Energy Systems, Northeastern University

4. Comparison with DECC (2014) Estimated impacts of energy and climate change policies on energy prices and bills

RE-POWERING MARKETS Market design and regulation during the transition to low-carbon power systems

EURELECTRIC responses to the invitation in Draft decision -/CMP.5 to make submissions to the UNFCCC secretariat on:

The Prospects for Cost Competitive Solar PV Power

1: Levelized Cost of Energy Calculation. Methodology and Sensitivity

Portfolio Carbon Initiative

Project Idea Note: Solar Water Heating Fee-For-Service Program in the Caribbean

Commonly asked Question about Green Power, and Kit Carson Renewable Energy Program.

Ausbau der Windenergie in Vietnam Up-Scaling of Wind Power in Vietnam

However, to ensure that JGN can continue attracting necessary funds, we depart from the AER s guideline by estimating:

Response to the Energy White Paper Issues Paper PREPARED BY EMC ENGINEERING FOR THE AUSTRALIAN GOVERNMENT DEPARTMENT OF INDUSTRY

Security of electricity supply

Introduction to the Project and Today s Meeting

Federal Incentives Provided by EPAct 2005 for Advanced Coal Technology

Urban Community Energy Fund Getting your project investment ready

Managing Rising Energy Costs for Seniors in the ACT

Resource Planning Update. June 16, 2016 Board Meeting Presentation

What is Climatescope?

SMARTGRID Roadmap 1.

Growing the Green Economy

MINISTRY OF ENERGY FEED-IN-TARIFFS POLICY ON WIND, BIOMASS, SMALL-HYDRO, GEOTHERMAL, BIOGAS AND SOLAR RESOURCE GENERATED ELECTRICITY

The Hidden Costs of Solar Power

COMMISSION STAFF WORKING DOCUMENT EXECUTIVE SUMMARY OF THE IMPACT ASSESSMENT. Accompanying the document

SECTOR ASSESSMENT (SUMMARY): ENERGY. 1. Sector Performance, Problems, and Opportunities

The Economics of Solar in Alberta

Levelized Cost and Levelized Avoided Cost of New Generation Resources in the Annual Energy Outlook 2015

How to implement renewable energy and energy efficiency options

On June 28, 2011, the Municipal Services Committee recommended that the City Council adopt the recommendations stated in the subject agenda report.

Residential Consumer Guide to Solar Power

ETSAP ETechDS Data Normalisation Project

The Economic c Viability of Nuclear Power in The Netherlands

Financing Renewables and Energy Efficiency Projects in Developing Countries

Analysis of a 30 Percent by 2030 National Renewable Electricity Standard

Guidance for U.S. Positions on MDBs Engaging with Developing Countries on Coal-Fired Power Generation 1

Renewable Power Generation Costs

CEFC finance supports Australian solar PV manufacturer

Projected Costs of Generating Electricity

Overview of Rooftop Solar PV Green Bank Financing Model

PROJECT FINANCIAL EVALUATION

Tax Credit Extension: Impact on Renewables Investment and Emissions Outcomes

Solar securitization

The debate on market design in the EU energy policy

Energy Technology Perspectives 2015

The CTF MENA CSP Scale-up Investment Plan

Some micro- and macro-economics of offshore wind*

Some highlights of the South Australia study include: A large untapped resource: The modelling results show strong growth in

Consumer Cost Effectiveness of CO 2 Mitigation Policies in Restructured Electricity Markets. Jared Moore and Jay Apt.

