Urban Housing Demand Location

Similar documents
10 Hot Topics in Urban Economics (including Housing Economics) Christian Hilber London School of Economics

Tax Expenditures for Owner-Occupied Housing: Deductions for Property Taxes and Mortgage Interest and the Exclusion of Imputed Rental Income AUTHORS

ID: U Abstract. Urban growth

Economic Growth in Cities (and policies to promote it) Economics 312 Martin Farnham

This PDF is a selection from a published volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research

Interest Rates and Fundamental Fluctuations in Home Values

Good [morning, afternoon, evening]. I m [name] with [firm]. Today, we will talk about alternative investments.

Figure 6: Effect of ITC on Skilled and Unskilled Labor Markets

Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Reports

This PDF is a selection from a published volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research

For instance between 1960 and 2000 the average hourly output produced by US workers rose by 140 percent.

Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Reports

Adjusting Compensation for Geographical Differences

Chapter 3 Market Demand, Supply and Elasticity

The Natural Resource Content of United States Foreign Trade

Reforming the Mortgage Interest Deduction. Eric Toder Margery Austin Turner Katherine Lim Liza Getsinger April 2010

Notes - Gruber, Public Finance Chapter 20.3 A calculation that finds the optimal income tax in a simple model: Gruber and Saez (2002).

Ladies and gentlemen welcome to Stockholm - the fastest growing. capital in Europe together with Oslo, just next door.

House Prices and Female Labor Force Participation*

WHY STUDY PUBLIC FINANCE?

[03.03] Guidelines for the User Cost Method to calculate rents for owner occupied housing. International Comparison Program

TAX REDUCTION AND ECONOMIC WELFARE

urban economics Spatial forces

1. Various shocks on a small open economy

IN THEOR Y, PUBLIC INVESTMENTS IN MASS TRANSIT CAN MAKE URBAN

FEDERAL TAXES AND SPENDING HAVE LONG

Housing Bubbles: A Survey

Reference: Gregory Mankiw s Principles of Macroeconomics, 2 nd edition, Chapters 10 and 11. Gross Domestic Product

The Case for a Tax Cut

Chapter 3. The Concept of Elasticity and Consumer and Producer Surplus. Chapter Objectives. Chapter Outline

ECON 3312 Macroeconomics Exam 3 Fall Name MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

DEMAND: PREFERENCES AND INCOME/WEALTH

Current account deficit -10. Private sector Other public* Official reserve assets

Annex 8. Market Failure in Broadcasting

Surveillance of algorithmic trading

The State of Equity in China: Income and Wealth Distribution

A Static Version of The Macroeconomics of Child Labor Regulation

INTERNATIONAL ECONOMICS, FINANCE AND TRADE Vol. II - Sustainable Development, Environmental Regulation, and International Trade - Pushkar Maitra

ECON 103, ANSWERS TO HOME WORK ASSIGNMENTS

SECTION 8 RENTAL ASSISTANCE PROGRAMS ARE NOT GROWING AS SHARE OF HUD BUDGET Proposed Reforms Would Make Section 8 Even More Efficient By Douglas Rice

REVENUE COSTS AND INCENTIVE EFFECTS OF THE MORTGAGE INTEREST DEDUCTION FOR OWNER-OCCUPIED HOUSING. James Poterba and Todd Sinai

The labour market, I: real wages, productivity and unemployment 7.1 INTRODUCTION

Money and Public Finance

AP Microeconomics Chapter 12 Outline

Endogenous Gentrification and Housing-Price Dynamics

Two miles per day may not seem like much, but do the math.

7 AGGREGATE SUPPLY AND AGGREGATE DEMAND* Chapter. Key Concepts

The Elasticity of Taxable Income and the Implications of Tax Evasion for Deadweight Loss

Why Did House Prices Drop So Quickly?

SOCIAL AND NONMARKET BENEFITS FROM EDUCATION IN AN ADVANCED ECONOMY

Practical decisions facing urban planners

A layperson s guide to monetary policy

The Free Market Approach. The Health Care Market. Sellers of Health Care. The Free Market Approach. Real Income

4 THE MARKET FORCES OF SUPPLY AND DEMAND

THE EFFECTS OF WEATHER AND FUEL OIL SHOCKS ON ENEMALTA S PROFITS

Aggregate Demand and Aggregate Supply Ing. Mansoor Maitah Ph.D. et Ph.D.

Supply, Demand, Equilibrium, and Elasticity

CHAPTER 4 Labor Demand Elasticities

Firm Clustering. Econ 312 Martin Farnham

Beef Demand: What is Driving the Market?

