Week 1 Efficiency in Production and in Consumption and the Fundamental Theorems of Welfare Economics



Similar documents
MICROECONOMICS AND POLICY ANALYSIS - U8213 Professor Rajeev H. Dehejia Class Notes - Spring 2001

Table of Contents MICRO ECONOMICS

REVIEW OF MICROECONOMICS

Homework #5: Answers. b. How can land rents as well as total wages be shown in such a diagram?

Economics of Insurance

chapter >> Consumer and Producer Surplus Section 3: Consumer Surplus, Producer Surplus, and the Gains from Trade

Public Goods & Externalities

Efficiency and Equity

Deriving Demand Functions - Examples 1

Economics I. General equilibrium and microeconomic policy of the state

Advanced International Economics Prof. Yamin Ahmad ECON 758

Unraveling versus Unraveling: A Memo on Competitive Equilibriums and Trade in Insurance Markets

Principles of Economics: Micro: Exam #2: Chapters 1-10 Page 1 of 9

Managerial Economics Prof. Trupti Mishra S.J.M. School of Management Indian Institute of Technology, Bombay. Lecture - 13 Consumer Behaviour (Contd )

Constrained Optimisation

Chapter 4. Specific Factors and Income Distribution

Chapter 25: Exchange in Insurance Markets

Hurley, Chapter 7 (see also review in chapter 3)

U = x x x 1 4. What are the equilibrium relative prices of the three goods? traders has members who are best off?

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

Chapter 27: Taxation. 27.1: Introduction. 27.2: The Two Prices with a Tax. 27.2: The Pre-Tax Position

Market Failure. presented by: Dr. Ellen Sewell

Multi-variable Calculus and Optimization

Principles of Economics

GCE. Economics. Mark Scheme for June Advanced GCE Unit F583: Economics of Work and Leisure. Oxford Cambridge and RSA Examinations

PPA 723, Fall 2006 Professor John McPeak

CHAPTER 10 MARKET POWER: MONOPOLY AND MONOPSONY

Increasing for all. Convex for all. ( ) Increasing for all (remember that the log function is only defined for ). ( ) Concave for all.

Sample Midterm Solutions

Chapter 4 Online Appendix: The Mathematics of Utility Functions

An increase in the number of students attending college. shifts to the left. An increase in the wage rate of refinery workers.

Chapter 7 Monopoly, Oligopoly and Strategy

8. Average product reaches a maximum when labor equals A) 100 B) 200 C) 300 D) 400

LABOR UNIONS. Appendix. Key Concepts

Macroeconomics Lecture 1: The Solow Growth Model

6. Budget Deficits and Fiscal Policy

Microeconomics Topic 3: Understand how various factors shift supply or demand and understand the consequences for equilibrium price and quantity.

Chapter 9. The IS-LM/AD-AS Model: A General Framework for Macroeconomic Analysis Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved

INDUSTRIAL ECONOMICS COMPONENT: THE INTERACTIVE TEXTBOOK

Chapter 8 Application: The Costs of Taxation

ECO 352 Spring 2010 No. 7 Feb. 23 SECTOR-SPECIFIC CAPITAL (RICARDO-VINER) MODEL

Paper 1 (SL and HL) markschemes

Chapter 6: Pure Exchange

The Real Business Cycle model

Annex 8. Market Failure in Broadcasting

Problem Set #5-Key. Economics 305-Intermediate Microeconomic Theory

Lectures, 2 ECONOMIES OF SCALE

Oligopoly and Strategic Pricing

MARKET FAILURE AND GOVERNMENT INTERVENTION

2. Information Economics

. In this case the leakage effect of tax increases is mitigated because some of the reduction in disposable income would have otherwise been saved.

SCREENING IN INSURANCE MARKETS WITH ADVERSE SELECTION AND BACKGROUND RISK. Keith J. Crocker

ANSWERS TO END-OF-CHAPTER QUESTIONS

WHY STUDY PUBLIC FINANCE?

Constrained optimization.

Labor Demand The Labor Market

Problem Set #3 Answer Key

CHAPTER 3 CONSUMER BEHAVIOR

Second Hour Exam Public Finance Fall, Answers

c. Given your answer in part (b), what do you anticipate will happen in this market in the long-run?