Phakwe group. Growing with Africa

Greenhouse gas abatement potential in Israel

Success story: Feed-In Tariffs Support renewable energy in Germany

A Systematic Approach for the use of Climate Finance in Sustainable Transport

POLICY BRIEF WHAT IS A MARGINAL ABATEMENT COST (MAC) CURVE? HOW TO READ A MAC CURVE. Marginal Abatement Cost (MAC) Curve. Abstract

Joint IEA-RETD and IRENA Workshop. The Business case of New Generation RE-COST1 STUDY Preliminary Results. Mercedes Mostajo

The African Development Bank

DOE Announces $1B Loan Guarantee Fund For Distributed Energy Projects

Interview: Aurélie Faure, Financial Analyst at Dexia Asset Management

GLOBAL RENEWABLE ENERGY MARKET OUTLOOK 2013

GHG Accounting Guidance Note Manufacture of Renewable Energy Climate Related Products

How to Earn the LEED Green Power Credit

Annex 1 Tool for the demonstration and assessment of additionality

Solar PV in the Caribbean Opportunities and Challenges

Climate Change and. Environment Position. Statement. and 2017 Action Plan. action. Statement. Action Plan. September 2014

Updating the New Zealand Emissions Trading Scheme: Consultation Document

Investing in renewable technologies CfD contract terms and strike prices

New York Green Bank: Overview and Example Partnerships

Energy Prices, Climate Change Policy and U.S. Economic Growth

are country driven and in conformity with, and supportive of, national development priorities;

White Paper Growing Up: Onshore wind s place in a competitive, low carbon power generation system. At a Crossroad the UK Power Market

Power Purchase Agreement Financial Models in SAM

Renewable Choice Energy

SESSION VI: CLIMATE CHANGE AND ENERGY EFFICIENCY POLICIES

INDONESIA S COUNTRY REPORT ENCOURAGING CLEAN ENERGY INITIATIVE

Transcription:

Derisking Renewable Energy Investment Key Concepts Note UNDP's report introduces an innovative framework, together with a financial tool, to assist policymakers to promote renewable energy in developing countries. INTRODUCTION Across the world, developing country governments are seeking to rapidly scale-up investment in renewable energy. The financial sums required to achieve this are enormous; UN-DESA has estimated that it could cost up to USD 250 270 billion per year to shift developing countries to 20 percent renewable energy by 2025 1. Private sector financing, backed by the international capital markets, will be key to meeting this investment challenge. However, the reality is that renewable energy project developers in developing countries often struggle to access the large quantities of financing they require and when available, the cost of financing is often high. The need to make renewable energy investment financially attractive for the private sector has inspired the development of a wide variety of public instruments. These public instruments can come at a cost to industry, to consumers or to the tax-payer. The challenge is to design packages of public instruments which can cost-effectively catalyse private investment. To this end, the United Nations Development Programme (UNDP) recently issued Derisking Renewable Energy Investment, a report to assist policymakers to promote renewable energy investment in developing countries. The report introduces an innovative framework, with an accompanying financial tool, to quantitatively compare different public instruments and their cost-effectiveness. This briefing note provides a brief summary of some key concepts from the report: The impact of high financing costs on renewable energy Identifying a public instrument mix The framework s waterfalls The frameworks performance metrics MORE ON THE REPORT The report is the work of UNDP s Energy, Infrastructure, Technology and Transport (EITT) unit. The full report, executive summary and financial tool can be downloaded at www.undp.org/drei For more information, please contact DREI@undp.org This key concept note was first published in October 2013. This updated version dates from March 2014. 1 DeMartino, S., Le Blanc, D. (2010). Estimating the Amount of a Global Feed-in Tariff for Renewable Electricity. UN DESA Working Paper No. 95. New York, NY: United Nations Department of Affairs 1

