INVESTMENT DECISIONS and PROFIT MAXIMIZATION



Similar documents
INTEREST RATES A BAROMETER of the REAL ECONOMY

= C + I + G + NX ECON 302. Lecture 4: Aggregate Expenditures/Keynesian Model: Equilibrium in the Goods Market/Loanable Funds Market

Agenda. Productivity, Output, and Employment, Part 1. The Production Function. The Production Function. The Production Function. The Demand for Labor

2. With an MPS of.4, the MPC will be: A) 1.0 minus.4. B).4 minus 1.0. C) the reciprocal of the MPS. D).4. Answer: A

The Short-Run Macro Model. The Short-Run Macro Model. The Short-Run Macro Model

Answers to Text Questions and Problems. Chapter 22. Answers to Review Questions

Lesson 7 - The Aggregate Expenditure Model

Answers to Text Questions and Problems in Chapter 8

13. If Y = AK 0.5 L 0.5 and A, K, and L are all 100, the marginal product of capital is: A) 50. B) 100. C) 200. D) 1,000.

TRADE AND INVESTMENT IN THE NATIONAL ACCOUNTS This text accompanies the material covered in class.

The level of price and inflation Real GDP: the values of goods and services measured using a constant set of prices

The Theory of Investment

ANSWERS TO END-OF-CHAPTER QUESTIONS

The Aggregate Production Function Revised: January 9, 2008

AP Microeconomics Chapter 12 Outline

14.02 Principles of Macroeconomics Problem Set 1 Fall 2005 ***Solution***

Study Questions for Chapter 9 (Answer Sheet)

Study Questions 8 (Keynesian Model) MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

Government Budget and Fiscal Policy CHAPTER

Long Run Economic Growth Agenda. Long-run Economic Growth. Long-run Growth Model. Long-run Economic Growth. Determinants of Long-run Growth

CHAPTER 9 Building the Aggregate Expenditures Model

Chapter 12. Aggregate Expenditure and Output in the Short Run

The Multiplier Effect of Fiscal Policy

Macroeconomics Lecture 1: The Solow Growth Model

With lectures 1-8 behind us, we now have the tools to support the discussion and implementation of economic policy.

Lecture 2. Marginal Functions, Average Functions, Elasticity, the Marginal Principle, and Constrained Optimization

1. a. Interest-bearing checking accounts make holding money more attractive. This increases the demand for money.

3 Macroeconomics LESSON 1

AGGREGATE DEMAND AND EXPENDITURE

Pre-Test Chapter 8 ed17

ECON20310 LECTURE SYNOPSIS REAL BUSINESS CYCLE

Towards a Structuralist Interpretation of Saving, Investment and Current Account in Turkey

Name: Date: 3. Variables that a model tries to explain are called: A. endogenous. B. exogenous. C. market clearing. D. fixed.

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

PERPETUITIES NARRATIVE SCRIPT 2004 SOUTH-WESTERN, A THOMSON BUSINESS

Chapter 9 Aggregate Demand and Economic Fluctuations Macroeconomics In Context (Goodwin, et al.)

(1) A reduction in the lump sum tax (2) A rise in the marginal propensity to import (3) A decrease in the marginal propensity to consume

Pre-Test Chapter 18 ed17

The Keynesian Cross. A Fixed Price Level. The Simplest Keynesian-Cross Model: Autonomous Consumption Only

Econ 303: Intermediate Macroeconomics I Dr. Sauer Sample Questions for Exam #3

Practice Problems on the Capital Market

[03.03] Guidelines for the User Cost Method to calculate rents for owner occupied housing. International Comparison Program

Sample Question Paper (Set-2) Economics (030) Class XII ( ) Section A: Microeconomics

3. a. If all money is held as currency, then the money supply is equal to the monetary base. The money supply will be $1,000.

Real income (Y)

INTRODUCTION AGGREGATE DEMAND MACRO EQUILIBRIUM MACRO EQUILIBRIUM THE DESIRED ADJUSTMENT THE DESIRED ADJUSTMENT

FISCAL POLICY* Chapter. Key Concepts

8. Average product reaches a maximum when labor equals A) 100 B) 200 C) 300 D) 400

. In this case the leakage effect of tax increases is mitigated because some of the reduction in disposable income would have otherwise been saved.

