HARVARD MISREPORTING CORPORATE PERFORMANCE. Oren Bar-Gill Lucian Arye Bebchuk. This paper is a June 2003 revision of a paper



Similar documents
U + PV(Interest Tax Shield)

FIXED INCOME ATTRIBUTION

Financial Services [Applications]

The Tangled Web of Agricultural Insurance: Evaluating the Impacts of Government Policy

GUIDE TO LISTING ON NASDAQ OMX FIRST NORTH

The Tangled Web of Agricultural Insurance: Evaluating the Impacts of Government Policy

Risk and Return: Estimating Cost of Capital

Capital Structure. Itay Goldstein. Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania

UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN

Risk Arbitrage Performance for Stock Swap Offers with Collars

Why focus on assessment now?

Patch management is a crucial component of information security management. An important problem within

Options on Stock Indices, Currencies and Futures

An Anatomy of Futures Returns: Risk Premiums and Trading Strategies

Investment Analysis (FIN 670) Fall Homework 5

A performance analysis of EtherCAT and PROFINET IRT

Exchange Rate Volatility and the Timing of Foreign Direct Investment: Market-seeking versus Export-substituting

Financial Statement Presentation. Introduction. Staff draft of an exposure draft

School of Economics and Management

Research Summary Saltuk Ozerturk

A THEORETICAL FRAMEWORK FOR CHILD FOSTERING ARRANGEMENTS IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

HARVARD. Lucian Arye Bebchuk. Discussion Paper No /1997. As published in 3 The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics and the Law (1998)

Why Do Firms Announce Open-Market Repurchase Programs?

Capital Structure: Informational and Agency Considerations

FACTOR COMPONENTS OF INEQUALITY. Cecilia García-Peñalosa and Elsa Orgiazzi GINI DISCUSSION PAPER 12 JULY 2011 GROWING INEQUALITIES IMPACTS

Integrated airline scheduling

TOPIC 6: CAPITAL STRUCTURE AND THE MARKET FOR CORPORATE CONTROL

A logistic regression approach to estimating customer profit loss due to lapses in insurance

Course Information Form (CIF) - February QAP0021 Page 1 of 11

Public Policy and Market Competition: How the Master Settlement Agreement Changed the Cigarette Industry

anti-cyclical Europe housing future analyse investment education foreign growing demand Investing in European Student Housing Summary

A MPCP-Based Centralized Rate Control Method for Mobile Stations in FiWi Access Networks

A NOVEL ALGORITHM WITH IM-LSI INDEX FOR INCREMENTAL MAINTENANCE OF MATERIALIZED VIEW

Labor Demand. 1. The Derivation of the Labor Demand Curve in the Short Run:

Interaction of voluntary disclosure and earnings management

Global Review of Business and Economic Research GRBER Vol. 8 No. 2 Autumn 2012 : Jian Zhang *

How credit analysts view and use the financial statements

Executive compensation in companies with

AM Receiver. Prelab. baseband

STRATEGIC LIQUIDITY SUPPLY AND SECURITY DESIGN *

The Calculation of Marginal Effective Tax Rates

Power functions: f(x) = x n, n is a natural number The graphs of some power functions are given below. n- even n- odd

Maintenance Scheduling Optimization for 30kt Heavy Haul Combined Train in Daqin Railway

Stock Option Vesting Conditions, CEO Turnover, and Myopic Investment

Moral Hazard. Itay Goldstein. Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania

A FRAMEWORK FOR AUTOMATIC FUNCTION POINT COUNTING

Credible Discovery, Settlement, and Negative Expected Value Suits

Offshore Oilfield Development Planning under Uncertainty and Fiscal Considerations

Mechanism Design for Online Real-Time Scheduling

High School Students Who Take Acceleration Mechanisms Perform Better in SUS Than Those Who Take None

Appendix C White Paper to Support Bicycle Facility Design Toolkit on Lane Width Design Modifications DRAFT

Copyright 2005 IEEE. Reprinted from IEEE MTT-S International Microwave Symposium 2005

FINANCIAL ANALYSIS GUIDE

Pricing of Software Services

Introduction. Coverage. Principle 1: Embedded Value (EV) is a measure of the consolidated value of shareholders interests in the covered business.

INTERNATIONAL FRAMEWORK FOR ASSURANCE ENGAGEMENTS CONTENTS

Uses and Limitations of Ratio Analysis

Inflation. Chapter Money Supply and Demand

IFRS 13 Fair Value Measurement

No May Revenue from Contracts with Customers (Topic 606) An Amendment of the FASB Accounting Standards Codification

International Journal of Pure and Applied Sciences and Technology

Working Paper What happened to foreign outsourcing when firms went online?

Mining the Situation: Spatiotemporal Traffic Prediction with Big Data

Chapter 27: Taxation. 27.1: Introduction. 27.2: The Two Prices with a Tax. 27.2: The Pre-Tax Position

Notes - Gruber, Public Finance Chapter 20.3 A calculation that finds the optimal income tax in a simple model: Gruber and Saez (2002).

How Does Foreign Direct Investment Promote Economic Growth? Exploring the Effects of Financial Markets on Linkages

Department of Accounting and Finance

Rainfall generator for the Meuse basin

Quality differentiation and entry choice between online and offline markets

Reporting Service Performance Information

The Stewardship Role of Accounting

IASB. Request for Views. Effective Dates and Transition Methods. International Accounting Standards Board

Frequency Range Extension of Spectrum Analyzers with Harmonic Mixers

POLICY STATEMENT TO REGULATION RESPECTING INSIDER REPORTING FOR CERTAIN DERIVATIVE TRANSACTIONS (EQUITY MONETIZATION)

Darcy Friction Factor Formulae in Turbulent Pipe Flow

A Network Equilibrium Framework for Internet Advertising: Models, Quantitative Analysis, and Algorithms

A guide to investing in cash alternatives

Chapter 14. Understanding Financial Contracts. Learning Objectives. Introduction

Lecture 2: The nature of financial intermediation:

A Primer on Valuing Common Stock per IRS 409A and the Impact of FAS 157

United States of America Takeover Guide

Materiality and Audit Adjustments

Schooling, Political Participation, and the Economy. (Online Supplementary Appendix: Not for Publication)

THE MODELING AND CALCULATION OF SOUND RADIATION FROM FACILITIES WITH GAS FLOWED PIPES INTRODUCTION

An Empirical Analysis of Insider Rates vs. Outsider Rates in Bank Lending

VALUE %. $100, (=MATURITY

!!! Technical Notes : The One-click Installation & The AXIS Internet Dynamic DNS Service. Table of contents

Online Appendix Feedback Effects, Asymmetric Trading, and the Limits to Arbitrage

Appendix. Selected Financial Ratios Useful in Analytical Procedures

SIMPLIFIED CBA CONCEPT AND EXPRESS CHOICE METHOD FOR INTEGRATED NETWORK MANAGEMENT SYSTEM

Ending inventory: Ending Inventory = Goods available for sale Cost of goods sold Ending Inventory = $16,392 - $13,379 Ending Inventory = $3,013

Fair Value Measurement

Call Tracking & Google Analytics Integration

THE EFFECT OF SETTLEMENT IN KAPLOW S MULTISTAGE ADJUDICATION

Subordinated Debt and the Quality of Market Discipline in Banking by Mark Levonian Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco

8. ENERGY PERFORMANCE ASSESSMENT OF COMPRESSORS 8.1 Introduction

A Primer on Valuing Common Stock per IRS 409A and the Impact of Topic 820 (Formerly FAS 157)

HKAS 27 Consolidated and Separate Financial Statements 1

Transcription:

ISSN 145-6333 JON M. OIN CENTER FOR AW, ECONOMICS, AND BUSINESS ARVARD MISREPORTING CORPORATE PERFORMANCE Oren Bar-Gill ucian Arye Bebchuk This paper is a June 23 revision o a paper originally issued as Discussion Paper No. 4, December 22 arvard aw School Cambridge, MA 2138 The Center or aw, Economics, and Business is supported by a grant rom the John M. Olin Foundation. This paper can be downloaded without charge rom: The Social Science Research Network Electronic Paper Collection: http://papers.ssrn.com/abstract_id=354141 The original 12/22 version o this paper is paper can be downloaded without charge rom: The arvard John M. Olin Discussion Paper Series: http://www.law.harvard.edu/programs/olin_center/

ast revision: June 23 Misreporting Corporate Perormance Oren Bar-Gill arvard Society o Fellows (bargill@law.harvard.edu) ucian Arye Bebchuk arvard aw School and NBER (bebchuk@law.harvard.edu) Abstract This paper develops a model o the causes and consequences o misreporting o corporate perormance. Misreporting in our model covers all actions, whether legal or illegal, that enable managers o irms with low value to make statements that mimic those made by irms with high value. We show that even managers who cannot sell their shares in the short-term might misreport in order to improve the terms under which their company would be able to raise capital or new projects or acquisitions. When managers may sell some o their holdings in the short-term, incentives to misreport and the incidence o misreporting increase to an extent that depends on what raction o their holdings managers may sell and on whether they can sell without the market knowing about it. Investments in misreporting have real economic costs and distort inancing and investment decisions, with irms that misreport raising too much equity and irms that do not misreport raising too little. A lax accounting and legal environment increases the incidence o misreporting and consequently the distortions in capital allocation. Our analysis provides many testable predictions concerning the times, industries, and types o irms where misreporting is likely to occur. The analysis also has implications or corporate governance and executive compensation. JE classiication: G3, K22, M4 Keywords: Asymmetric inormation, acquisitions, corporate governance, disclosure, myopia, short-termism, executive compensation, stock options, insider trading, accounting, inancial statements, earnings management, auditor, inancial reporting. Copyright 23. Oren Bar-Gill and ucian Bebchuk. All rights reserved. We are grateul to Allen Ferrell, Jesse Fried, Oliver art, and participants in seminars at arvard and Michigan or their helpul suggestions and to the John M. Olin Center or aw, Economics, and Business at arvard aw School or its inancial support.

1. Introduction Recent events have directed much public attention to the reporting made to investors and the market by publicly traded companies. While the number o earnings restatements by publicly traded irms was on average 43 per year rom 199 to 1997, such restatements numbered 92 in 1997, 12 in 1998, 174 in 1999, 21 in 2, and 225 in 21. From January 1997 through June 22, about 1 percent o all listed companies announced at least one restatement (see Moriarty and ivingston (21), General Accounting Oice (22)). This paper investigates the causes and consequences o corporate misreporting. We deine misreporting as any action that enables low-value companies to report the same earnings, or revenues, or other dimensions o corporate perormance, as high-value companies report. This category includes, o course, cases in which companies get auditors to approve statements that are inconsistent with accounting standards. But it also includes cases in which companies with low long-term prospects take actions that are completely legal, being within accepted accounting and legal standards, to be able to make statements about the company s current perormance that make it impossible or investors to distinguish the company rom companies with high long-term prospects. We develop a model o why and when misreporting occurs and the distortions associated with misreporting. The model yields many testable predictions concerning the circumstances in which misreporting is more and less likely to occur. The model also has implications or corporate governance. It identiies the eiciency costs o misreporting and how these costs depend on corporate governance arrangements. To investigate the causes and consequences o misreporting, we study a ive-stage model. First, in the ex ante stage, managers decide how much to invest in creating opportunities to engage in short-term misreporting in the event that they subsequently learn that the irm is o a low-value type. Second, there is a stage in which managers learn inormation that suggests whether the expected long-term value o the irm s current projects is low or high. In this stage, managers are required (or at least may choose) to make statements to the market about short-term perormance. Managers o highvalue irms are always able to report positive short-term results. Managers o low-value irms might sometimes be able to make such statements, say by engaging in earnings management or creative accounting, with the probability o their being in a position to do so depending on their earlier 1