High financing costs for renewable energy High financing costs in developing countries reflect a range of underlying investment risks. Renewable energy, given its upfront capital intensity, is penalized in high financing cost environments. The technology costs of renewable energy have shown remarkably steady decreases over the past decades. For example, in the case of solar photovoltaic, module costs have experienced a near 98 percent reduction from 1979 to 2012 2. Nonetheless, while technology costs have fallen, private sector investors in renewable energy in developing countries still face high financing costs (both for equity and debt). These high financing costs reflect a range of technical, regulatory, financial and informational barriers and their associated investment risks. Investors in early-stage renewable energy markets, such as those of many developing countries, require a high rate of return to compensate for these risks. Figure 1, below, illustrates how these high financing costs can impact the competitiveness of renewable energy. The figure compares the levelised cost of electricity (LCOE) of onshore wind energy and combined-cycle gas in a developed and developing country. In a developed country benefiting from low financing costs, wind power can be almost cost-competitive with gas. In a developing country with higher financing costs, wind power generation cost becomes 40 percent more expensive than in a developed country. In contrast, gas only becomes 6 percent more expensive due to these higher financing costs. This is a function of the high upfront capital intensity of renewable energy. Simply put, high financing cost environments penalize renewable energy when compared to fossil-fuel based power generation. Figure 1: The Impact of financing costs on wind and gas power generation costs Developed country Developing country (Wind vs. Gas) (Wind vs. Gas) 9.4 PRE-TAX LCOE (USD CENTS/kWh) 6.7 1.8 0.9 1.1 2.9 + 40% 6.1 0.6 0.3 4.5 + 6% 3.3 2.4 0.8 2.9 6.5 1.0 0.9 3.9 Financing Cost (Equity) Financing Cost (Debt) Operating Cost (incl. fuel cost) Investment Cost/ Depreciation Wind (onshore) 0.7 Gas (CCGT) Developed Country = 10% = 5% Wind (onshore) Developing Country = 18% = 10% 0.7 Gas (CCGT) All assumptions besides the financing costs are kept constant between the developed and developing country. For technology assumptions, see inputs for wind energy and gas (CCGT) in Section A.3 (Annex A); a 70%/30% debt/equity capital structure is assumed; financing costs are based on data obtained in the four country case study (Chapter 3), assuming a non-investment grade developing country. Operating costs appear as a lower contribution to LCOE in developing countries due to discounting effects from higher financing costs. 2 IRENA. (2012). Renewable Power Generation Costs in 2012: An Overview. Abu Dhabi: International Renewable Energy Agency. 2

Faced with this challenge of high financing costs in developing countries, policymakers seeking to promote renewable energy have two broad options: first, to reduce the high financing costs of renewable energy through derisking instruments, by addressing the underlying investment risks that result in higher financing costs; secondly, to cover any incremental cost of renewable energy through direct incentives, typically by a market-based instrument, such as a PPA price premium. The report examines this policy trade-off between derisking and direct incentives. Given the high sensitivity of renewable energy to financing costs, the report puts forward a theory of change that reducing high financing costs for renewable energy, and thereby making the generation costs of renewable energy competitive, is a key opportunity for policymakers acting in developing countries today. Identifying a public instrument mix Derisking can take two basic forms: measures which reduce risk ( policy derisking ) and measures which transfer risk ( financial derisking ) Figure 2, below, illustrates a typical public instrument package for large-scale renewable energy. This is composed of a cornerstone instrument, such as a feed-in-tariff (FiT), acting as the centrepiece public instrument, complemented by derisking instruments, and where necessary, direct financial incentives. The report makes an important distinction between two groups of public derisking measures: policy derisking instruments and financial derisking instruments. Policy derisking instruments address and seek to remove the underlying barriers that are the root causes of investment risks. These instruments utilise policy and programmatic interventions to mitigate risk. For example, renewable energy projects typically involve obtaining a number of permits and approvals. A policy derisking approach might involve streamlining Figure 2: Public instrument selection for large-scale renewable energy the permitting process, clarifying institutional responsibilities, reducing the number of process steps and providing capacity building to programme administrators. Financial derisking instruments do not seek to directly address the underlying barrier but, instead, function by transferring investment risks to public actors, such as development banks. These instruments can include public loans and guarantees, political risk insurance and public equity co-investments. For example, the credit worthiness of a power purchase agreement (PPA) may often be a concern to lenders. Partial loan guarantees can provide local banks with the security to lend to project developers, thereby kick-starting the local financial sector s involvement in renewable energy. Select Cornerstone Instrument Feed-in tariff PPA-based bidding process Select Policy Derisking Instruments Long-term RE targets Streamlined permits process Select Financial Derisking Instruments Public loans Partial loan guarantees + Direct Financial Incentives (If positive incremental cost) FiT/PPA price premium Tax credits Improved O&M skills risk insurance Carbon offsets 3