MEASURING A NATION S INCOME

Capital Gains Taxes: An Overview

Growth and Employment in Organised Industry

The Circular Flow of Income and Expenditure

Market Analysis Retail Housing Office [CITY OF BERLIN MARKET ANALYSIS] City of Berlin, Wisconsin

Introduction to microeconomics

Chapter 4 Consumption, Saving, and Investment

State: PENNSYLVANIA Pennsylvania Housing Finance Agency (PHFA) HOUSING LOCATION: Site and Neighborhood Standards A1. Mandatory

Municipal bond investing

Aide-Mémoire. Impact of Currency Exchange Fluctuations on UNHCR s Operations

HW 2 Macroeconomics 102 Due on 06/12

Economic inequality and educational attainment across a generation

So what s a state to do? Some recent research provides guidance.

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES UNDERSTANDING COMMERCIAL REAL ESTATE: JUST HOW DIFFERENT FROM HOUSING IS IT? Joseph Gyourko

THE MORTGAGE INTEREST DEDUCTION ACROSS ZIP CODES. Benjamin H. Harris and Lucie Parker Urban-Brookings Tax Policy Center December 4, 2014 ABSTRACT

DOES HUMAN CAPITAL AFFECT RURAL ECONOMIC GROWTH? EVIDENCE FROM THE SOUTH

The Equity of Sales Tax Revenue in North Carolina Counties

The Effect of Housing on Portfolio Choice. July 2009

Policy Analysis Report

E D I T I O N CLEP O F F I C I A L S T U D Y G U I D E. The College Board. College Level Examination Program

a) Aggregate Demand (AD) and Aggregate Supply (AS) analysis

FAIR VALUE ACCOUNTING: VISIONARY THINKING OR OXYMORON? Aswath Damodaran

This PDF is a selection from a published volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research

Econ 137 Urban Economics Lecture Notes III

What are the key current issues shaping equity release by older home owners?

Objectives for Chapter 9 Aggregate Demand and Aggregate Supply

What Drives the Consumer Price Index? Joshua Klick, Bureau of Labor Statistics, Washington DC

The Economic Impact of Texas State University

Re: Draft Environmental Impact Statement & Growth and Equity Analysis for the Seattle Comprehensive Plan Update

CHAPTER 7: AGGREGATE DEMAND AND AGGREGATE SUPPLY

The economic impact of stamp duty: Three reform options. Property Council of Australia

Chapter 7 Monopoly, Oligopoly and Strategy

DOES GOVERNMENT R & D POLICY MAINLY BENEFIT SCIENTISTS AND ENGINEERS?

Scottish Socialist Party Submission to. the Local Tax Commission 2015

The Impact of Broadband Deployment on Recreational and Seasonal Property Values- A Hedonic Model

14.23 Government Regulation of Industry

Findings: City of Tshwane

THE LOCAL ECONOMIC IMPACT OF COLLEGES AND UNIVERSITIES. Peter McHenry, Allen Sanderson and John Siegfried

General hospital offering comprehensive, cradle-tograve. Specialty medical provider targeting specific patient use

Transcription:

1 Urban Housing Demand Prepared for the New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics By Todd Sinai, University of Pennsylvania (Wharton) and NBER Edited version: March 8, 2007 Urban housing demand is a reflection of households desire to live in cities. In this article, I discuss possible reasons why US households have exhibited an increasing taste for urban living, including employment, urban amenities, and consumption opportunities. Next, I explain how growing urban housing demand led to rising house prices and a sorting of households across cities by income. That dynamic generated a divergence across housing markets in the value of the tax subsidy to owner-occupied housing as well as housing market risk. Those factors, in turn, had a feedback effect on urban housing demand. At its core, the demand for urban housing is just the manifestation of the demand for living in urban areas. On net, residence patterns suggest that most people want to live in or near cities, and that desire is increasing over time. In fact, by 1999, 75 per cent of US households lived in cities (Rosenthal and Strange, 2003). Today, urban America is where housing demand is most likely to exceed housing supply and generate rising house prices, where the tax system provides the greatest subsidy to owner-occupied housing, and where the housing market is the most volatile. In this article I discuss some of the causes and consequences of urban housing demand, and the supporting evidence. Location The classic explanation for the concentration of households in cities is that people want to live close to their jobs. That notion, developed in the Alonso/Muth/Mills monocentric city model, leads to a prediction that is rarely as evident in reality as it is in theory: housing costs should rise as the distance to the employment centre falls since households would be willing to pay more in order to save time getting to work. Instead, households often settle for a longer commute in exchange for other positive qualities of a non-urban community, such as the density