(First 6 problems from Caves, Frankel and Jones, 1990)

CHAPTER 12 MARKETS WITH MARKET POWER Microeconomics in Context (Goodwin, et al.), 2 nd Edition

Where are we? To do today: finish the derivation of the demand curve using indifference curves. Go on then to chapter Production and Cost

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

Week 3: Demand Theory and Welfare Analysis

CHAPTER 11 PRICE AND OUTPUT IN MONOPOLY, MONOPOLISTIC COMPETITION, AND PERFECT COMPETITION

Pricing in a Competitive Market with a Common Network Resource

Competitive Screening in Credit Markets with Adverse Selection: A Cover Version of Bester s Model

The Specific-Factors Model: HO Model in the Short Run

Final Exam 15 December 2006

Notes on indifference curve analysis of the choice between leisure and labor, and the deadweight loss of taxation. Jon Bakija

Economics 2020a / HBS 4010 / HKS API-111 FALL 2010 Solutions to Practice Problems for Lectures 1 to 4

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question on the accompanying scantron.

Equilibrium in Competitive Insurance Markets: An Essay on the Economic of Imperfect Information

All these models were characterized by constant returns to scale technologies and perfectly competitive markets.

Definition and Properties of the Production Function: Lecture

Econ 101: Principles of Microeconomics

Introduction to microeconomics

CHAPTER 9: PURE COMPETITION

Who gains and who loses from an import tariff? An export tax? (Assume world prices are fixed).

Theoretical Tools of Public Economics. Part-2

QE1: Economics Notes 1

The fundamental question in economics is 2. Consumer Preferences

TRADE AND INVESTMENT IN THE NATIONAL ACCOUNTS This text accompanies the material covered in class.

Connecting the Firm s Optimal Output and Input Decisions

Economics 201 Fall 2010 Introduction to Economic Analysis Problem Set #6 Due: Wednesday, November 3

Welfare Economics and Public Choice Timothy Besley London School of Economics and Political Science. April 2002

Midterm Exam - Answers. November 3, 2005

19 : Theory of Production

The Economic Problem: Scarcity and Choice. What is Production?

Theory of Demand. ECON 212 Lecture 7. Tianyi Wang. Winter Queen s Univerisity. Tianyi Wang (Queen s Univerisity) Lecture 7 Winter / 46

Optimal Security Design

The economics of the Export-Import Bank: a teaching note

Market Supply in the Short Run

Oligopoly: How do firms behave when there are only a few competitors? These firms produce all or most of their industry s output.

Demand, Supply and Elasticity

How To Learn Economics In India

CHAPTER 18 MARKETS WITH MARKET POWER Principles of Economics in Context (Goodwin et al.)

ECON 103, ANSWERS TO HOME WORK ASSIGNMENTS

Practice Problem Set 2 (ANSWERS)

Transcription:

1. Introduction Week 1 Efficiency in Production and in Consumption and the Fundamental Theorems of Welfare Economics Much of economic theory of the textbook variety is a celebration of the free market system. This celebration has two parts. First, the operation of the price system, in the context of competitive markets, leads to balance between the demand and supply of the different goods and services traded. In other words, flexible prices result in competitive markets clearing. Second, the marketclearing equilibrium - brought about through flexible prices and competitive markets - is a "good thing" in the sense that it is also a point of economic efficiency 1. In other words competitive outcomes are also efficient ones. The fact that competition leads to efficiency is known as the First Fundamental Theorem of Welfare Economics 2. These results - which are, of course, a vindication of dam Smith's intuition about the existence of an "invisible hand" bringing consistency and order to the chaos of individual actions - would be remarkable in themselves. ut there is more. The efficient outcome will have been brought about through parsimony in the use of information; the only things that individuals, in making their supply/demand decisions, need to know are the prices of the different commodities. Furthermore, since the efficient outcome is the result of firms and consumers acting "selfishly", by looking only to their own interests, it is "incentive compatible" in the sense that its existence does not depend upon altruistic behaviour. Lastly, not only will competitive markets lead to an efficient outcome, but any efficient outcome that one might desire can be attained through the operation of competitive markets. This last statement known as the Second Fundamental Theorem of Welfare Economics - is a very powerful result for it says that if one does not like the particular efficient outcome (perhaps because there were great inequalities associated with it) that resulted from the operation of competitive markets in a specific context, then all is not 1 Economists regard an outcome as being "efficient" if there no other another outcomes in which, relative to the original outcome, some persons are better off without anyone being worse off. If such "better" outcomes exist, then the original outcome is termed inefficient. 2 See rrow and Hahn (1971), for an authoritative account of how competitive economies work.