The framework s financing cost waterfalls The report introduces a framework to assist policymakers to select and quantify the impacts of public instruments to promote renewable energy. In order to demonstrate how the framework can be applied in practice, the report includes illustrative modelling case studies in four developing countries: Kenya, Mongolia, Panama and South Africa. One of the framework s key concepts is the financing cost waterfall, which quantifies how different categories of investment risks contribute to higher financing costs in the particular renewable energy market being studied. Figure 3, below, shows the financing cost waterfalls generated in the report s illustrative case study in South Africa. The case study was performed for onshore wind energy, assuming a 20 year target of 8.4GW in installed capacity. Figure 3: waterfalls from the illustrative South Africa case study (onshore wind, 8.4GW) BUSINE USUAL FINANCING COSTS 1.1% 0.5% 0.2% 0.7% 0.6% 0.5% 0.6% 1.2% 9.5% 15.0% 5.0% 0.6% 0.1% 0.4% 0.3% 0.4% 0.7% 7.5% Financing cost waterfalls quantify how different categories of investment risks contribute to higher financing costs. Best-in-Class Country Permits Financial Sector Macro-econ. 0.4% 0.1% 0.1% 0.2% 0.2% 0.1% N/A N/A -1.2% Best-in-Class Country ERISKING FINANCING COSTS Macro-econ -0.5% 0.2% 0.0% 0.1% 0.1% N/A N/A 15.0% 13.8% 7.5% 7.0% Permits Financial Sector Macro-econ. Macro-econ. Data obtained from interviews with wind investors and developers. See Annex A of the report for full assumptions. The post-derisking cost of debt and equity show the average impacts over a 20 year modelling period, assuming linear timing effects. The underlying data for financing cost waterfalls is obtained from structured interviews with private sector equity and debt investors, where investors are asked to score the strength of various investment risks. The original concept for the financing cost waterfall comes from UNDP s research partnership with Deutsche Bank in the Deutsche Bank report, GET FiT Plus 3. 3 DB Climate Change Advisors. (2011). GET FiT Plus: Derisking Clean Energy Business Models in a Developing Country Context. New York, NY: The Deutsche Bank Group. 4

The report s framework generates risk waterfalls in two scenarios: A business-as-usual scenario, which represents the current investment environment for the renewable energy in the particular country. This provides policymakers with an accessible analysis of the impediments to private sector investment, and can assist in prioritising or targeting the public instruments to address specific investment risks. A post-derisking scenario, after applying public derisking instruments to reduce investment risks. The scenario models how a particular package of public instruments can result in lower financing costs, which can then make renewable energy more competitive with fossil-fuel alternatives. In the illustrative South Africa case study, the business-as-usual financing cost waterfalls identify a number of investment risks as large contributors to higher financing costs, including power market risk, grid integration risk, counterparty risk and currency risk. A package of derisking instruments, targeting the various investment risk categories identified and estimated at USD 40m over 20 years, results in the cost of equity for wind energy being reduced by 1.2% to 13.8%, and the cost of debt being lowered by 0.5% to 7.0%. The framework s performance metrics The framework then uses the data obtained from the financing cost waterfalls to assess the impact of the selected public instrument package to achieve the targeted investment in renewable energy. Figure 4, below, shows some of the results obtained in the illustrative case study for onshore wind energy in South Africa. In the South Africa case study, the LCOE for wind energy falls from 9.6 to 8.9 USD cents per kwh when derisking instruments are implemented. Figure 4: Results from the illustrative South Africa case study (onshore wind, 8.4GW) LCOE (USD CENTS/kWh) 7.4 Baseline Activity (Unsubsidised) 9.6 Wind Investment 8.9 Wind Investment INVESTMENT LEVERAGE RATIO (Metric 1) CARBON ABATEMENT (Metric 4) Present value of costs over 20 years Policy derisking instruments Price premium (FiT, PPA) 14 604 Mt CO 2 e (20 yrs) MILLION USD 7,257 x 2.3* 4,993 4,953 40 x 3.3 16,632 USD/tCO 2 e 12 10 8 6 4 2 12.0 8.2-32% Cost of Instruments Cost of Instruments Wind Energy Investments 0 Data obtained from interviews with wind investors and developers. See Annex A of the report for full assumptions. The post-derisking cost of debt and equity show the average impacts over a 20 year modelling period, assuming linear timing effects. 5