2 of development, the calibre of the school system, local taxes and amenities, and the similarity of the other residents to themselves. Since the 1960s, the patterns of where people live have begun to shift back to cities, even though people are now less likely to work in the downtown areas. According to Glaeser et al. (2001), between 1960 and 1990 the rate of growth of commutes where the household lives in the city increased while the growth rate of commutes originating in the suburbs fell. Within cities, the high-income population has been moving closer to the central downtown area. Glaeser et al. argue that nowadays thriving cities are consumer cities, ones that attract highly educated households through appealing cultural amenities, such as museums, restaurants and opera. In fact, between 1977 and 1995, a temperate and dry climate, a coastal location, and more live performance venues and restaurants per capita predicted future population growth. By contrast, having more bowling alleys was correlated with population decline. Indeed, the very congestion that urban economists typically point to as a reason that cities become unattractive may lead to an availability and quality of goods and services that are appealing. In a city, the large number of residents living in close proximity makes it feasible for even niche markets to be served since a critical mass of potential customers exists. Joel Waldfogel (2003), who in a series of papers termed this phenomenon preference externalities, found empirical support in the markets for broadcast radio, newspapers, and restaurants. For example, when there is a larger local consumer base for a certain format of radio station, calibre of newspaper, or style of restaurant, the more of them exist in a city. By revealed preference, that greater variety increases city dwellers welfare, because the more options there are for residents that share a particular set of tastes the more they consume. Even the advent of the Internet has not dampened the consumption appeal of living in cities. Since the Internet makes information and goods universally available to anyone, no matter where they live, it substitutes for living in a city. However, Sinai and Waldfogel (2004) find that the number and variety of websites focused on a city increases with the city s population. By enhancing the welfare benefits of living in cities perhaps by mitigating the effects of congestion or facilitating communication and connection among city residents these sites have an offsetting positive effect on urban housing demand. Urban housing demand and house prices

3 Two measures of the intensity of urban housing demand are house prices and the rate of house price growth. In some cities, housing is in inelastic supply because there is little or no open land and local regulations either restrict development or make it prohibitively expensive or slow. In that case, demand for a location leads to bidding up of the price of land in order to equilibrate housing demand with the available supply. Indeed, when one compares house prices across cities and town, areas that presumably have higher demand because they offer better amenities and fiscal conditions exhibit higher house prices (Roback, (1982). Another indication of high demand for a city is population growth, which occurs when housing development is easy. I focus on high house prices because they can change the character of a city, which then has a further effect on urban housing demand. Since the 1950s, a handful of metropolitan areas experienced real house price growth that significantly exceeded the national average, leading to a widening gap across locations in average house prices. For example, in 1950 the average house price in San Francisco was 37 per cent higher than the average across all metropolitan areas. By 2000 the gap had grown to 218 per cent. In order for land prices to continually grow in one location relative to another, the demand for that location must be growing as well. One possible explanation is that productivity growth in a handful of cities has exceeded the national average, and residents pay more to live in productive cities because their wage rises with their productivity. Another potential rationalization is that some cities are becoming more appealing over time and residents are paying more for increasingly higher quality. Another possibility is that the rapid growth in the number and earnings of high-income households in the United States has led to an increased willingness-to-pay for scarce locations. Since some cities are in such limited supply, households have to outbid each other to live there, leading to land prices that grow with the aggregate spending power of the clientele that prefers that particular city. In Superstar Cities, Gyourko, Mayer and Sinai (2006) show that inelastically supplied, high-demand cities have income distributions that are shifted to the right: low-income families can live there only if they have a very strong preference for the city, while high-income families can live there even if they only modestly prefer it. As the national highincome population grows, the greater number of high-income families outbid relatively lowincome families (as well as some high-income families) who are unwilling or unable to pay a higher premium to live in their preferred location. Gyourko, Mayer and Sinai find that such