Lecture 3: Growth with Overlapping Generations (Acemoglu 2009, Chapter 9, adapted from Zilibotti)

Chapter 4 Consumption, Saving, and Investment

Microeconomics Instructor Miller Practice Problems Labor Market

14.02 Principles of Macroeconomics Problem Set 1 *Solution* Fall 2004

Economics 201 Fall 2010 Introduction to Economic Analysis Problem Set #6 Due: Wednesday, November 3

Current Accounts in Open Economies Obstfeld and Rogoff, Chapter 2

Preparation course MSc Business&Econonomics: Economic Growth

13 EXPENDITURE MULTIPLIERS: THE KEYNESIAN MODEL* Chapter. Key Concepts

SRAS. is less than Y P

TAXATION AND SAVINGS. Robin Boadway Queen s University Kingston, Canada. Day Six

Preparation course Msc Business & Econonomics

The Real Business Cycle Model

Profit and Revenue Maximization

VI. Real Business Cycles Models

Lecture 14 More on Real Business Cycles. Noah Williams

U = x x x 1 4. What are the equilibrium relative prices of the three goods? traders has members who are best off?

Productioin OVERVIEW. WSG5 7/7/03 4:35 PM Page 63. Copyright 2003 by Academic Press. All rights of reproduction in any form reserved.

SAMPLE PAPER II ECONOMICS Class - XII BLUE PRINT

Pre-Test Chapter 25 ed17

PART A: For each worker, determine that worker's marginal product of labor.

Keynesian Macroeconomic Theory

Pre-Test Chapter 11 ed17

Chapter 1 Lecture Notes: Economics for MBAs and Masters of Finance

BADM 527, Fall Midterm Exam 2. Multiple Choice: 3 points each. Answer the questions on the separate bubble sheet. NAME

POTENTIAL OUTPUT and LONG RUN AGGREGATE SUPPLY

CHAPTER 10 MARKET POWER: MONOPOLY AND MONOPSONY

Schooling, Political Participation, and the Economy. (Online Supplementary Appendix: Not for Publication)

The Cobb-Douglas Production Function

The Solow Model. Savings and Leakages from Per Capita Capital. (n+d)k. sk^alpha. k*: steady state Per Capita Capital, k

chapter: Solution Fiscal Policy

Use the following to answer question 9: Exhibit: Keynesian Cross

BUSINESS ECONOMICS CEC & 761

Chapter 5 The Production Process and Costs

Financial Development and Macroeconomic Stability

The IS-LM Model Ing. Mansoor Maitah Ph.D.

Economic Growth. (c) Copyright 1999 by Douglas H. Joines 1

These are some practice questions for CHAPTER 23. Each question should have a single answer. But be careful. There may be errors in the answer key!

1.1 Introduction. Chapter 1: Feasibility Studies: An Overview

changes in spending changes in income/output AE = Aggregate Expenditures = C + I + G + Xn = AD

M.A.PART - I ECONOMIC PAPER - I MACRO ECONOMICS

Equity Valuation Formulas. William L. Silber and Jessica Wachter

Long-Run Average Cost. Econ 410: Micro Theory. Long-Run Average Cost. Long-Run Average Cost. Economies of Scale & Scope Minimizing Cost Mathematically

Economics 152 Solution to Sample Midterm 2

Introduction to Macroeconomics TOPIC 2: The Goods Market

Econ 102 Aggregate Supply and Demand

Business Conditions Analysis Prof. Yamin Ahmad ECON 736

Consumption, Saving, and Investment, Part 1

Learning Objectives. After reading Chapter 11 and working the problems for Chapter 11 in the textbook and in this Workbook, you should be able to:

Q = ak L + bk L. 2. The properties of a short-run cubic production function ( Q = AL + BL )

Recently, the Bureau of Labor Statistics projected

Transcription:

Lecture 6 Investment Decisions The Digital Economist Investment is the act of acquiring income-producing assets, known as physical capital, either as additions to existing assets or to replace assets that have worn out (depreciated). These assets may be in the form of fixed nonresidential plant and equipment, housing (fixed residential) or business inventories. Decisions about the appropriate quantity of assets or capital are often based on profit-maximizing behavior of a private individual business firm producing goods and services or providing housing services. The investment relationship may be written as follows: where J t = K* t - K t-1 + δk t-1 J t = Gross Investment (measured in units of new or replacement capital), K* t = Desired (profit-maximizing level) Capital Stock, K t-1 = Existing Capital Stock, δ = rate of depreciation. The difference in the first two terms (K* t - K t-1 ) represents net or new investment and the last term (δk t-1 ) represents replacement investment. Gross investment is just the sum of the two expressions. By multiplying both sides of the equation by P k (the price of capital) and factoring out 'K t-1 ', we can write an expression for Investment expenditure (I t ): I t = P k [K* t - (1-δ)K t-1 ] where I t = P k J t. INVESTMENT DECISIONS and PROFIT MAXIMIZATION The Net Present Value Approach The key to understanding investment decisions is the determination of K*, the desired capital stock. This desired level is based, as stated above, on profit-maximizing behavior of the firm. There are several methods by which we can approach the profit-maximizing level of capital stock. First, we can analyze the net present value of different amounts of capital to determine which quantity gives the greatest discounted stream of profits. For example, given the following: 76

P k = $1000/unit, δ = 10%/year which implies that a unit of capital has a life of 10 years, We assume that the capital has no salvage value, r = 5%/annually -- this is the real market rate of interest, P x = $5 -- the market price of a unit of output. With this data we will use the following annuity factor computation: Note: The Present Value of an Income producing asset that generates an annual income stream (revenue) of 'R' is defined by the following formula: PV asset = Σ [t = 1, N] R t (1+r) -t or using the formula for a sum of a geometric series: = (R/r)[1 - (1+r) -N ] as N, this expression reduces to R/r. PV N = (Revenue)[1 - (1+r) -N ] r = (Revenue)[1 - (1.05) -10 ] 0.05 = (Revenue)7.722 Table 1, Net Present Value Input Output Revenue Costs Present Net Present K (units X ) [P x (X)] [P k (K)] Value (N=10) Value 1 50 $250 $1930.50 $1000 $930.50 2 90 $450 $3474.90 $2000 $1474.90 3 120 $600 $4632.00 $3000 $1632.00 4 140 $700 $5405.40 $4000 $1405.40 5 150 $750 $5791.50 $5000 $791.50 In the above table we have a short run production relationship with capital being the only variable input. The input-output relationship is derived under assumption of diminishing marginal productivity. We find that three units of capital would generate the greatest net present value and thus the greatest profits. The Marginal Revenue Product Approach A second approach is the marginal approach where we compare the contribution to revenue by using one more unit of capital with the costs of acquiring that unit of capital. The contribution to revenue is known as the Marginal Revenue Product of capital and is calculated by multiplying the marginal product with the market price of the output produced: 77

MRP k = MP K P x The contribution to costs is known as the Rental Cost of Capital that includes borrowing costs (or opportunity costs of using internal funds for investment expenditure) and depreciation costs: RCC =P K (r) + P K (δ) = P K (r + δ) The desired level of capital stock K* is that quantity where: MRP K = RCC We will use similar data and a table for an example: Table 2, MRP, RCC K Output MP k MRP k RCC (r = 5%, δ=10%) 1 50 units 50 $250 $150 2 90 40 $200 $150 3 120 30 $150 = $150 4 140 20 $100 $150 5 150 10 $50 $150 If the MRP exceeds RCC then profits will increase by acquiring additional units of capital (contribution to revenue exceed contribution to costs). If the opposite is true then the additional costs associated with one more unit of capital exceed the revenue generated and profits will decline. These relationships are shown in the diagram below: Figure 1, MRP, RCC See: http://www.digitaleconomist.com/capital.html to experiment with changes in relevant parameters of this model. 78

