Prot Maximization and Cost Minimization



Similar documents
Deriving Demand Functions - Examples 1

Sample Midterm Solutions

MICROECONOMICS AND POLICY ANALYSIS - U8213 Professor Rajeev H. Dehejia Class Notes - Spring 2001

Utility Maximization

Costs. Accounting Cost{stresses \out of pocket" expenses. Depreciation costs are based on tax laws.

Profit and Revenue Maximization

Constrained Optimisation

Lecture 2. Marginal Functions, Average Functions, Elasticity, the Marginal Principle, and Constrained Optimization

To give it a definition, an implicit function of x and y is simply any relationship that takes the form:


c. Given your answer in part (b), what do you anticipate will happen in this market in the long-run?

ECON 103, ANSWERS TO HOME WORK ASSIGNMENTS

CHAPTER 4 Consumer Choice

Equations, Inequalities & Partial Fractions

constraint. Let us penalize ourselves for making the constraint too big. We end up with a

Cost Constraint/Isocost Line

Systems of Linear Equations: Two Variables

19 : Theory of Production

Chapter 4 Online Appendix: The Mathematics of Utility Functions

3.1. Solving linear equations. Introduction. Prerequisites. Learning Outcomes. Learning Style

Increasing for all. Convex for all. ( ) Increasing for all (remember that the log function is only defined for ). ( ) Concave for all.

Basic numerical skills: EQUATIONS AND HOW TO SOLVE THEM. x + 5 = = (2-2) = = 5. x = 7-5. x + 0 = 20.

Click on the links below to jump directly to the relevant section

Intermediate Microeconomics (22014)

8. Average product reaches a maximum when labor equals A) 100 B) 200 C) 300 D) 400

Cost Minimization and the Cost Function

Linear Programming. Solving LP Models Using MS Excel, 18

Microeconomics Sept. 16, 2010 NOTES ON CALCULUS AND UTILITY FUNCTIONS

Common sense, and the model that we have used, suggest that an increase in p means a decrease in demand, but this is not the only possibility.

In this section, we will consider techniques for solving problems of this type.

SOLUTIONS TO HOMEWORK SET #4

or, put slightly differently, the profit maximizing condition is for marginal revenue to equal marginal cost:

2.3 Solving Equations Containing Fractions and Decimals

Pre-Test Chapter 25 ed17

NAME: INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMIC THEORY SPRING 2008 ECONOMICS 300/010 & 011 Midterm II April 30, 2008

Elements of a graph. Click on the links below to jump directly to the relevant section

1.2 Solving a System of Linear Equations

Constrained Optimization: The Method of Lagrange Multipliers:

Managerial Economics Prof. Trupti Mishra S.J.M. School of Management Indian Institute of Technology, Bombay. Lecture - 13 Consumer Behaviour (Contd )

3 1B: Solving a System of Equations by Substitution

c 2008 Je rey A. Miron We have described the constraints that a consumer faces, i.e., discussed the budget constraint.

Temperature Scales. The metric system that we are now using includes a unit that is specific for the representation of measured temperatures.

Productioin OVERVIEW. WSG5 7/7/03 4:35 PM Page 63. Copyright 2003 by Academic Press. All rights of reproduction in any form reserved.

Review of Fundamental Mathematics

Monopoly and Monopsony Labor Market Behavior

14.01 Principles of Microeconomics, Fall 2007 Chia-Hui Chen October 15, Lecture 13. Cost Function

Production Function in the Long-Run. Business Economics Theory of the Firm II Production and Cost in the Long Run. Description of Technology

0.8 Rational Expressions and Equations

MATH MODULE 5. Total, Average, and Marginal Functions. 1. Discussion M5-1

CAHSEE on Target UC Davis, School and University Partnerships

Solving Rational Equations

Principles of Economics: Micro: Exam #2: Chapters 1-10 Page 1 of 9

Second Order Linear Nonhomogeneous Differential Equations; Method of Undetermined Coefficients. y + p(t) y + q(t) y = g(t), g(t) 0.

PART A: For each worker, determine that worker's marginal product of labor.