investments in creating opportunities to misreport. We reer to the making o such statements by low-value irms as misreporting even when there is nothing illegal or alse in the statements made. Third, the learning o inormation and disclosure decisions stage is ollowed by market trading in the irm s shares. Fourth, the irm operates and might have an opportunity to engage in a new project or acquisition that would require raising additional capital. In the ith and inal stage, payos rom the irm s initial projects, and whatever additional project i any was added in the ourth stage, are realized and distributed. Our model is one in which markets engage in rational pricing. Investors do not know what managers private inormation is, but they are aware o the possibility that managers will misreport, and they draw rational inerences rom whatever they know o the managers actions as to what the managers likely inormation is. We start with the case in which managers may not sell their own shares in the intermediate trading stage and must keep all o their shares until the inal period. Even in this case, where managers must keep their shares until values are ully realized, and in which managers interests are aligned with those o long-term shareholders, managers might have an incentive to invest in creating opportunities to misreport and to misreport when they can do so. When an opportunity to raise equity to inance an acquisition or a new project arises, misreporting enables the managers who learn that the irm s current projects are o low value to pool themselves with irms with existing projects o high-value and in this way improve the terms upon which they would be able to raise capital. The initial shareholders (including the managers) o irms with existing projects whose value is lower than estimated by the market will be made better o i they will be able to obtain new capital on avorable terms, i.e., or a price exceeding what the outside investors are getting and the initial shareholders are giving up. This motive or misreporting might be especially important in circumstances in which irms are engaged in a series o stock-inance acquisitions. Whereas misreporting might take place even when managers must keep their shares until the inal realization period, the beneits to managers rom misreporting, and the incidence o misreporting, increase in the case in which managers may sell some o their shares in the intermediate trading period. When managers who learn that their projects have a low expected value can and do misreport, the misreporting would enable them to gain by selling shares during the intermediate period. The selling o shares by managers o 2

Enron enabled them to get out with substantial value beore the market learned that the irm s value was substantially lower than expected. The extent to which managers would gain rom misreporting, and thus the increased incentive to do so, would depend on the raction o the managers shares that they are permitted to sell. Thus, the greater managers reedom to sell holdings in the short-run, the greater the incentive to misreport. The extent to which managers short-run selling can increase their gains rom misreporting depends also on whether the market can tell whether such selling is taking place. The market s ability to identiy managerial selling in turn depends on whether and how requently sales must be disclosed, the existence o trading windows, and the amount o shares managers might seek to sell relative to the ordinary volume o trading arising rom liquidity selling. When the market knows or suspects that the managers are selling, the market price will decline to relect an increased probability that the irm s managers have been misreporting; this would reduce the proits that misreporting managers would be able to make by selling their shares in the intermediate trading period. owever, as long as the market would not be able to tell whether known or suspected sales by managers are due to managers knowledge o negative inormation or due to managers liquidity needs, allowing managers to sell shares in the intermediate trading period will increase their gain rom misreporting and their incentive to invest in creating opportunities to misreport. One eature o our model is that the incidence o misreporting is endogenously determined and is a unction o ex ante investments (such as in how operations and inancial structures are set). 1 These investments are inluenced by various parameters o the irm, the industry, and the managers compensation package, which aect the potential beneits rom misreporting. These investments are also inluenced by the technology o misreporting, which is a unction o legal and accounting rules (and the implementing institutional inrastructure) that are in place. Our model has signiicant descriptive implications. The model can help shed light on the increase in misreporting in the second hal o the 9 s. It identiies several actors that might have played a role in this increase. To begin, consider the many companies whose value was based primarily on uture growth opportunities. For these companies, the dierence between good and bad inormation about current operations (or example, about 1 Erickson et al. (22) provides evidence that irms are willing to incur costs to be in a position to misreport. 3

current revenues), which has little direct eect on the irm s value, could still lead to a large dierence in the market s estimate o the irm s uture growth and business opportunities and thus o the expected uture value o the irm s projects. Furthermore, the 9 s were a period in which managers opportunities to sell large amounts o shares in the short-run was substantial. Speciically, the use o large stock option grants in compensation schemes became more common, and in the case o many high-tech irms, managers had some signiicant pre-ipo holdings that they were able to sell on the market. Finally, because o reductions in the potential liability o auditors and the structure o auditor services, auditors became more likely to acquiesce to misreporting by the audited irm (Coee, 22). As a result, the likelihood that a irm was able to misreport or any given level o prior investment in creating opportunities to misreport -- went up. Our analysis provides a wide range o testable predictions concerning the circumstances in terms o the period, the industry, the irm, and the managers payos -- in which misreporting is more and less likely to occur. Throughout, we identiy relationships between the likelihood o misreporting and such parameters. Some o these relationships are consistent with already existing evidence, and others could be tested by uture empirical work. Our model also has corporate governance and policy implications. The analysis highlights that the phenomenon o misreporting does not have only distributive consequences but also gives rise to potentially signiicant eiciency costs. One type o cost arises rom deadweight investments in creating opportunities to misreport and pool one s irm with irms o higher value. Roychowdhury (23) recently documents the costs to operation and eicient perormance that companies incur in order to report higher earnings. Another, probably more important cost arises rom distorting the allocative role o capital markets. When some low value irms can misreport and thereby pool themselves with high-value irms, the inancing and investment decisions o both types o irms will be distorted. In the pooling equilibrium caused by misreporting, high-value irms will be cross-subsidizing those lowvalue irms whose managers will misreport. Because o this compelled crosssubsidization, high-value irms might orgo some eicient projects to avoid the need to raise capital, whereas some low-value irms that misreport might raise equity even when they do not have eicient projects. As a result, there will be under-investment by irms that do not misreport and over-investment 4