Similar to the Net Present Value approach, we find that with three units of capital the contribution to revenue of this third unit is just equal to the costs of acquiring and using that third unit--profits will be a maximum at this level of input. Present Value of a Perpetuity Approach A third approach is using a calculation similar to the present value of a perpetuity. We begin by using the marginal conditions above: MRP = RCC MP K P x = P K (r + δ) And we rearrange the terms: [MRP K - P K (δ)] P K = 'Ψ' This term Ψ' represents the yield on the last unit of capital employed in the production process: Table 3, Present Value of a Perpetuity K Output MRP K - P K (δ) P K Yield r market 1 50 units $250-$100 $1000 15% 5% 2 90 $200-$100 $1000 10% 5% 3 120 $150-$100 $1000 5% 5% 4 140 $100-$100 $1000 0% 5% 5 150 $50-$100 $1000 NA 5% In this case, we find that the yield on the first two units of capital is greater than the market interest rate r market and thus may be acquired to earn profits over-and-above the borrowing costs. It is the third unit of capital where the yield is just equal to the market rate of interest -- no additional profits may be earned by hiring additional capital. In all three approaches we find that the desired capital stock 'K*' is equal to three units based on the productivity of capital, the rate of depreciation, the price of capital and the output being produced and, of greatest importance, market interest rates. We can use a Cobb-Douglas form of the production function to solve for K* and combine this with the expression for investment defined above: X = AL α K β and MP K = βx / K given the profit-maximizing condition: MRP K = RCC, β(x/k)p x = P K (r + δ) 79

or K* = [β(p x )X] [P K (r + δ)] Inserting this expression for K* into the investment expenditure equation gives us: or I t = P K { [β(p x )X] [P K (r + δ)] - (1-δ)K t-1 } I t = [β(p x )X] (r + δ) - (1-δ)P K K t-1 where we find that Investment expenditure is inversely related to market interest rates r and the price of a unit of capital P K, positively related to output prices P x and the productivity of capital (as measured by the parameter 'β'), and undetermined with respect to the rate of depreciation δ. TOBIN s - q A different approach to understanding investment decisions is in using an expression known as Tobin's-q. This q-value represents a ratio between the market value of existing capital and its replacement cost: q = Market Value Replacement Cost = {(Revenue)[1 - (1+r) -N ] r} [P K K] If this value is greater than one, then the value of capital is greater than replacement costs and it would make sense to add or invest in more capital. It the q-value is less than one then the market value is less than replacement costs and business firms will allow existing capital to depreciate resulting in negative levels of investment. Given the inverse relationship between asset prices and market interest rates we can note that when these interest rates rise the market value of installed capital falls relative to replacement costs dis-investment will occur. The ACCELERATOR A different approach to investment relative to the profit-maximizing model is that of the accelerator model. This model begins with the notion that a certain amount of capital is necessary to support a given level of economic activity. We can define this relationship as being proportional to RGDP Y : K t = θ Y t K t - K t-1 = θ(y t Y t-1 ) 80

where 'θ' is known as the accelerator and represents a constant of proportionality between the two variables. If we restrict the definition of capital to only include business inventory stocks then we might note that: 0 < θ < 1 Investment represents changes in these stocks such that: I t = P k {K t - K t-1 + δk t-1 } = P k {θ Yt + δk t-1 } In order to understand investment behavior in this model, we need to look at the determinants of income or equilibrium level of expenditure: Y t = C t + I t + G t + NX t Defining consumption expenditure as being proportional to disposable income: Ct = by d = b(1 - t)y t -- where 'b' represents the marginal propensity to consume. We can then substitute: Y t = b(1 - t)y t + θp k {Y t - Y t-1 }+ δp k K t-1 + G t + NX t For algebraic simplicity, we will eliminate the depreciation term and set P k equal to 1. Solving for Y t : Thus: Y t [1 - b(1 - t) - θ] = A t - θy t-1 -- where A t = G t + NX t Y t * = [1 - b(1 - t) - θ] -1 (A t - θy t-1 ) The term in the brackets, [1 - b(1 - t) - θ] -1, is known as the multiplier which represents how a change in autonomous expenditure 'A t ' affects the equilibrium level of income. We will replace this term with a simple variable 'α' such that: Y t * = α(a t - θy t-1 ) Using the following values for the parameters, the marginal propensity to consume -- b = 0.75, income tax rates -- t = 0.20, the accelerator -- θ = 0.10, and Y t = Y t-1 = Y t-2 = 2500. we can compute a value for the multiplier to be equal to 3.333 thus: 81