Envelope Theorem. Kevin Wainwright. Mar 22, 2004

Study Questions for Chapter 9 (Answer Sheet)

The Cost of Production

The Cobb-Douglas Production Function

Chapter 9. Systems of Linear Equations

Connecting the Firm s Optimal Output and Input Decisions

Name: ID: Discussion Section:

Year 9 set 1 Mathematics notes, to accompany the 9H book.

Linear Equations and Inequalities

Balancing Chemical Equations

Math 53 Worksheet Solutions- Minmax and Lagrange

DEMAND FORECASTING. Demand. Law of Demand. Definition of Law of Demand

Microeconomic Theory: Basic Math Concepts

ANSWERS TO END-OF-CHAPTER QUESTIONS

Revenue Structure, Objectives of a Firm and. Break-Even Analysis.

5.1 Radical Notation and Rational Exponents

Review of Production and Cost Concepts

Week 1: Functions and Equations

Compute the derivative by definition: The four step procedure

Ratio and Proportion Study Guide 12

Maximizing volume given a surface area constraint

Table of Contents MICRO ECONOMICS

Partial Fractions Decomposition

Indiana State Core Curriculum Standards updated 2009 Algebra I

Demand. Lecture 3. August Reading: Perlo Chapter 4 1 / 58

Long-Run Average Cost. Econ 410: Micro Theory. Long-Run Average Cost. Long-Run Average Cost. Economies of Scale & Scope Minimizing Cost Mathematically

This unit will lay the groundwork for later units where the students will extend this knowledge to quadratic and exponential functions.

Midterm Exam #1 - Answers

An increase in the number of students attending college. shifts to the left. An increase in the wage rate of refinery workers.

Math 120 Final Exam Practice Problems, Form: A

Grade Level Year Total Points Core Points % At Standard %

REVIEW OF MICROECONOMICS

3.1. RATIONAL EXPRESSIONS

Short Run Market Equilibrium. The market supply curve is found by horizontally adding the supply curves of individual rms. If there are m rms, we have

is identically equal to x 2 +3x +2

Section 4.1 Rules of Exponents

The Envelope Theorem 1

Pre-Test Chapter 8 ed17

5 Numerical Differentiation

Mathematical goals. Starting points. Materials required. Time needed

Sensitivity Analysis 3.1 AN EXAMPLE FOR ANALYSIS

TOPIC 4: DERIVATIVES

Solution Guide Chapter 14 Mixing Fractions, Decimals, and Percents Together

November 16, Interpolation, Extrapolation & Polynomial Approximation

On closed-form solutions of a resource allocation problem in parallel funding of R&D projects

Pricing I: Linear Demand

Transcription:

Simon Fraser University Prof. Karaivanov Department of Economics Econ 0 COST MINIMIZATION Prot Maximization and Cost Minimization Remember that the rm's problem is maximizing prots by choosing the optimal quantities of inputs to employ and output to produce. We already know how to solve the rm's prot maximization problem in a competitive market environment. This direct approach is great but there are some very important insights especially on the cost side of the rm's problem that can be gained if we look at the rm's problem through a more indirect approach. The idea is to break down the prot maximization problem of the rm into two stages: rst, we look at the problem of minimizing costs of producing any given amount of output, and second, we look at how to choose the most protable output level. These notes cover the rst of these two stages, i.e. they answer the question: for a given amount of output, y (just some number, 0, 0, 00, which does not have to be necessarily the rm's optimal output that it will end up producing) what is the minimum cost of producing it. In other words, we ask given that we have to produce y units of output and given input prices w and w, how much of each input should the rm employ to produce y in the least costly way. Notice that the amount of each input that will be used will depend on the output level that the rm wants to produce - if you want to produce 000 units of outputs you would denitely need more workers and machines than to produce just 0 units. Notice that cost minimization is a necessary condition for prot maximization in competitive markets. If, for a given level of output, one is not cost minimizing that means that he is also not prot maximizing. Why? For a given y revenue is xed (taking p as given), so if there is a less costly way to produce this output level this will lead to higher prots. The Cost Minimization Problem Given the above discussion the rm wants to solve: min x ;x w x + w x s:t: f(x ; x ) = y How is the above interpreted? The rm wants to minimize its costs (w x + w x ) of producing y units of output. The fact that the rm wants produce y units of output is given by the constrain f(x ; x ) = y: Remember that the production function, f(x ; x ) corresponds to the maximum output that can be extracted from x units of input and x units of input - i.e. (since inputs are costly), using the production function we would use x and x most eciently. The cost minimization is then done by choosing how much of each input to employ (x and x ) such that the costs of producing y using the production function are minimized.