by irms that do. The existence o such real economic costs can be expected to reduce ex ante share value. Thus, arrangements that encourage misreporting can have a negative eect on share value. In our model, lax rules, which make it more likely that a irm will be able to misreport given its investment in creating opportunities to do so, are shown to increase the incidence o misreporting. An important role o rules and institutions in our context is not simply to penalize some instances o misreporting ex post but also to aect the ex ante set o misreporting opportunities. Our analysis supports the calls by participants in public policy discussions (see, e.g., evitt (1998)) or rigorous accounting standards and implementing institutions, which can narrow irms degrees o reedom to engage in misreporting. Our analysis also shows how the incidence o misreporting and its associated costs can be inluenced by the design o corporate governance arrangements. We ind that any increase in the raction o managers holdings which they may sell beore the inal period will increase incentives to invest in creating opportunities to misreport and the incidence o misreporting. We also ind that arrangements that eliminate or reduce the ability o managers to sell without the market s knowledge such as the recent legislative mandate that all trading by managers be very promptly disclosed can reduce but not eliminate the adverse incentives created by managers reedom to unload holdings in the short-run. 2 It is worth noting, however, that the incentives to invest in misreporting would decrease, but not be ully eliminated by arrangements that require or encourage managers to keep their shares or the long haul. Thus, while such arrangements might be helpul in addressing the problem o misreporting, their adoption would not make the problem (and thus the accounting and legal measures that can constrain it) irrelevant. An important line o work related to ours is that modeling managerial short-termism and myopia (see, e.g., Stein (1988, 1989) and Bebchuk and Stole (1993)). In the myopia literature, managers are assumed to give some exogenously stipulated weight to short-run and long-run stock prices; as Stein (1989) observes, this assumption is equivalent to managers being required to sell a given raction o their holdings (or to issue to the public a given number o new shares) in the intermediate trading stage (Stein, 1989). In contrast, we 2 Our analysis thus reinorces the concerns long expressed about possible links between agency problems and speciically, ones produced by short-term components o executive compensation and managerial misreporting (see, e.g., ealy and Palepu (1993) and Benabou and aroque (1992). 5

allow or the possibility that, as is usually the case, managers have the option, but are not required, to issue new shares and/or sell some o their own shares in the trading stage. In our model, managers use this option in some circumstances but not others, and managers use o their private inormation to decide when to do so signiicantly aects our results. Another dierence between our model and the myopia literature is that this literature develops models in which there is one type o irm whose value is unobservable but is, in equilibrium, accurately anticipated. In contrast, in our model, there are in equilibrium both low-value and high-value irms which are pooled together in the short-run trading period - a pooling that produces distortions in subsequent investment and inancing decisions. This eature o our model provides many testable predictions not suggested by the myopia models. Our analysis is also related, o course, to the large body o theoretical literature on disclosure by irms. 3 Although a substantial part o this literature assumes that insiders can veriiably disclose all the inormation they have (see Verrecchia (21), pp. 142-143), several models have allowed or alse or misleading reporting by irms (see, e.g., Dye (1988), Fishman and agerty (199), Benabou and aroque (1992), Arya et al. (1998), Verrecchia (21) and ambert (21, sec. 5)). owever, these models dier rom ours in some o the key elements that it includes, such as the endogenous ex ante determination o opportunities to misreport, the explicit link between misreporting and subsequent inancing and investment decisions, and the explicit link between the compensation contracts and holdings o managers and their disclosure decisions. Yet another related line o work ocuses on how asymmetric inormation aects decisions to issue equity (see, e.g., Myers and Majlu (1984), ucas and McDonald (199, 1992) and Korajczyk, ucas and McDonald (1991)) or decisions whether to make a stock-based acquisition (see, e.g., Shleier and Vishny (23) and Jovanovic and Braguisnsky (22)). We incorporate the eects o asymmetric inormation and capital and investment decisions into our analysis and connect them to the problem o misreporting. In our model, the level o asymmetric inormation, which aects decisions whether to raise equity to inance an acquisition o a new project, is determined endogenously as a unction o irms level misreporting. 3 Verrecchia (21), Dye (21) and Fishman and agerty (1998) oer good surveys o this literature. 6

Our analysis is organized as ollows. Section 2 presents our ramework o analysis. Section 3 analyzes reporting and investment decisions in the case in which managers must keep their shares until the inal realization period. Section 4 analyzes these decisions in the case in which managers are permitted to sell at least some o their shares beore the inal period. Section 5 concludes. 2. Framework o Analysis 2.1 Sequence o Events The sequence o events in the model is as ollows: T=: Initial situation with (initially) identical publicly traded irms each run by a manager. T=1: Managers may invest in creating opportunities or uture misreporting o corporate perormance. T=2: earning o inormation and disclosure decisions managers learn inormation pertaining to the companies expected inal cash lows and make disclosures about the irm s current perormance. T=3: Market trading. T=4: Investment and inancing decisions the company may have an opportunity or a potentially beneicial project that would require raising additional capital. T=5: Realization o payos. The initial situation Creating opportunities to misreport earning o inormation and disclosure decisions Market trading Financing and investment decisions Payos realized 1 2 3 4 5 T Fig. 1: Sequence o Events We now speciy the assumptions regarding each one o the six stages. 7

2.2 T=: Initial Situation At T=, all companies are publicly traded, and each irm has an existing project and is run by a manager. 4 Without loss o generality, we assume that at T= each company has one issued share that is held by initial shareholders including the company s manager. The manager holds a raction β o the company s stock. (The results would be essentially the same assuming that the manager has an option to purchase a raction β o the company s stock.) The manager is assumed to be cash-constrained and thus cannot purchase additional equity. 5 We shall abstract rom other incentives that the manger might have (e.g., due to the threat o a control contest) and will assume that the manager will be making decisions or the irm in all o the model s periods. We will urther assume that the manager s interest in enhanced share value comes solely rom the speciied holding o shares. We initially assume that, due to legal or contractual constraints, managers may not sell shares at the T=3 market trading stage. Thereore, the manager s objective is to maximize the price o the company s stock at the inal period. This assumption will be relaxed in Section 4, which will allow or managerial selling o shares in the intermediate trading period. The T= value o a company, which is also the T= market price o the company s share, is denoted by P. 2.3 T=1: Creating Opportunities or Misreporting Investments in creating opportunities to misreport i.e., to make positive disclosures even when long-term prospects are unavorable -- are + determined endogenously. At T=1 the manager invests C R in creating opportunities or uture misreporting o unavorable inormation concerning corporate perormance. 6 Speciically, given an investment C at T=1, i the 4 We take the existing project as given; Bar-Gill and Bebchuk (23b) explore how some o the agency problems analyzed in this paper aect the choice o projects. 5 I managers can purchase equity, then they may have an incentive to misreport down, whereas in our model they only have an incentive to misreport up. 6 We assume that C is not observable to the market (although the market will be able to anticipate the level o C at equilibrium). Otherwise, managers would be able to eectively commit to truthul reporting simply by setting C =. Indeed, i C were observable and veriiable, we would expect shareholders (or those who took the irm public) to require managers (through corporate charters or contracts with the managers) not to invest in creation o opportunities to misreport. 8

