Explaining Keynes Theory of Consumption, and Assessing its Strengths and Weaknesses.



Similar documents
INTRODUCTION AGGREGATE DEMAND MACRO EQUILIBRIUM MACRO EQUILIBRIUM THE DESIRED ADJUSTMENT THE DESIRED ADJUSTMENT

ANSWERS TO END-OF-CHAPTER QUESTIONS

Lesson 7 - The Aggregate Expenditure Model

Study Questions for Chapter 9 (Answer Sheet)

Government Budget and Fiscal Policy CHAPTER

1. Firms react to unplanned inventory investment by increasing output.

In this chapter we learn the potential causes of fluctuations in national income. We focus on demand shocks other than supply shocks.

Chapter 27: Taxation. 27.1: Introduction. 27.2: The Two Prices with a Tax. 27.2: The Pre-Tax Position

CHAPTER 9 Building the Aggregate Expenditures Model

BADM 527, Fall Midterm Exam 2. Multiple Choice: 3 points each. Answer the questions on the separate bubble sheet. NAME

Answers to Text Questions and Problems in Chapter 8

_FALSE 1. Firms react to unplanned inventory investment by increasing output.

Chapter 9. The IS-LM/AD-AS Model: A General Framework for Macroeconomic Analysis Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved

Econ 303: Intermediate Macroeconomics I Dr. Sauer Sample Questions for Exam #3

7 AGGREGATE SUPPLY AND AGGREGATE DEMAND* Chapter. Key Concepts

The Keynesian Cross. A Fixed Price Level. The Simplest Keynesian-Cross Model: Autonomous Consumption Only

Introduction to Economics, ECON 100:11 & 13 Multiplier Model

Aggregate Demand and Aggregate Supply Ing. Mansoor Maitah Ph.D. et Ph.D.

2. With an MPS of.4, the MPC will be: A) 1.0 minus.4. B).4 minus 1.0. C) the reciprocal of the MPS. D).4. Answer: A

Answers to Text Questions and Problems. Chapter 22. Answers to Review Questions

Pre-Test Chapter 8 ed17

Do Commodity Price Spikes Cause Long-Term Inflation?

ECON 3312 Macroeconomics Exam 3 Fall Name MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

Chapter 12. Aggregate Expenditure and Output in the Short Run

14.02 Principles of Macroeconomics Problem Set 1 Fall 2005 ***Solution***

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

Microeconomics Topic 3: Understand how various factors shift supply or demand and understand the consequences for equilibrium price and quantity.

FISCAL POLICY* Chapter. Key Concepts

S.Y.B.COM. (SEM-III) ECONOMICS

The Keynesian Total Expenditures Model

Potential GDP and Economic Growth

does the debt matter? comments

CHAPTER 5: MEASURING GDP AND ECONOMIC GROWTH

I. Introduction to Aggregate Demand/Aggregate Supply Model

Economics 101 Multiple Choice Questions for Final Examination Miller

Chapter 30 Fiscal Policy, Deficits, and Debt QUESTIONS

Keynesian Macroeconomic Theory

4. Answer c. The index of nominal wages for 1996 is the nominal wage in 1996 expressed as a percentage of the nominal wage in the base year.

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

Study Questions 8 (Keynesian Model) MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

For a closed economy, the national income identity is written as Y = F (K; L)

CHAPTER 7: AGGREGATE DEMAND AND AGGREGATE SUPPLY

Econ 202 Final Exam. Table 3-1 Labor Hours Needed to Make 1 Pound of: Meat Potatoes Farmer 8 2 Rancher 4 5

SHORT-RUN FLUCTUATIONS. David Romer. University of California, Berkeley. First version: August 1999 This revision: January 2012

SRAS. is less than Y P

Lab 17: Consumer and Producer Surplus

= C + I + G + NX ECON 302. Lecture 4: Aggregate Expenditures/Keynesian Model: Equilibrium in the Goods Market/Loanable Funds Market

Extra Problems #3. ECON Macroeconomic Theory Spring 2010 Instructor: Guangyi Ma. Notice:

The level of price and inflation Real GDP: the values of goods and services measured using a constant set of prices

Chapter 12: Gross Domestic Product and Growth Section 1

1. Explain what causes the liquidity preference money (LM) curve to shift and why.

Econ 202 H01 Final Exam Spring 2005

2.If actual investment is greater than planned investment, inventories increase more than planned. TRUE.