How Do We Solve The Cost Minimization Problem? In general the cost minimization problem is harder to solve that the consumer problem or the prot maximization problem since usually the constraint (f(x ; x ) = y) is a non-linear function of x and x so sometimes it may be hard to express x in terms of x from it and plug into the costs that we are minimizing. When this is the case there are two ways to proceed of which the rst is simpler and recommended and the second is optional for those of you with more knowledge of math (you can use either one at the exams):. Solving the cost minimization problem using the optimality condition T RS = w w : Remember that we showed in class graphically that at the optimal choice of input quantities (the optimum) we must have that the isocost line is tangent to the isoquant corresponding to output level y: The slope of the isoquant is given by the technical rate of substitution (TRS) which is a function of x and x : Why? Because remember what the TRS is equal to: it equals minus the ratio of marginal products, i.e. T RS = MP (x ;x ) MP (x ;x but the marginal products are ) functions of x and x since they are simply the partial derivatives of the production function w which is a function of x and x : The slope of the isocost line (remember from class) was w i.e. minus the ratio of the input prices (this is similar to the slope of the budget line, however note that the isocost curve does not serve the same purpose as the budget line). In the consumer problem we had a xed budget line and we were trying to nd the point on this budget line which would give us maximum utility - i.e. the point which lies on the highest indierence curve. In contrast, in the rm's problem we have a xed isoquant and we are trying to nd the point on this xed isoquant which gives us minimum costs, i.e. the point lying on the lowest isocost line. Given the above, we can solve the cost minimization problem by solving two equations for the two unknowns x and x : the optimality condition and the constraint that y must be produced: MP (x ; x ) = w (optimality condition) MP (x ; x ) w f(x ; x ) = y (output must be y condition) Notice that y is not an unknown! It is just a xed level of output we want to produce (say 0, 0, 0 or whatever). We do not have to solve for y - it is given. The solutions to the above problem ^x and ^x will be generally functions of everything that is given: the input prices, w and w and the output level y; i.e. we will have: ^x = ^x (w ; w ; y) ^x = ^x (w ; w ; y) These solutions (to the cost minimization problem of a rm facing input prices w and w which wants to produce y) are called the conditional input demands for producing y units of output at input rises w and w : Why are they called conditional? Because they are conditioned (i.e. depend on) what level of output we want to produce - if we want to produce more output more inputs will be needed in general.

Dierence between the conditional input demands from the cost minimization problem and the (unconditional) input demands from the prot maximization problem It is important to understand that the conditional input demands coming from the cost minimization problem above are not the same thing as the (unconditional, as sometimes called) input demands resulting from the prot maximization problem (see the notes on prot maximization and input demands). Remember the prot maximizing input demands, x (w ; w ; p) and x (w ; w ; p) were functions of the input prices, w and w and the output price p: They are called unconditional (or simply not called conditional) because they do not depend on y - the output level in the rm's prot maximization problem is already optimized and this optimized output level is a function of the prices (w ; w ; p) that are taken as given by the rm - thus the (unconditional) input demands are only functions of what is given, i.e. the prices. In contrast, the cost minimization problem is being solved for a given output level which is not necessarily the optimized one that the rm will eventually choose. Why? Remember the cost minimization problem was only the rst step in the indirect approach to solve the rm's problem and at that rst step the output level was taken as given as we were only interested in how to produce any given output level at minimum cost. Thus the conditional input demands depend only on what is given in the cost minimization problem - i.e. the input prices, w and w and the output level y: One more time: the (unconditional) input demands depend on output price, p, the conditional input demands depend on output level, y: Both of them depend on input prices, w and w :. Solving the cost minimization problem using the Lagrange method (OPTIONAL! NOT REQUIRED FOR THE EXAM!) For those of you interested in math and knowing what the Lagrange method of solving optimization problems is, the cost minimization problem of the rm stated above can be solved also using this method. What we do is write the Lagrangean: (x ; x ; ) = w x + w x (f(x ; x ) y) where is the Lagrange multiplier on the constraint. Then we have to take the partial derivatives of the Lagrangean with respect to its three arguments, x ; x and and set them equal to zero: w @f(x ; x ) @x = 0 w @f(x ; x ) @x = 0 f(x ; x ) y = 0 where @f(x ;x ) @x and @f(x ;x ) @x are the rst partial derivatives of the production function with respect to x and x : The last equation is simply our constraint. We can take the rst two equations above to get: w = @f(x ; x ) @x 3