manager learns negative inormation at T=2, she will be able to misreport ~ ~ ~ with probability δ = λ δ ( C ). We assume that λ, δ ' ( C ) >, δ ' ' ( C) < and ~ δ ' (). 7 ~ The unction λ δ ( C ) represents the various legal and institutional actors in the economy that deine the available misreporting technology. Many actors inluence this technology, including legal rules, accounting standards and conventions, the structure o the accounting industry and accounting services (which in turn aect the ability o managers to inluence auditors to go along), and the intensity o outside monitoring (by analysts, plainti lawyers, the inancial press, etc.) A higher λ represents a more lax environment that makes it easier to misreport. 8 Theoretically, the investment C may create opportunities or misreporting o avorable inormation as well. Moreover, managers can perhaps invest in creating additional opportunities or misreporting C g avorable inormation. owever, it can be readily shown that managers will never misreport, announcing that their inormation is negative, when in act it is positive. It ollows that managers will not have any reason to invest in creating opportunities to hide avorable inormation. Thereore, without loss o generality, we assume that the investment C creates only opportunities to misreport unavorable inormation. 2.4 T=2: earning o Inormation and Disclosure Decisions At T=2 the manager o each company learns whether the company s existing project is promising or not. Speciically, the manager will learn 7 An alternative assumption would be that C can be invested ater the company s type is revealed (at T=2). Similar results will hold under this alternative assumption. Fischer and Verrecchia (2) study a model where misreporting is costly (they study a singleperiod model, so the question when the cost o distorting the report is incurred does not come up). 8 We shall, or simplicity o exposition, assume that the level o λ is given by the environment and is not a parameter chosen by the irm itsel. O course, although the environment clearly plays a key role in shaping the scope o misreporting opportunities, companies might be able to adopt observable arrangements that inluence the level o λ. Our model can be easily extended to the case in which the environment deines a range o values or λ rom which irms can choose. In our model, i companies could lower λ in an observable ashion, it would be ex ante optimal or shareholders to do so. Accordingly, one can simply interpret the analysis below assuming that the λ it uses is the lowest possible given the legal and institutional environment. 9

whether the company is a low-value, type company, or a high-value, type company. The expected value o the inal (T=5) payo rom the irm s existing assets is V or type irms and V or type irms, with V > V. We denote the dierence between the two expected values as V = V V. The probability that the manager will learn that the irm is type (type ) is θ ( 1 θ ). Managers inormation about the irm s type is unobservable (even to the irm s auditors), and managers are not required to make any statements about this inormation. Managers, however, are required to make statements at T=2 about the company s current perormance. The statements might concern current igures pertaining to revenues, costs, earnings, and the like, as well as current actions such as the establishment o strategic or other relations, and so orth. For concreteness we assume that managers are required to state an earnings igure (e.g. in the company s inancial statements), E { E, E }, where E > E. We denote by E the dierence between low and high earnings ( E = E E ). We also denote by µ the ratio V E, i.e., the ratio between the dierence in value between type and type projects and the dierence between the two possible earning igures. We assume that, i the company is type, then managers will always be able to report at T=2 a high earnings igure,. I the company is type, its manager will always be able to report a low earnings igure,. owever, a manager o a type irm might also be able to report a high earnings igure. Speciically, there is a probability δ -- where δ is determined by the T=1 investments as already described -- that the manager o a type irm will be able to report a high earnings igure. 9 It is worth noting that all o our results also apply to the case in which disclosure at T=2 is voluntary. All the irms that announce high earning igures in the mandatory disclosure case will also elect to make such statements in the voluntary disclosure case, and all the irms that announce low earning igures in the mandatory disclosure case will be silent in the voluntary disclosure case. The discussion below will use the mandatory disclosure model, but we will on occasion note the particular voluntary disclosure interpretation o our results. E E 9 Recall that in our model whether or not a company has the opportunity to misreport depends on investments that are undertaken beore the manager learns the company s type ( or ). Our model can be adjusted to allow or investments in creating opportunities to misreport that are undertaken ater the manager learns the company s type. 1

Investors at T=2 only observe the manager s statement about current perormance. They make whatever inerences can be rationally drawn rom the manager s announcement. The T=2 market price o the company s share will be denoted by 2 P. 2.5 T=3: Market Trading At T=3 market trading occurs, because some shareholders must sell or 3 liquidity reasons, and a price P is set or the company s stock. Given our current assumption that legal or contractual restrictions prevent the manager rom trading at T=3, the T=3 price cannot relect any new inormation, i.e. 3 2 P = P. 2.6 T=4: Investment and Financing Decisions At T=4, the manager might learn -- with probability γ -- o a potential new and proitable project. This project requires an investment K. Our analysis can be viewed as covering both the case in which this capital is needed to build the new project rom scratch and the case in which this capital is needed to acquire another company. The project will increase the inal cash low by K + R, where R is distributed over R + ( =, ) with a positive and continuous pd (R) and a cd (R). et [ ) F E( R) R = denote the average return o the new project. Note that or now we are assuming that the new project, i it emerges, would be an eicient one, with the uncertainty being only about its proitability, but we shall drop this assumption and allow or ineicient projects in Section 3.6. The manager knows R at T=4. The market, however, knows only the distribution (R). In the event that the company elects to raise capital, the market will also make whatever inerences can be drawn rom the manager s T=2 announcement and the T=4 decision to raise capital. The T=4 market 4 price o the company s stock is denoted by P. We shall or now assume that the company can raise capital only by issuing equity; Section 3.7 will consider the case o issuing debt. In the case o inancing an acquisition, the new equity might be given directly to the shareholders o the acquired company or it might be sold to third parties and the cash obtained orm them given to the selling shareholders. We shall denote by αˆ the number o new shares that would have to be sold to raise K through issuing new equity. Selling αˆ shares would involve giving up a 11