The Short-Run Macro Model. The Short-Run Macro Model. The Short-Run Macro Model

(1) A reduction in the lump sum tax (2) A rise in the marginal propensity to import (3) A decrease in the marginal propensity to consume

Elasticity. I. What is Elasticity?

With lectures 1-8 behind us, we now have the tools to support the discussion and implementation of economic policy.

1. a. Interest-bearing checking accounts make holding money more attractive. This increases the demand for money.

University of Lethbridge Department of Economics ECON 1012 Introduction to Macroeconomics Instructor: Michael G. Lanyi

MONETARY AND FISCAL POLICY IN THE VERY SHORT RUN

Chapter 10 Fiscal Policy Macroeconomics In Context (Goodwin, et al.)

WHY STUDY PUBLIC FINANCE?

Common sense, and the model that we have used, suggest that an increase in p means a decrease in demand, but this is not the only possibility.

Chapter 9 Aggregate Demand and Economic Fluctuations Macroeconomics In Context (Goodwin, et al.)

Keynesian Economics I. The Keynesian System (I): The Role of Aggregate Demand

13 EXPENDITURE MULTIPLIERS: THE KEYNESIAN MODEL* Chapter. Key Concepts

Production and Unemployment. Great Depression. Prices and Wages. World Depression. Stock Market Crash. Recession or Depression?

Chapter 3. The Concept of Elasticity and Consumer and Producer Surplus. Chapter Objectives. Chapter Outline

Use the following to answer question 9: Exhibit: Keynesian Cross

Hedge-funds: How big is big?

Version /10. General Certificate of Education. Economics. ECON1: Markets and Market Failure. Mark Scheme examination - January series

Managerial Economics Prof. Trupti Mishra S.J.M. School of Management Indian Institute of Technology, Bombay. Lecture - 13 Consumer Behaviour (Contd )

Chapter 12 Unemployment and Inflation

Introduction to Macroeconomics 1012 Final Exam Spring 2013 Instructor: Elsie Sawatzky

THE THEORY OF ECONOMIC VALUE

In the news. The Global Economy Aggregate Supply & Demand. Roadmap. In the news. In the news. In the news

Supply and Demand in the Market for Money: The Liquidity Preference Framework

3 Macroeconomics LESSON 1

Chapter 10. Key Ideas Correlation, Correlation Coefficient (r),

. In this case the leakage effect of tax increases is mitigated because some of the reduction in disposable income would have otherwise been saved.

Politics, Surpluses, Deficits, and Debt

ECON 443 Labor Market Analysis Final Exam (07/20/2005)

The labour market, I: real wages, productivity and unemployment 7.1 INTRODUCTION

ECON 103, ANSWERS TO HOME WORK ASSIGNMENTS

Use the following to answer question 15: Exhibit: Short-run Phillips Curve. Page 3

Consumers face constraints on their choices because they have limited incomes.

The Multiplier Effect of Fiscal Policy

Chapter 4 Consumption, Saving, and Investment

Pre-Test Chapter 11 ed17

MEASURING GDP AND ECONOMIC GROWTH*

Accepted 4 October, 2011

University of Lethbridge Department of Economics ECON 1012 Introduction to Microeconomics Instructor: Michael G. Lanyi. Chapter 29 Fiscal Policy

Finance, Saving, and Investment

WHAT IS ECONOMICS. MODULE - 1 Understanding Economics OBJECTIVES 1.1 MEANING OF ECONOMICS. Notes

Introduction to microeconomics

Credit Spending And Its Implications for Recent U.S. Economic Growth

UNIT 1 THE CONCEPTS OF MACROECONOMICS

Solutions to Problem Set #2 Spring, a) Units of Price of Nominal GDP Real Year Stuff Produced Stuff GDP Deflator GDP

Optimal Consumption with Stochastic Income: Deviations from Certainty Equivalence

Transcription:

Explaining Keynes Theory of Consumption, and Assessing its Strengths and Weaknesses. The concept of consumption is one that varies between the academic community, governments, and between individuals. Before exploring the various theories on consumption determination, therefore, it must be explained what consumption entails. Consumption is, or shall be defined to be, the total quantity of goods and services that people in the economy wish to purchase for the purpose of immediate consumption. As such, it is one of the main determinants of an economy s aggregate demand (that is, the sum of all planned expenditures in the economy). Other determinants of aggregate demand include investment and government expenditure (with net trade taken into account for open markets), which are also defined in terms of desired rather than actual expenditure. This distinction is an important one, as will be seen later; by looking at desired expenditure it is possible to calculate actual expenditure, and derive formulae to discover how variations in external conditions will affect this. Taking the case of a closed economy (it is possible to look at this case and add trade later; the same conclusions would be drawn), we can therefore define aggregate demand ( d y ) as the sum of consumption, investment, and government expenditures: y d = c + i + g and, by looking at actual figures for the individual elements, it is quite obvious that consumption is the most important influence here. This may sound surprising, especially as the media constantly emphasises how government spending is currently at 46% of national income, but it must be realised that the vast majority of government expenditure is on items such as social security payments, which, while not counted on the above model (g above is defined to be the expenditure on goods and services alone), would be counted as consumption expenditure when the benefit receivers bought goods within the economy. A large amount of material has therefore been written regarding the consumption function; many macroeconomic policies rely on an ability to influence the aggregate Page 1

demand in an economy without directly increasing government expenditure. most famous (and, perhaps, therefore the most studied) paper is J M Keynes General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money, published in 1936, during the Great Depression. The Although the work covered many areas of economic theory, the most relevant idea here was that the major (and perhaps only) influence on personal consumption was an individual s income. Keynes theories centre on the equation: c = a + by, which shows that the consumption level is influenced by an autonomous figure (a), and a constant fraction of income (by). Keynes theorised that the autonomous figure would always be positive, and the multiple of income would lie between one and zero, varying according to the individuals in the economy. This factor of income was named the marginal propensity to consume (the MPC), and was included because men are disposed, as a rule and on the average, to increase their consumption as their income increases, but not by as much as the increase in their income 1. This may seem obvious; it is impossible for an individual to continually spend more than they earn, which would be implied if the MPC were to be greater than one. It must be recognised, however, that previous theories had, in general, assumed that consumption was either not linked to income, or that any rise in income would lead to an equal rise in consumption; this latter theory was the one generally adopted by classical economists. One key idea to be raised from this theory was that of saving. By definition, all money not spent on consumption in a two-sector economy (that is, without government) will be saved by an individual. In a three- or four- sector economy this assumption still holds, but must be examined more closely; money not spent may be either saved or given as tax, and this tax may be either spent as government expenditure, spent as consumption (via benefits), or saved. In a three- or four-sector economy, however, we may link tax into the consumption equation, to give: c = a + b( y t), where t is the amount of tax paid (not the tax rate). Page 2

It is possible to express the concept of saving using a Keynesian Cross (or 45 degree) diagram: c c = y c = a + by a y' y Keynes reasoned that there is a certain level of consumption that is necessary for an individual to stay alive; this would typically consist of expenditure on food, heat, and shelter, although in certain cases it could contain other items. This amount, the autonomous element a, can be seen above as the intercept with the y axis. At this point, and, indeed, at any point to the left of y' (the break-even income), consumption is above income, and individuals must use money from savings (that is, they must dissave) to pay for the deficit. At y' consumption exactly equals income, and there is no saving or dissaving, while above this level of income (to the right) the individual will save any surplus income not consumed. Using this diagram it is quite easy to see why the MPC cannot be greater (or even equal to) one if this was the case, and the autonomous level of consumption was strictly greater than zero, the two lines would never cross and the individual would be in a permanent state of dissaving. 1 Keynes (1936) Page 3

It was further theorised that, as this analysis concerned independent individuals, it would be followed by an entire economy, which consists of such individuals. Although the MPC would be different for each person, the average figure would still be constant. This enabled Keynes to predict how an economy would react to changes in national income, and how this may be beneficial in policy making. Following the publication of Keynes General Theory, a great deal of work was carried out to either prove or disprove the ideas contained within it. The data used for the analysis did indeed roughly follow Keynes theories, but it was noted that the long term data (averages over five years) gave different results to those concerning only short periods of time. It was noted that, as the data became more long term, the autonomous constant tended to zero, and the MPC tended to one: c Long term Medium term Short term y However, it was reasoned there would be an explanation for this phenomenon which would not contradict the rest of Keynes work, and the inclusion of various factors other than income may have compensated. Further factors influencing consumption were put forward, including levels of wealth (a rise in wealth would lead to an increase in consumption), expectations (optimism would be likely to shift the consumption function upwards, but this previously could be included in autonomous consumption if optimism was constant), and interest rates (if rates are too high, an individual will not necessarily be able to dissave, and so the consumption function Page 4