4 superstar locations experience supra-normal house price growth and a shift of their income distributions to the right as they experience inflows of high-income households and outflows of their lowest-income residents. This pattern has been intensified as cities have begun to fill up due to the growing national population. For example, in 1960 only Los Angeles and San Francisco were demonstrably inelastically supplied. By 2000 more than 20 cities were. Gyourko, Mayer and Sinai show that cities that fill up experience a right-shift in their income distributions and higher price growth after their transition into superstar city status. These findings imply that there must be something unique and attractive about superstar cities, otherwise potential residents would turn to cheaper locations and superstar cities would not be able to sustain excess price growth. A niche-market appeal may be due to particular amenities, or the kind of preference externalities described by Waldfogel. As preference agglomerations form, the highest willingness-to-pay households are those that share the same preferences. If such sorting is along income lines, rising house prices can lead to high-income homogeneity, which itself makes an area more desirable to high-income residents. That dynamic implies that certain urban markets will evolve into luxury areas and grow increasingly unaffordable for the average household. The inelasticity of housing supply also leads to price changes, and a correlated change in the demand for urban housing, in cities that are experiencing declining demand. Glaeser and Gyourko (2005) point out that, since housing does not quickly depreciate once built, if the demand for a city declines then house prices must fall since quantity cannot easily adjust downwards. That decline in prices can spur demand by low-income households that cannot afford to live anywhere else, leading to sorting into low-income enclaves rather than highincome ones. The tax subsidy to owner-occupied housing Differences in house prices among cities also affect the benefits homeowners obtain from their houses, which in turn affect the demand for urban housing. One such benefit in the United States that often is especially valuable in cities is the favourable Federal income tax treatment for owner-occupied housing, worth a total of $420 billion in 1999 (see HOUSING MARKETS AND POLICY). Gyourko and Sinai (2004) note that two conditions are necessary in order to receive a

5 high value of this tax subsidy: a high-priced home, so that the subsidy operates on a larger base, and a high tax rate, which in the progressive US tax system follows from having a high income. Because of this, the very same superstar city dynamic discussed earlier leads to an unequal distribution of the housing subsidy across the country. Superstar cities experience both house price growth and relatively high-income residents, and thus should also have the highest tax subsidies, further increasing the demand for urban housing in hot markets. Indeed, the tax subsidy is highly concentrated in a handful of cities, with just five metropolitan areas receiving more than 85 per cent of the total tax benefits in 1990. Between 1980 and 2000, the rise in house prices in superstar cities more than offset declining marginal tax rates, leading to a greater concentration of tax benefits in a handful of metropolitan areas. This tax subsidy has been shown to lead to higher house prices, either because the subsidy induces households to consume a larger quantity of housing or simply because house prices capitalize the present value of the future tax savings. Recent estimates of the after-tax price elasticity of housing demand cluster around 0.5, and the income elasticity around 0.25. Urban areas tend to exhibit relatively high demand elasticities, as demand is more readily capitalized into land prices rather than the limited new supply. By contrast, rural areas have much lower measured elasticities of housing demand. Risk and the demand for urban housing Since urban housing markets tend to have inelastic supply, they are more volatile as shocks to housing demand are transmitted more completely into rents and prices. That higher risk may deter households from living in urban areas since they would face more uncertainty over housing costs, whether they rented or owned. Also, house price volatility generates an additional cost because it distorts other investment decisions (Flavin and Yamashita, 2002). A mitigating factor, demonstrated in Sinai and Souleles (2005), is that long length-of-stay households can reduce their effective risk by owning their houses, in essence prepaying their housing costs. Other research suggests that uncertainty over house price growth simply may lead households to purchase housing in a city sooner than they otherwise would have in order to prevent housing costs from outpacing their income growth.

6 Bibliography Flavin, M. and Yamashita, T. 2002. Owner-occupied housing and the composition of the household portfolio over the life cycle. American Economic Review 92, 345 62. Glaeser, E. and Gyourko, J. 2005. Urban decline and durable housing. Journal of Political Economy 113, 345 75. Glaeser, E., Kolko, J. and Saiz, A. 2001. Consumer city. Journal of Economic Geography 1, 27 50. Gyourko, J., Mayer, C. and Sinai, T. 2006. Superstar cities. Working Paper No. 12355. Cambridge, MA: NBER. Gyourko, J. and Sinai, T. 2004. The (un)changing geographical distribution of housing tax benefits: 1980 to 2000. In Tax Policy and the Economy, vol. 18, ed. J. Poterba. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. Roback, J. 1982. Wages, rents, and the quality of life. Journal of Political Economy 90, 1257 78. Rosenthal, S. S. and Strange, W. C. 2003. Evidence on the nature and sources of agglomeration economies. Handbook of Urban and Regional Economics, ed. J.V. Henderson and J.-F. Thisse. Sinai, T. and Souleles, N. 2005. Owner-occupied housing as a hedge against rent risk. Quarterly Journal of Economics 120, 763 89. Sinai, T. and Waldfogel, J. 2004. Geography and the Internet: is the internet a substitute or complement for cities? Journal of Urban Economics 56, 1 24. Waldfogel, J. 2003. Preference externalities: an empirical study of who benefits whom in differentiated product markets. RAND Journal of Economics 34, 557 68.