ˆ α raction α = o the company s T=5 total cash lows, and it will be 1+ ˆ α convenient to use α, rather than αˆ, in the mathematical derivations. et α ( E ) and α ( E ) denote the ractions o the company that will need to be sold in order to raise K when managers announce E and E, respectively. 2.7 T=5: Realization o Payos At T=5, all cash lows are realized. The company s initial project will produce cash lows o V + εo, where V { V, V } and ε O is a random zeromean noise. The company s new project, i one was undertaken at T=4, will produce cash lows o K + R + ε N, where ε N is a random zero-mean noise. I at T=1 the company invested in creating opportunities to misreport its earnings at T=2, cash lows are reduced by the cost C o doing so. The inal T=5 stock price is denoted by P. Note that the presence o noise implies that it is not possible to iner clearly rom a company s T=5 cash lows whether or not misreporting took place at T=2. When a company reported high earnings at T=2, a relatively low value at T=5 could be due to an unavorable realization o uncertainty rather than to misreporting at T=2. O course, while the model assumes that whether misreporting occurred is not directly observable, in reality ex post investigations sometimes unearth evidence that misreporting took place. We shall assume or simplicity that no ex post penalties will be imposed at T=5. Our model, however, can be easily extended to the case in which misreporting is penalized ex post with some probability. In such a case, misreporting will take place only i the beneits rom it, as derived below, exceed the expected sanction. The results presented below are qualitatively robust to such an extension (adding this threshold condition or misreporting). 3. Reporting and Investment Decisions As is conventional, we solve the model by backward induction, starting with the T=4 inancing and investment decisions. We irst examine how decisions at this stage would be made i no misreporting took place earlier. We then study how these decisions would be made in the presence o misreporting. 12

3.1 Financing and Investment Decisions Without Misreporting Consider irst the benchmark case in which no company can misreport, so that at T=2 companies report E and companies report E. In this case, since R, all companies that ace a new project will issue equity and raise K to und it. Assuming no misreporting, let α α α α ( ) and ( ) E E denote the ractions o the company that need to be sold in order to raise K when managers announce E and E, respectively. Speciically, in order to raise K: companies will sell a raction α ( V + K + R ) = K ; and companies will sell a raction ( + K + R ) K V = α. Clearly, α o the company such that α o the company such that α > α, i.e. companies will have to sell a larger raction o their T=5 cash lows in order to und the new project. In the no misreporting case, the expected inal T=5 per-share prices or and companies are E( P ) = ( α ) ( V + K + R) E( P ) = ( α ) ( V + K R + 1 and 1 ), respectively. 1 In this model, these will be the manager s (per-share) payos, depending on her company s type. Thereore, the manager will always sell equity to inance the new project. A manager acing a below average new project, i.e. R < R, will clearly sell equity to inance this new project. This manager enjoys both the positive revenues rom the new project and a cross-subsidization eect that lowers the number o shares that must be sold to raise K. A manager acing an above average new project, i.e. R > R, will also sell equity to inance the new project, since the high revenues more than oset the cross-subsidization eect. 11 1 The expected T=5 cash lows o the company are V + K + R or companies and V + K + R or companies. To get the per-share market price, we divide these values by the number o outstanding shares, 1+ αˆ. Recall that α = ˆ α ( 1+ ˆ α ), which implies 1 + ˆ α = 1 ( 1 α ). 11 Formally, the manager will sell equity i and only i ( 1 α ) ( V + K + R) > V, where α satisies α ( V + K + R ) = K R K R ( V + R ). This condition can be rewritten (ater some rearranging) as >, which implies that the manager will sell equity or all R. 13

3.2 Financing and Investment Decisions with Misreporting In our model, some irms might have an opportunity to misreport at T=2. When companies with an opportunity to misreport mimic companies and announce, the market cannot distinguish between these E two types o companies. Consequently, a single pooling price is set or all the companies that announce. et α α denote the raction o the E ( ) P E E T=5 cash lows that a company that announces will have to sell in order to und a new project when (some) companies misreport earnings. Speciically, in order to raise K, managers must sell a raction α P o the company such that α Π K, where Π is the expected value o a company P = conditional on the act that the company reported This expected value is given by: E and is selling equity. Π = V [ R ] ρ, ( θ δ Pr( sell) ρ ) V + K + θ δ Pr( sell) R + (1 θ ) Pr( sell) where Pr( sell) is the probability that an company that misreports and has a new project sells equity, Pr( sell) is the probability that an company that has a new project sells equity, ρ = θ δ Pr ( sell) + (1 θ ) Pr( sell) is the overall probability that a company that has a project and reported E sells equity, R is the expected value o the proit rom an company s new project conditional on the company announcing and selling equity, and R is the expected value o the proit rom an company s new project conditional on the company selling equity. To proceed, we need to derive the probabilities Pr( sell) and Pr( sell) and to identiy the circumstances in which each type o company sells equity. This is done in the ollowing proposition. Proposition 1: When companies that can misreport do so at T=2, then, in the event that a proitable new project emerges at T=4 - (i) Managers o companies, both those that misreported and those that did not, will always sell equity to und the project. (ii) Managers o companies will sell equity i and only i the proitability o the new project exceeds a threshold equation: E Rˆ, which is deined by the ollowing 14