lost. In such a situation all that is required is to specify a different, more desirable, outcome and to modify the context suitably; competitive markets operating in the new context would then lead to that outcome. gainst the background of these results the government does not have much of a role. If economic outcomes were not socially desirable then one role for government would be to change the context within which markets operated. This context is provided by the initial endowments with which individuals are equipped for trade in the market. For example, persons who were wealthy or who possessed skills and education would be better equipped for trade than the poor and the unskilled and hence would benefit disproportionately from market outcomes. If endowments were unfairly distributed then market outcomes, notwithstanding the fact that they were efficient, would also be unfair. Thus, within the framework of market sovereignty, redistribution - whereby initial endowments were altered in order to prevent grossly inequitable outcomes - would be an acceptable role for government. Even here, its role would be limited by the injunction that, in the pursuit of redistributive objectives, the government should not, by distorting incentives, pervert the free functioning of markets. Since this injunction could only be satisfied through the highly infeasible instrument of "lump-sum" taxes and transfers (that is, all "rich" persons pay, for example, $100 each, and all "poor" persons receive the same, irrespective of their wealth or poverty), in practice the redistributive role for government would be non-existent. lthough proponents of free markets concede that government might legitimately have a say, however circumscribed, in the sphere of distribution (that is, in terms of who receives how much) it would deny government any role, other than a purely facilitating one, in the spheres of production and of allocation (that is, in terms of deciding what, how much of, and by whom, commodities are to be produced. In terms of by whom to produce, the basic choice is between production by the private sector and production by the public sector. Economists who believe in

the free functioning of markets would argue that the most useful role that government could play in this regard would be to abdicate its productive responsibilities in favour of the private sector - a process known as privatisation. Such economists would, in similar vein, argue that the most useful contribution that governments could make to allocative decisions (relating to what, and how much, to produce) would be to remove market imperfections. These imperfections, which prevent markets from functioning properly, are associated with an absence of competition (for example, through the existence of monopolies) or with the presence of barriers to price flexibility (for example, through price-support mechanisms like minimum wage legislation). The task of government would then be to take the necessary steps to ensure that all impediments to the proper functioning of markets were removed. Economists who are not content with this purely passive role for public policy, point to numerous real-world instances where, notwithstanding the existence of competition and price flexibility, markets fail to deliver on efficiency. (Indeed as Solow (1993) has pointed out, many of the young stars of economics, of the past twenty years, made their mark by going beyond the simple competitive model and considering the consequences of dropping some of its restrictive assumptions). In the presence of such cases of market failure, they would argue, governments have no alternative but to intervene actively to help markets overcome these difficulties. Indeed Stiglitz (1989) has argued that, contrary to the traditional view that market failures are the exception, such failures may be so pervasive as to be the norm. However, it is not at all obvious that government will necessarily succeed where markets have failed. Consequently, not all cases of market failure will be amenable to correction through government action. The key to effective government intervention, therefore, lies not in demonstrating the existence of market failures (and thereby establishing a rationale for government intervention) but rather one of identifying situations where such failures are of the kind that would make intervention worthwhile.

2. The Conditions for Efficiency Efficiency in production arises when factors of production are allocated between the production of different commodities in such a way that a different allocation would not produce more of some commodities without also producing less of some other commodities. The necessary and sufficient condition for efficiency in production, when there are two factors of production, labour and capital - whose quantities are represented by L and K, respectively used in producing two commodities, whose quantities are represented by and, respectively, is: MRTS LK = MRTS (1) where: MRTS is the marginal rate of technical substitution between labour and capital 3. LK Efficiency in consumption arises when the available quantities of the different commodities are distributed between the different consumers in such a way that a different distribution would not lead some consumers to be better off without making some other consumers worse off. The necessary and sufficient condition for efficiency in consumption, when fixed quantities of two commodities, denoted and, are to be distributed between two consumers, and is: MRS = MRS (2) where: MRS is the marginal rate of substitution between the two commodities. labour and capital 4. Efficiency in production is illustrated in Figure 1: each point on the efficiency locus in Figure 1 represents a point of tangency between isoquants and can be mapped onto a point on the production possibility curve in Figure 2: W D and V C. Figure 3 illustrates efficiency in consumption and Figure 4 shows the mapping of the efficient points in consumption (of Figure 3) onto a utility possibility curve. 3 MRTS is the reduction in the amount of capital needed when an additional unit of labour is used in the production of a given amount of output. 4 MRS is the amount of one commodity a consumer is prepared to give up, to get an additional unit of another commodity, utility remaining unchanged.