Y t = 3.333[A t - 0.10Y t-1 ], and conduct the following simulation: time: 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 Y t : 2500 2500 2833 2720 2760 2744 2750 A t : 1000 1000 1100 1100 1100 1100 1100 I t = θ Y t : 0 0 33.33-11.30 4.00-1.60 0.60 We find, in this example, in time periods 0 and 1 the economy is in equilibrium with an income level of $2500. In time period 2, there is an autonomous shock (an increase in government spending or perhaps an increase in net-export spending) of $100. Working through the multiplier, the $100 change in autonomous spending leads to a $333 increase in income (an example of the multiplier process). Changes in income mandate increases in inventory to support this additional economic activity. However, after this initial shock, the economy oscillates towards a new equilibrium of $2750 by time period 6. Through time, with this cyclical behavior in income, there is also cyclical behavior in investment with additions taking being offset by reductions every other year. Eventually as the economy approaches the new level, the need for new investment approaches zero. See: http://www.digitaleconomist.com/acc_modl.html to experiment with the parameters of the accelerator model. The nature of this cyclical behavior is sensitive to the values of the marginal propensity to consume, tax rates (which impacts the multiplier process), and the value of the accelerator (which affects both the multiplier and the rate of acceleration). For example suppose we increase the value of the accelerator to 20%. The new value of the multiplier will be equal to 5.0: time 0 1 2 3 4 5 Y t : 2500 2500 3000 2500 3000 2500 A t : 1000 1000 1100 1100 1100 1100 I t = θ Y t : 0 0 +100-100 +100-100 In this case the autonomous shock leads to an economy that oscillates forever between $2500 and $3000 with investment being +$100 every other year. It is the larger value of the multiplier relative to the size of the MPC that leads to this result. This relationship between the accelerator and the MPC (or marginal propensity to spend when taxes are considered) helps explain the cyclical behavior of economic activity. We can summarize this relationship below: Table 4, Oscillations in Real GDP Large θ Moderate θ Small θ High propensity to Spend (b > 0.60) Explosive Cyclical Damped Moderate propensity to Spend (b<0.60) Explosive Explosive Cyclical/Damped 82

Be sure that you understand the following concepts and terms: Marginal Productivity Marginal Revenue Product Rental Cost of Capital Real Rate of Interest Rate of Depreciation Gross Investment Net Investment Replacement Investment Desired Capital Stock Present Value Present Value of a Perpetuity Tobin s q the Accelerator the Multiplier 83

Worksheet #4: Capital Accumulation 1. Given the following data: The Digital Economist Capital Output Output MRP K Output [K] [X] MP K Price (P x ) (MP K x P x ) Price (P x ') MRP K ' 50 1000 70 $2.00 $140 $4.00 60 1600 60 2.00 120 4.00 70 2100 50 2.00 100 4.00 80 2500 2.00 4.00 90 2800 2.00 4.00 100 3000 2.00 4.00 110 3100 2.00 4.00 120 3150 2.00 4.00 The Price of a unit of capital (P k ) is $320 The [expected] life of a unit of capital is 10 years The Optimal level of the capital stock K* is defined where: MRP K = P K (r + δ) δ represents the annual rate of depreciation Complete steps a d for a market output price P x of $2.00 a. If the real rate of interest r is 15% (0.15), what is the optimal level of capital stock K*? b. If the real rate if interest falls to 2.5%, what is the new optimal level of capital? Investment is defined as: I t = K* t K t-1 + δk t-1 c. If K t-1 is equal to 70 units of capital, what will be the level of investment expenditure for r = 15% at the existing rate of depreciation? d. What will be the level of investment expenditure for K t-1 = 70, r = 15% and a rate of depreciation δ of 0.225? e. Repeat steps 'a-c' for an output price (P x ') of $4.00. 84

Worksheet #4, page 2 (Question #1, cont.) f. Graphically show the relationship between investment expenditure and the real rate of interest. Specifically, show the level of expenditure for K t-1 = 70, δ = 0.10, P x = $2.00, r 0 = 15%, and r 1 = 8.75%. Real Rate of Interest (r) 0 Investment Expenditure 2. Suppose that production is defined by a Cobb-Douglas production function Y = AL 1-α K α α = 0.30, Α = 100 a. Provide an economic interpretation for the parameters α and A. b. Does this production function exhibit increasing returns, constant returns, or decreasing returns to scale? Explain. Using the following expression for the Rental Costs of Capital (RCC), solve for the optimal level of capital stock K* as a function of the real interest rate r : RCC = P k (r + δ) = $320(r + 0.10) Remember that K* is that level of capital where RCC = MRP K. c. By how much does the optimal capital stock change when the interest increases from r = 10% to r = 8%? 85