would shift downwards), and the distribution of income, although this last factor does contradict Keynes assertion that the MPC should be constant at all levels of income. It was this assumption that was broken down in the main consumption theories following Keynes. There are two main theories which are recognised as significantly building on Keynes work: the first, Permanent Income Hypothesis, was developed by Professor Milton Friedman; the second, the Life-Cycle Hypothesis, by Professors Franco Modigliani and Albert Ando. Although similar in many ways, these two theories should be examined individually. Permanent Income Hypothesis The main assumption behind Permanent Income Hypothesis is that people prefer their consumption to be smooth rather than volatile; that is, they prefer to buy a similar quantity of goods from week to week, from month to month, and so on. If, at the same time, it is assumed that individuals are rational and sensible problem solvers (a common assumption), it can be gathered that, because consumers aim to smooth their consumption, they will cut links between consumption and any volatile variable, including income. In order to do this, people will instead look to their long-term income prospects, which is known (slightly misleadingly) as their permanent income, and adjust consumption to this rather than actual income. It should be noted that Keynes theory had included a form of permanent income, in that it was assumed that workers would not spend all their allocated money on the day they were paid; rather they would spread consumption over the month (or however long between salaries). Friedman s theory, however, looks at a much longer timescale, and includes two different types of income; permanent and transitory. The permanent income component, as described above, is the amount of income a worker can expect to get every so often over a long period (such as a decade), and will vary proportionately with the actual level of income. The transitory income, however, will fluctuate, Page 5

according to how fortunate the individual is every period. As the number of time periods examined increases, the transitory income will tend to zero (good and bad spells will average out). It should be noted that transitory income can be either positive or negative, according to whether actual income is above or below permanent income. Looking at a long period, it can therefore be assumed that transitory income will be negligible, and it is possible to obtain a graph for consumption against income thus: c c = βy y where β is the MPC, which, over long periods, naturally tends to one (as people attempt to spend all their income). It should be noted again that in the above graph, the transitory element is approximately zero; the effect of a non-zero transitory element (and thus over a short time period) is as follows. It can be assumed that the average level of income will be very close to the average level of permanent income, if not equal to it. Looking at a level of income higher than this, it can be stated that this temporary high income is either due to a higher level of permanent income or a high transitory income. The latter is more likely, so transitory income is positive. Permanent income is thus lower than actual income, but, because people will consume at their permanent income, consumption will be at a point lower than the long run curve. Page 6

The opposite can be said of a level of income below the average; this will lead to an unusually high level of consumption. Looking at how this affects a graph, we can see a Keynesian graph for short term data, with an explanation for why Keynesian graphs shift and rotate when the lengths of time periods change: c c = βy Short term y While this hypothesis does explain quite adequately all that was uncertain about Keynes model, it was noted that long term graphs (those taken over decades) drifted upwards and to the right. It is therefore theorised that permanent income is slowly increasing, due to (and causing) higher living standards. Life-Cycle Hypothesis The Life-Cycle Hypothesis is very similar to the Permanent Income Hypothesis, but it assumes that permanent incomes are calculated over individuals entire life spans. This leads to the transitory element being decided, not by luck, but by the occupation and status of the individual. To start with, income is lower than can be expected, and individuals will borrow; then, as their salary increases with promotions, they will start paying this borrowing off, and then finally saving for when they retire. It should be noted that the amounts saved and dissaved over this time will not necessarily be equal, as interest on borrowing will diminish the savings considerably. It should further be noted that permanent income in this case is entirely constant, ceteris paribus. Page 7

This hypothesis is also heavily influenced by wealth other than income. If life starts with a certain amount of money, this money will be spent over the lifetime, thus increasing the level of permanent income, and the amount of saving and dissaving will alter accordingly; net saving will decrease. In conclusion, it can be seen that while Keynes theory of the consumption function contains many valid ideas, there are areas on which it could be improved. The basic premise of consumption depending almost entirely on income is obviously very strong, but the use of actual income rather than that expected partially invalidates the theory. As shown by Milton Friedman, the assumption that the marginal propensity to consume remains constant is false, and, while this is compensated for around Keynes original model, it does mean that a purely Keynesian view of consumption is unable to explain many of the phenomena in this area satisfactorily. Page 8

Bibliography Begg D, Fisher S & Dornbusch R (1994): Economics (4th edition), McGraw-Hill Friedman, M (1957): A Theory of the Consumption Function, Princeton University Press Keynes, JM (1936): The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money Maunder P, Myers D, Wall N & Miller RL (1991): Economics Explained (2nd edition), Collins Parkin M & Bade R (1995): Modern Macroeconomics, Prentice Hall Tim Miller, December 1996. Page 9