Isoquants W L O K isoquants C (mapping of V) Efficiency locus D (mapping of W) V K 0 L Figure 1: The Edgeworth ox in Production Figure 2: The Production-Possibility Curve O s Indifference Curves E U s Indifference Curves J (mapping of F) Efficiency locus K (mapping of E) F 0 Figure 3: The Edgeworth ox in Consumption Figure 4: The Utility-Possibility Curve U Each point on the production possibility curve represents an efficient allocation of labour and capital in production; given a point on the production possibility curve representing the total quantities produced of each of the two commodities - each point on the utility possibility curve represents an efficient distribution of the two commodities in consumption.

llocative efficiency occurs when the right amounts of the two commodities are produced or, in other words, the economy is at the right point on its production possibility curve. The necessary and sufficient condition for allocative efficiency is: MRS = MRS = MRT (3) where: MRT is the marginal rate of transformation between the two commodities 5. The point G in Figure 5, below, is a point of allocative efficiency: at G, the slope of the production possibility curve ( MRT ) is equal to the (common) slopes of the indifference curves ( MRS = MRS ). G Figure 5: llocative Efficiency See the Mathematical ppendix for a derivation of the efficiency conditions of equation (3). 3. The Fundamental Theorems of Welfare Economics The First Theorem: Every Competitive Equilibrium is an Efficient Outcome Under a competitive equilibrium, every consumer faces the same prices. Therefore, equilibrium for consumers and occurs when: MRS = p / p and MRS = p / p MRS = MRS. 5 Suppose MRT =α and MRS =β, α>β. Then if loses one unit of, because one unit less of is produced, will need to be compensated by β units of ; but producing one unit less of, will increase output of by α>β. So, after has been compensated, following a unit reduction in the production of, there will be a surplus of.

Similarly, each producer faces the same input prices. Therefore, equilibrium for each producer occurs when: MRTS = q / q and MRTS = q / q MRTS = MRTS for i, j = 1... N LK LK LK K L LK K L Lastly, MRT = MC / MC and, under competitive conditions: p = MC and p = MC p / p = MRT = MRS = MRS so that the conditions for allocative efficiency are satisfied. Second Theorem: If preferences and technology are convex, then every Pareto optimal outcome can be represented as a competitive equilibrium for some pattern of initial endowments and some vector of prices. E G H Figure 6: The Second Theorem In Figure 6, consumers with an initial endowment at E, when faced with prices represented by the slope of the dashed line, will arrive at the efficient point, H. Similarly, producers will produce at G. Consequently, the Pareto optimal outcome at G and H can be attained through the competitive process.

Deriving the Efficiency Conditions Mathematical ppendix Pareto efficient allocation is one that maximises one person s utility () subject to the constraint that the second person s utility does not change: Max U (, ) s.t. U (, ) = U and T(, ) = 0 (4),,, 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 The Lagrangian for this problem is: L = WU [ (, ), U (, )]- µ [ T(, ) 0] (5) 1 2 1 2 1 2 and the first order conditions for maximising the Lagrangian with respect to the choice variables are: L U T = µ = 0 1 1 1 L U T = µ = 0 2 2 2 L U T = λ µ = 0 1 1 1 L U T = λ µ = 0 2 2 2 (6) Dividing the first equation by the second, and the third equation by the fourth, yields: MRS = MRS = MRT (7) 12 12 12

Key Points Weeks 1 &2 1. Efficiency in Production: reallocation of resources from one use to another cannot cause some outputs to increase without a loss in other outputs 2. Inefficiency in Production: reallocation of resources from one use to another can cause some outputs to increase without a loss in other outputs 3. Marginal Rate of Technical Substitution (MRTS): amount of an input one can give up for an unit increase in another input, output remaining unchanged, MRTS LK 4. Condition for efficiency in production: MRTS LK= MRTS LK 5. Edgeworth ox: isoquants; efficiency locus (tangency of isoquants); derivation of production possibility curve 6. Marginal Rate of Transformation: MRT 7. Efficiency in Consumption: redistribution of resources from some consumers to others cannot cause some utilities to increase without a loss in other others 8. Inefficiency in Consumption: redistribution of resources from some consumers to others can cause some utilities to increase without a loss in other others 9. Marginal Rate of Substitution (MRS): amount of a good one is willing to give up for an unit increase in another good, utility remaining unchanged, MRS 10. Condition for efficiency in consumption: MRS = MRS 11. Edgeworth ox: indifference curves; efficiency locus (tangency of indifference curves); derivation of utility possibility possibility curve 12. Condition for llocative Efficiency: MRTS LK= MRTS LK= MRT Under allocative efficiency we have: (i) Efficiency in production and (ii) the right quantities being produced 15. Why competitive markets lead to Efficient Outcomes