Divide them through (both sides) to get: w = @f(x ; x ) @x w w = @f(x ;x ) @x @f(x ;x ) @x But what are the partial derivatives of the production - remember they are simply the marginal products of each input, MP (x ; x ) and MP (x ; x ): Thus we get: w = MP (x ; x ) w MP (x ; x ) which is what we had before! Then this equation, together with the constraint f(x ; x ) = y can be used to solve for the conditional input demands ^x (w ; w ; y) and ^x (w ; w ; y): An Example With A Specic Production Function: Take f(x ; x ) = x =3 and let input prices be w = ; w = : We want to solve the rm's cost minimization problem of producing y units of output. We will use all three methods discussed above and obtain the same results: { substitution from the constraint { using the optimality condition MP (x ;x ) = w MP (x ;x ) w { using the Lagrange method (optional) Let us rst write down the problem: min x ;x x + x s.t. x =3 = y Method (Direct Substitution). We rst have to express x in terms of x from the technology constraint f(x ; x ) = y: The easiest way to to it is get rid of the exponents rst by raising the constraint to power 3 - we get: x x = y 3 thus x = y3 x :. Now let's plug the expression for x obtained above in our cost function to get the following minimization problem: min x x + y3 x 3. We solve the above problem of just one unknown (x ) by taking the rst derivative of the function being minimized and setting it to zero: + y 3 ( 4 ) = 0 x

(we use that the derivative of x is x ): Remember y is given, i.e. treated as if it were a number!. From the above equation we can solve for the optimal x as function of y (in general it is also a function of w and w but remember we plugged numbers for these already): x = y 3 or x = y 3 ; or ^x (y) = p y 3= which is the conditional input demand for input. 4. Now how do we nd the optimal quantity demanded of input (i.e. its conditional input demand, ^x )? Remember we know that ^x = y3 ^x so we have: ^x (y) = p y3 = y3= p y 3= which is the conditional input demand for input. Notice that both conditional input demands depend on the given level of output, y that the rm wants to produce. 5. The minimum cost of producing y units of output then can be found by simply substituting the conditional input demands obtained above into the cost function: ^c(y) = ^x (y) + ^x (y) = p y 3= + p y 3= = p y 3= Method (using the optimality condition) This method works even if it is not obvious how to express x in terms of x from the constraint. However, it relies on tangency and interiority of the solution.. To be able to write down the optimality condition for cost minimization we need to compute the marginal products of each input, i.e. the partial derivatives of the production function with respect to x and x : We have: MP (x ; x ) = @f(x ; x ) = @x 3 x =3 MP (x ; x ) = @f(x ; x ) = @x 3 x=3 x =3 (remember when taking partial derivatives you hold all variables that you are not taking the derivative with respect to as constant).. Thus the optimality condition for our particular production function and input prices is (cancelling the /3s): x =3 x =3 x =3 = or collecting the exponents, x x = 5

(please remember how to manipulate fractions of numbers raised to dierent powers!). From above we get: x = x : 3. We can use the above relationship between x and x and plug it in the second equation that they must satisfy, namely that output should be y : Again, raising both sides to power 3 helps: x =3 ( x ) =3 = y x = y 3 or, x = y 3 ; so ^x (y) = p y 3= or the conditional input demand for input one is the same thing as before once again. Then ^x (y) = ^x (y) = y3= p again same as before. Clearly then the minimized costs will be also the same. Method 3 (using Lagrange, OPTIONAL). We write the Lagrangean for our specic problem: (x ; x ; ) = x + x (x =3 y). Taking the partial derivatives with respect to the arguments of the Lagrangean we get: 3 x =3 = 0 3 x=3 x =3 = 0 x =3 y = 0 3. Re-arrange the rst two equations as described in the general example above and divide them through to get: = x =3 x =3 x =3 which is the same what we had in Method. Thus you can use the rest of the steps in Method to nish the solution. 6