The top half of Figure 4 shows the South Africa case study s outputs for the levelised cost of electricity (LCOE). In South Africa, and with a generation mix currently dominated by coal, the case study calculates the LCOE for the energy baseline at 7.4 USD cents/kwh. Without a package of derisking instruments in place, wind energy is more costly than this baseline. However, with a package of derisking instruments in place, the LCOE falls from 9.6 USD cents per kwh for wind energy in the business-as-usual to 8.9 USD cents per kwh in the post-derisking scenario. The lower half of Figure 4 shows two of the framework s four performance metrics, each of which examines the impacts of the selected public instrument package from a different perspective. These performance metrics are analysed over the entire 8.4GW 20 year target for wind energy in the South Africa case study. The first metric, the investment leverage ratio, examines the relationship between the cost of public instrument package and the resulting investment catalysed. These numbers illustrate that USD 40m in public derisking instruments can reduce the electricity tariff price premium (cumulative, real terms) for wind energy in South Africa from USD 7.3bn (business-as-usual scenario) to USD 5.0bn (post-derisking scenario). The second metric, carbon abatement, examines the cost of public instrument package from a climate change mitigation perspective. Here the numbers illustrate that investing in 8.4GW in wind energy will reduce carbon emissions by 604m tco 2 e over 20 years. In the business-as-usual scenario, the incremental cost of wind energy over the baseline equates to a cost of USD 12.0 per tco 2 e. With a package of derisking instruments in place, this cost is reduced to USD 8.2 per tco 2 e. In this way, the South Africa case study demonstrates the positive impact of public derisking instruments. The other three case studies in the report show similarly promising results. The report's case studies quantify how well designed public interventions can reduce risk, lower financing costs and make renewable energy more affordable Conclusions The report introduces a first version of the framework. UNDP welcomes feedback on the framework, and looks forward to working with its partners to further develop and refine it. Overall, the intent of the framework is not to provide one definitive numerical result, but instead to facilitate a structured, transparent process, where key inputs and outputs can be checked, debated and strengthened by all relevant stakeholders. By enabling the modelling of alternative portfolios of instruments, and supporting their analysis through a set of performance metrics, the framework can build a shared technical and political understanding of the issues surrounding the promotion of renewable energy. Two central findings emerge from the results of the report s four case studies: The first finding is that it is important for policymakers to address the risks to renewable energy investment in a systemic and integrated manner. In all four case study countries, the framework s financing cost waterfalls clearly demonstrate that a range of risks exist in the investment environment. Barriers to renewable energy investment can be numerous and are often deeply embedded, reflecting long-held practices centred on fossil fuels and monopolistic market structures. Any isolated, short-term effort focusing on a sub-set of risks and relying on a sub-set of instruments is unlikely to sustainably transform renewable energy markets. Each market transformation stage will usually require a mix of policy and financial derisking instruments, supplemented by direct financial incentives as required. The second finding is that investing in derisking measures, bringing down the financing costs of renewable energy, appears to be cost-effective when measured against paying direct financial incentives to compensate investors for higher risks. Instead of using scarce public funds to pay higher electricity tariffs, it can be advantageous to first reduce and manage typical renewable energy risks (for example, those associated with power markets, permits, and transmission) that energy investors face in a given country. Well-designed, stable policies are required by investors and can reduce risks, lower finance costs and benefit consumers. 6