θ δ R + (1 θ ) Rˆ θ δ + (1 θ ) R ( R) dr θ δ V ( 1 F( Rˆ ) V ˆ R + K + Rˆ when V > R ω, and which equals zero when V R ω. =, Remark: The intuition or this result, whose proo is provided in the Appendix, is as ollows: In the no misreporting case, we have seen that managers will always sell equity to inance new projects. Introducing misreporting by companies adds a cross-subsidization eect, which stems rom the pooling between companies and companies that misreport earnings. This cross-subsidization will make misreporting companies all the more eager to sell equity in order to inance their new projects, because they will now need to sell ewer shares at T=4 (compared with the case in which there is no misreporting). The same cross-subsidization eect might prevent companies rom pursuing new projects, since they will now need to sell more shares at T=4 in order to raise K. Speciically, companies acing a proitable, yet insuiciently attractive project, i.e. a new project with R < ˆ, will orgo the new project. From proposition 1, we know that companies that misreport earnings ρ = θ δ + ( 1 θ ) Pr sell. will always sell equity, i.e. ( sell) 1 Pr =. Thereore, ( ) Since the proportion o companies among companies that announce sell equity is o central importance, we deine companies sell equity, i.e. i = and ˆ R E and ω θ δ ρ. Also, i all R ( sell) 1 Pr =, we deine θ δ ω =. Using these deinitions, we can state the ollowing θ δ + (1 θ ) Corollary. Corollary 1 (Eiciency Costs): As long as the dierence between and types satisies V > R ω, then - (i) Some Companies will not inance and invest in new eicient projects. 15

(ii) The likelihood that an company will not inance and invest in a new eicient project that it aces is increasing in the threshold value Rˆ, which Rˆ in turn is an increasing unction o V and µ : Rˆ > and >. 12 V µ ( ) (iii) Among companies that announce, companies that misreport earnings will be more likely to raise capital. Remark 1 (intuition): The intuition or this result, whose proo is provided in the Appendix, is as ollows: (i) In the symmetric inormation case, absent cross-subsidization o companies, companies will always sell equity to pursue the new project i it emerges. Misreporting introduces the cross-subsidization eect, which imposes an additional cost, ω V, on companies that sell equity. When this cross-subsidization cost is suiciently small ( ω V < R ), then companies will always sell equity even in the presence o misreporting. owever, when the cross-subsidization eect is signiicant (speciically, i ω V > R ), companies will sell equity only when acing a new project that is suiciently proitable, namely when R > ˆ. (ii) When the cross-subsidization eect is signiicant, i.e. when ω V > R, companies will orgo eicient projects with R < ˆ. Thereore, the likelihood that an company will not inance and invest in new eicient projects is increasing in Rˆ. The threshold value, Rˆ, depends on the magnitude o the crosssubsidization loss that companies must bear i they choose to sell equity, as measured by ω V. When the dierence between the expected value o the initial projects o and companies, V, is larger, the cross-subsidization eect is also larger. Put dierently, since V = µ E, when the impact o misreported earnings on the estimate o the T=5 inal value (as measured by µ ) is greater, the cross-subsidization eect is larger. Note that, when ω V > R and ˆ >, companies might not raise capital to und eicient projects. Speciically they will not undertake projects with R, ˆ. Thereore, The possibility o misreporting might lead to ( ) R allocative ineiciency, generating a real economic cost. 12 For this part o the corollary it is necessary to assume that ( ) precise condition is provided in the proo in the Appendix). 16 R E R R R ˆ is not too large (the

announces (iii) When ω V > which all also announce new project, with R > ˆ announce sell equity. E E R E R, each type company that misreports and will sell equity. On the other hand, among the companies,, only companies acing a suiciently proitable, will sell equity. ence, among companies which, those that misreport earnings are subsequently more likely to Remark 2 (empirical implications): Corollary 1 provides us with the ollowing testable predictions or uture empirical work: (i) Companies that restate earnings, or are otherwise ound to have misreported, are more likely to have subsequently sold equity. This prediction is consistent with recent empirical evidence documented by ang and undholm (2). 13 (ii) The greater the magnitude o the misreporting o earnings, or the more signiicant the misreporting in terms o its implication or the expected inal value, the more likely it is to be ollowed by an equity sale. 14 3.3 The Reporting Decision Ater analyzing the T=4 inancing and investment decisions, we now move one step backwards in time, and solve or the T=2 decision o companies whether to misreport earnings. 15 Proposition 2: In the unique equilibrium, all companies that can misreport at T=2 will elect to do so. 13 Palmrose and Scholz (2) and Palmrose, Richardson and Scholz (21) collect data on restatements by companies. Assuming that restatements are at least correlated with misreporting, this type o data can be used to test the predictions derived rom our theoretical model. 14 When V (or µ ) are higher, the threshold Rˆ is higher, which means that ewer companies sell equity. Since companies always sell equity, i ewer companies sell equity, then rom the pool o companies that announce E and sell equity, the share o misreporting companies increases. Consequently, the correlation between misreporting and selling equity increases. 15 Since we are currently assuming that managers cannot sell stock at T=3, we can skip period 3. 17

Remark 1 (intuition): The intuition or this result, whose detailed proo is omitted, is as ollows: The existing shareholders o an company clearly gain rom announcing E reports (rather than E E ). Whatever the other companies report, i an company the market will assign a larger probability that the company is o type, as compared to the case in which the company announces. ence, misreporting will reduce the cost o raising capital. And, since misreporting is costless at T=2 (the cost C o creating opportunities to misreport is sunk at this stage), misreporting would be a dominant strategy or the managers o any company that can misreport. Note that, given that managers have opportunities to misreport, shareholders o companies will beneit rom their managers doing so; this is the case even though, as will be discussed (see proposition 4), shareholders might be better o ex ante under a regime that provides managers with ewer opportunities to misreport. Remark 2 (the gain rom misreporting): As noted above, the gain rom misreporting derives rom the more avorable terms or raising equity i.e., rom having to sell ewer shares to inance the new project. In particular, without misreporting an company will have to sell a raction α o the company such that α ( + K + R ) K, leaving it with an expected value o ( α ) ( + K R V + V = 1 ). In contrast, an company that misreports will need to sell only a raction α P o the company, deined by α P Π = initial shareholders with an expected value o ( 1 α P ) ( V K + R ) E K, leaving the +. Thereore, recalling that a new project will emerge with probability γ, the gain rom misreporting is ( α ) ( V + K R ) G = γ α. P + The gain rom misreporting can be shown to depend on the model s parameters as ollows. The gain rom misreporting is increasing in the probability that a new project will become available, γ. Also, the gain rom misreporting is decreasing in expected value o a company that announces α P, or equivalently is increasing in Π, the and sells equity. Since Π is decreasing in δ, the gain rom misreporting is also decreasing in δ. Intuitively, when the level o misreporting is higher, the market will know that among companies announcing there are more companies. Consequently, the market will oer a lower price per-share or companies that announces, reducing the gain rom misreporting. Finally, the gain E rom misreporting is increasing in E E V (or µ ). When the dierence in value 18

between companies and companies is greater, companies have more to gain rom pooling with companies. 3.4 Creating Opportunities to Misreport At T=1 managers decide how much to invest in creating opportunities to misreport earnings. The equilibrium level o this investment decision is characterized in the ollowing proposition. * Proposition 3: In the unique equilibrium, all companies invest C at T=1 in * ~ * creating opportunities to misreport, where C is deined by λ δ '( C * ) G ( δ ( C ) = 1. * The overall level o misreporting, ( C ) δ, is - (i) Increasing in the laxity o the legal and accounting environment, as measured by λ ; (ii) increasing in the probability that a company will ace a new project, γ ; (iii) increasing in the magnitude o the dierence in value between and companies, V, and thus in the signiicance o the misreporting or the expected inal value, as measured by µ. Remark 1 (intuition): The intuition or this result, whose proo is provided in the Appendix, is as ollows: A single manager has no inluence on the overall level o misreporting, * and thereore takes ( C ) δ as given in her T=1 decision concerning how much to invest in creating opportunities to misreport. The manager thereore will * λ ~ δ ' C G δ C exceeds the increase C as long as the marginal beneit o ( ) ( ( ) marginal cost: 16 (i) When the legal and accounting environment is more lax, the marginal beneit o investment in creating opportunities to misreport in terms o the increased probability o being able to misreport is larger. Consequently, by 16 * Given δ ( C ) ~ δ '( C) G( δ ( C * )) = 1 * and consequently o δ ( C) must induce the aggregate level o misreporting, ( C ) ence the condition: ~ * ~ λ δ '( C ) G( δ ( C * ) = 1. Since both δ '( C) and G ( ( C)) ~ * decreasing in C, the condition δ '( C * ) G( δ ( C ) = 1, there is a unique investment level, C, that satisies the FOC, λ. At equilibrium, the many individual managerial choices o C, investment in creating opportunities to misreport. 19 δ. δ are λ deines a unique level o

reducing the laxity o the legal and accounting environment, we may be able to reduce the incidence o misreporting. (ii) As explained in section 3.3, the gain rom misreporting is increasing in the probability that a new project will emerge. Thereore, when the probability γ increases, managers will invest more in creating opportunities to misreport. (iii) As explained in section 3.3, the gain rom misreporting is increasing in the dierence between the value o and companies, V, i.e., in the signiicance o the misreporting or the estimated expected inal value, µ. Thereore, when V and opportunities to misreport. µ are higher, managers will invest more in creating Remark 2 (empirical implications): The results stated in proposition 3 provide the ollowing testable predictions: (i) The result stated in part (i) o proposition 3 is consistent with empirical evidence regarding the positive eects o switching to more strict accounting standards (see euz and Verrecchia (2)). 17 It is also consistent with evidence indicating that managers take advantage o minimal disclosure requirements to engage in earnings management (see obo and Zhou (21)). Furthermore, since the eectiveness o any set o legal or accounting standards and practices varies across industries, proposition 3(i) suggests cross-sectional variations in the level o misreporting. This result is consistent with recent empirical evidence documenting more severe real eects o earnings manipulation in R&D intensive companies where existing accounting standards provide or only limited transparency (see Polk and Sapienza (22) and Aboody and ev (2)). (ii) The result stated in part (ii) o proposition 3 suggests the ollowing testable predictions: (a) Cross-sectionally, in industries where companies are likely to ace new opportunities that require additional capital, misreporting o earnings is more likely to occur. (b) Comparing dierent time periods, in periods when more companies ace such new opportunities, misreporting o earnings is more likely to occur. Relatedly, in periods when there are many equity oerings, misreporting o earnings is more likely to occur. 17 euz and Verrecchia (2) document the lower bid-ask spreads and higher trade volumes enjoyed by German irms that switched rom the German reporting regime to an international reporting regime (IAS or U.S. GAAP). 2

(iii) The result stated in part (iii) o proposition 3 provides the ollowing testable predictions: (a) Cross-sectionally, in industries where the impact o misreported earnings on the estimated inal value (as measured by µ ) is greater, misreporting is more likely to occur. In particular, in growth industries where the earnings to value multiplier is large, misreporting is more likely to occur. This prediction is consistent with the evidence that inormation asymmetries are especially large in R&D intensive industries, assuming that R&D intensity is correlated with growth opportunities (see Aboody and ev (2)). In such industries, misreporting is more likely to occur. (b) Comparing dierent time periods, in periods when managerial misreporting has a large impact (as measured by µ ) on the estimated value o the initial project, misreporting is more likely to occur. 3.5 The Ex Ante Cost o Misreporting We can now state the magnitude o the eiciency cost generated by misreporting. Proposition 4: Misreporting generates an expected eiciency cost o: * Φ = C + γ 1 θ Pr R < Rˆ E R R < ˆ. ( ) ( ) ( R ) Thereore, with misreporting, the ex ante T= value is reduced by Φ to V = V θ V + γ R Φ. The eiciency cost, Φ, and thus the reduction in ex ante value, are - (i) increasing in the probability that a company will ace a new project, γ ; (ii) increasing in the magnitude o the dierence between and companies, V, and thus in the signiicance o the misreporting or the expected inal value, as measured by µ. Remark 1 (intuition): The intuition or this result, whose detailed proo is omitted, is as ollows: Misreporting leads to two types o eiciency costs, which are relected in the two elements o Φ : * (1) The deadweight cost o creating opportunities to misreport, C, including costly distortions in real activities (see Roychowdhury (23)). (2) Ineicient investment decisions: With probability γ the company aces a new eicient project. owever, i this company is o type (the probability 21